Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 13

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Biomass gasification in cost-optimized district heating systems—A regional


modelling analysis
Martin Börjesson , Erik O. Ahlgren
Energy Systems Technology, Division of Energy Technology, Department of Energy and Environment, Chalmers University of Technology, SE-412 96 Göteborg, Sweden

a r t i c l e in f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Biomass integrated gasification combined cycle (BIGCC) plants could, in combined heat and power
Received 16 June 2008 (CHP) generation, increase the power-to-heat ratio compared to conventional biomass steam turbine
Accepted 2 September 2009 plants. Furthermore, biomass gasification could also be used for the efficient production of biofuels for
Available online 30 September 2009
transport. In this study, different applications of biomass gasification in connection to district heating
Keywords: (DH) are analysed and contrasted to conventional technology options. An application of the cost-
Biomass gasification optimizing energy system model MARKAL with a detailed description of the DH sector in a
MARKAL southwestern region of Sweden was developed within the study and used in the analysis. Policy
District heating measures for CO2 reduction and for promotion of ‘‘green’’ electricity are assumed, and required subsidy
levels for large-scale production of transport biofuels are calculated. The model also operates with
different supplies of biomass: a local supply at a lower cost and an international supply of refined
biomass at a slightly higher cost. The study shows that investments in BIGCC CHP are often cost-
efficient in cases with low ambitions regarding transport biofuels. However, due to limitations in heat
demand and in local, lower cost, supply of biomass, investment in biofuel production means less
investment in BIGCC CHP and, thereby, a smaller electricity production.
& 2009 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction and purpose are addressed. A region in the southwestern part of Sweden,
defined by the county of Västra Götaland and the conurbation of
There are mainly two driving forces for modern use of biomass Göteborg, with its specific energy demands and energy infra-
for energy purposes: climate concerns and energy security. With structure is used as a case study.
increasingly more ambitious CO2 emission reduction targets and a A global problem like the climate issue requires international
will to reduce dependence on imported energy carriers, the agreements and strategies. However, a local or regional perspec-
demand for biomass is likely to increase. Although biomass tive is central for the actual implementation of actions for
resources are renewable, the potential is limited, and an emission reduction, and allows in several aspects a higher degree
increasing pressure on efficient resource utilization is probable. of detail than what is possible with more aggregated approaches
The purpose of the present study is to examine the cost- on higher geographical levels. Local circumstances and geogra-
effectiveness of biomass gasification technologies compared to phical considerations, which often are important factors in choice
conventional technology alternatives in the district heating (DH) of energy technologies, are more easily integrated in the analysis.
sector. The study investigates whether, and under what condi- In addition, regional energy systems analyses can, besides adding
tions, combined heat and power (CHP) generation through insights of efficient energy technology choices in general, also
biomass gasification in so-called biomass integrated gasification provide understanding regarding factors such as suitable plant
combined cycle (BIGCC) plants could be part of the production in locations. Since biomass markets often are local or regional
cost-optimized DH systems. Production of biofuels for transport (although refining of the biomass to, e.g., pellets or briquettes
through biomass gasification is also analysed and, in particular, opens up wider markets through decreased transport costs) this
what impact on cost-optimized DH systems a large-scale perspective is also essential when it comes to analyses of
introduction of biofuel production would have and what subsidy biomass-derived products such as biofuels and ‘‘green’’ electricity.
levels that would be required for such an introduction. Further- The importance of regional and local initiatives for environmental
more, environmental effects in terms of impacts on CO2 emissions issues has been addressed in various forums. In the United
Nations Programme Agenda 21, local actions for sustainable
development is encouraged and recognized to play a vital role
 Corresponding author. Tel.: + 46 31772 5244; fax: + 46 31772 3592. (UN, 1993), and the European Commission has in its plan for
E-mail address: martin.borjesson@chalmers.se (M. Börjesson). energy efficiency improvements recognized that large saving

0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2009 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.09.001
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180 169

potentials could be realized by greater decentralization of energy be increased to 25 000 ha, which is equal to 0.9% of the arable land
management to local and regional levels (European Commission, in the country (Statistics Sweden et al., 2007). Imports of biomass
2000). A few energy systems studies have applied the regional and biofuels to Sweden have been estimated to about 5–9 TWh,
perspective. Two examples are Salvia et al. (2004), in which the and are mainly composed of wood pellets for use in heat
Basilicata region, Italy, was modelled to analyse cost-effective CO2 production and ethanol for use in the transportation sector
reduction strategies focusing on the civil and waste management (SEA, 2006a).
sectors, and Carlson (2003), in which the heating sector of DH is the dominating heating technology in Sweden with a
the Östergötland region, Sweden, was analysed with the market share of about 48% of the heating demand for residential
primary objective of examining the consequences of including and commercial premises (SEA, 2006a). In 2005, the energy
external costs for emissions. A review of studies done on supply for DH production (excluding electricity production in CHP
modelling for decentralized energy planning is given in Hiremath plants) totalled to 55 TWh, of which biomass (including waste and
et al. (2007). peat) accounted for 66%. This is the result of a substantial increase
The present study has partly its origin in the so-called during the last decades, e.g. in 1970 the total energy supply to DH
Biokombi Rya project (Nyström et al., 2007). The Biokombi Rya production was 15 TWh, of which 98% was oil (SEA, 2006b). In the
project had as its main objective, on different system levels, to DH sector, biomass is primarily used in boilers for heat production,
investigate the possibility and possible benefits of integrating although in recent years the CHP production has risen somewhat
biomass gasification with a 600 MWfuel natural gas combined (SEA, 2006a). The so far comparably low level of CHP production in
cycle (NGCC) plant, the Rya CHP, recently taken in operation in the Swedish DH systems and the potential of increasing the
the city of Göteborg in the Västra Götaland region of Sweden. production were addressed in Knutsson et al. (2006b).
However, in the present study, the possibility of retrofitting Energy products, such as heat, electricity and transport fuels,
existing natural gas plants with biomass gasification is not in are often influenced by different kinds of policy tools. One
focus. Instead, the approach is more general considering invest- example is the EU trading scheme for CO2 emission allowances,
ments in different types of gasification-based production, and the or tradable emission permits (TEPs), which put a price on CO2
biomass gasification technologies are treated as alternatives in the emissions from fossil fuels and, thereby, promotes the use of CO2-
entire studied region and not primarily as an option in Göteborg. free technologies and fuels. The system has been in operation
Other studies that in different ways are concerned with economic since January 2005 and includes in its initial stage a limited
performance of biomass gasification utilities are for instance number of sectors in energy-intensive industries and electricity
Dornburg and Faaij (2001), Marbe et al. (2004) and Fahle n and producers (SEA, 2006a). In Sweden, a CO2 tax was introduced in
Ahlgren (in press). The latter focuses on biomass gasification in 1991, which, in 2005, had a level of 102 EUR/ton CO2.1 The
connection with district heating in a similar way as the present application of the tax is different, depending on where the CO2
study, although there are several methodological differences. emissions take place. It has been applied to full extent to the
transportation sector and for production of space heating and to a
lesser degree in the industry and for electricity production. Today,
2. Background the tax is partly being phased out to make way for the EU
emission trading system (EU ETS), although it is still in use for
Gasification makes it possible to use biomass in gas combined sectors that are not included in the system (SEA, 2006a).
cycle (CC) plants and, thereby, to reach a significantly higher In order to stimulate renewable electricity production, a
electrical efficiency than in conventional biomass steam turbine market-based scheme, so-called tradable green certificates
(ST) plants. However, regarding CHP production, the heat (TGCs), has been introduced in Sweden. The TGC system has
efficiency and the total efficiency (electricity and heat) are lower been in operation since May 2003 and will be so until 2030
than in a conventional biomass ST CHP plant with flue gas (SEA, 2006a). In the TGC system, a green certificate is given to the
condensation (Nyström et al., 2007). electricity producer for each produced megawatt hour (MWh) of
Biomass gasification can also be used to produce biofuels for renewable electricity. The certificate is sold on a market and thus
the transportation sector. From the product gas received from the creates an extra income besides the income from the electricity
gasification process, a number of biofuels, e.g. dimethyl ether sales. All electricity consumers, except for energy-intensive
(DME), methanol, synthetic natural gas (SNG), hydrogen and industries, are obliged to buy certificates in an amount corre-
Fischer–Tropsch diesel, can be produced through different types sponding to a certain share of their total electricity consumption
of gas processing and synthesis steps. The energy efficiency is high and, thereby, a demand for the green certificates is created.
compared to, for instance, production of ethanol through Renewable electricity production technologies, excluding large-
fermentation of wheat or cellulose (e.g. KAM, 2003; Nyström scale hydropower and electricity production from combustion of
et al., 2007). municipal waste but currently including CHP production from
The use of biomass (including waste and peat) accounted, in peat, are entitled to TGCs (SEA, 2006a). The yearly price averages
2005, for 18%, or 112 TWh, of the total energy use in Sweden (SEA, for the TGCs were between 2003 and 2006 in the interval
2006a). Main users of biomass for energy purposes are the DH and 21–26 EUR/MWh (Svenska Kraftnät, 2007). Impacts and correla-
industry sectors, which, in 2005, used 42 and 51 TWh, respectively tion between TEPs and TGCs for the Nordic countries were
(SEA, 2006a). The major part of the biomass resources are residues modelled and analysed in Unger and Ahlgren (2005).
and by-products from forestry and forest products industry (paper Also the transportation sector in Sweden is influenced by
and pulp, sawmills, etc.). About 1% (1.5 TWh) originates from the energy policies, for example, through fuel taxes. In 2006 the
agriculture sector. Energy crops are grown on approximately fuel taxes, excluding VAT but including the earlier mentioned CO2
70 000 ha, or 2.5% of the total arable land in Sweden. About 70% of tax, were 0.55 EUR/l petrol (61 EUR/MWh) and 0.41 EUR/l
this area is used to grow feedstock for production of biofuels, diesel (41 EUR/MWh). To increase the amount of biofuels in
either wheat for ethanol or rape for rape methyl ester (RME/ the transportation sector, biofuels are currently exempt from
biodiesel), and 20%, or 14 000 ha, is used for cultivation of energy the taxation applied for petrol and diesel (SEA, 2006a).
forest, Salix (willow), which primarily is used for heat and
electricity production (SOU, 2007). The Swedish Salix industry
has a target that the area used for Salix cultivation in 2010 should 1
Exchange rates used throughout this paper are 9 SEK= 1 EUR (= 1.14 USD).
ARTICLE IN PRESS
170 M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180

An introduction of a system similar to the TGCs has also been 3. Method and model
investigated (SOU, 2004). The EU directive 2003/30/EC states that
the amount of biofuels in the transportation sector in 2010 should Computer-based models are powerful tools for analysis of
constitute 5.75% of the total transport fuel consumption in the EU complex energy systems. Modelling offers the possibility of a
(European Commission, 2003). The target level for 2005 on 2% comprehensive and structured system representation and allows
was not met on an EU level, but in Germany and Sweden it was technology options and their system suitability to be contrasted
met on a national level (European Commission, 2007). More and analysed. Furthermore, economical, environmental and
recently, a target for 2020 of 10% has been decided (European technical aspects of studied systems can be evaluated and
Council, 2007). compared quantitatively under different conditions and scenarios.
The county of Västra Götaland is a part of Sweden located in A range of different types of models and modelling tools are
the southwest of the country. Västra Götaland has a population of available. Except for the above-mentioned qualities, some model-
about 1.5 million people and the largest city is Göteborg. The ling features are of special significance in this study. Since the DH
municipality of Göteborg has a population of about 0.5 million sector is in focus, the modelling approach regarding DH systems is
people (Statistics Sweden, 2007). Of the total 49 municipalities in central. DH as a technology can be defined as the centralized
Västra Götaland, in 2004 there were deliveries of DH in 34, production of heat distributed as hot water in a piping system and
although in many of these in a very small quantity (Statistics used for heating purposes in premises (SEA, 2006a). One of the
Sweden, 2006). The conurbation of Göteborg, or ‘‘Greater major benefits with DH is the possibility of making use of local
Göteborg’’, includes 13 municipalities, all of which belong to resources, such as heat released from incineration of municipal
the county of Västra Götaland except for the municipality of waste or wood waste and heat from process industries or power
Kungsbacka, which is included in the county of Halland. In the generation that might otherwise be wasted (Knutsson, 2005).
present study, the studied region is defined by the county of Because of its characteristics, DH is, in another way than, e.g.,
Västra Götaland and Greater Göteborg. Table 1 summarizes the electricity, geographically restricted in small local systems, all
production in the 15 largest DH systems, in terms of delivered with their own specific prerequisites. In modelling studies,
heat, in the studied region in 2004. The included systems in however, several DH systems are often aggregated, e.g. in Unger
Table 1 accounted, in 2004, for about 95% of the total DH and Ahlgren (2005) a model of the Nordic energy system is used in
production in the studied region (Statistics Sweden, 2006). The which the Swedish DH sector is represented as one single system.
production of electricity from CHP plants amounted, in 2004, to Although this, depending on the study’s objective, can be a
about 0.5 TWh. After 2004 several new CHP plants have been passable way, Knutsson et al. (2006a) concluded that the level of
taken into operation, mostly small-scale biomass ST plants but aggregation of DH systems can have an important impact on the
also the 600 MWfuel NGCC plant Rya CHP. results of the study. In the present study, a model that enables
In 2004, the biomass use for DH (including CHP) in the studied representation of a number of individual DH systems is preferable.
region was about 2.5 TWh, excluding municipal waste and peat Furthermore, a high level of detail and flexibility concerning the
(based on Swedish District Heating Association, 2006; Statistics description of energy technologies, current and future, and energy
Sweden, 2006). For Västra Götaland, the possible potential carriers is necessary. Since the cost-effectiveness of new technol-
outtake of forest residues (tops, branches and needles) has been ogies and the optimal use of biomass resources are studied, a
estimated to about 1570 kton dry substance (DS). However, dynamic cost-optimizing model is an appropriate choice.
considering practical, technical and environmental aspects only The MARKAL (MARKet ALlocation) model (Lolou et al., 2004),
about 970 kton DS, approximately 5 TWh, is reported to be a developed within the International Energy Agency’s energy
reasonable potential available for energy purposes (about 70% of technology system analysis programme (ETSAP), has the proper-
the tops and branches, 30% of the needles) (Johansson, 2001). ties required in the present study. Applications of the MARKAL
The land used for Salix cultivation was, in 2001, less than 0.2% of model are generally linear programming (LP), cost-optimizing
the total arable land in Västra Götaland (about 900 ha), which bottom-up models with perfect foresight (no insecurity about
resulted in a Salix production of approximately 40 GWh (Johansson, future development). An objective function minimizes the total
2001). system cost (the objective value) within the limits outlined by an

Table 1
Delivered DH, net production of electricity in CHP plants and energy sources for DH (incl. CHP) production, for the largest DH systems in the studied region, i.e. Västra
Götaland and Greater Göteborg, in terms of amount delivered DH (data from 2004 except for Kungsbacka: data from 2003).

DH system DH (delivered) Electricity (production) Biomass fuels Peat Municipal solid Heat pump Ind. waste heat Natural gas Oil Other
(GWh) (GWh) (%) (%) waste (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)

Göteborg 3843 320 11 30 12 29 17 1


Borås 591 120 77 9 4 10
Mölndal 275 71 14 15
Trollhättan 269 100
Uddevalla 264 36 52 1 11
Lidköping 252 18 15 80 4 2
Skövde 246 89 1 10 1
Vänersborg 150 10 90
Kungsbacka 113 2 61 14 26
Mariestad 103 25 96 4
Alingsås 101 98 2
Kungälv 97 95 1 3
Falköping 88 98 2
Mark 80 90 10
Skara 60 90 10

In the table, heat pumps are represented by produced DH, while other alternatives are represented by the input energy.
Based on Swedish District Heating Association (2006) and Statistics Sweden (2006); for the Göteborg system also Göteborg Energi (2005) and Renova (2005).
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180 171

often large number of linear constraints. The achieved solution biofuels will be necessary under the time horizon of interest in the
represents the lowest system cost alternative, among the many present study.
choices that are possible in the reference energy system (RES) In the model, a biofuel subsidy defined as an extra income for
structured network of energy technologies, that fulfils the biofuel production in addition to the income from the fuel sales is
exogenously given energy demands. The network of energy used. To study what impact different levels of biofuel production
technologies is user specified and can cover the whole chain have on a cost-optimized system, an iterative modelling proce-
from fuel extraction to end-use energy services. In the present dure is applied. Each model case is in a first model run tested
study, the MARKAL model is applied to a database of the DH without the biofuel subsidy present (subsidy level=0). Thereafter,
sector in Västra Götaland and Greater Göteborg forming a model the level of the subsidy is gradually raised in a series of model
here referred to as the MARKAL_WS model (WS= West Sweden). runs. In the model, the biorefineries are only available in discrete
The MARKAL_WS model has a time horizon ranging from 2004 capacity levels (see also Section 3.2) and, therefore, biofuel
to 20292 divided into six model periods, with each being subsidy threshold levels at which new biofuel plants are
represented by one model year (2004, 2009, 2014, 2019, 2024, introduced will be found. These threshold values, each corre-
2029). Each model year is furthermore divided into three seasons: sponding to a certain capacity of biofuel production, are outputs
winter, summer and spring/autumn (intermediate). The DH sector of the study. Within each model run, the subsidy level is held
is, in the MARKAL_WS model, represented by the 15 DH systems constant throughout the whole studied time period.
that are presented in Table 1. As previously stated, these systems In the study, it is not analysed what kind of policy tool would
account for the main part of the DH in the studied region be the most suitable option in reality. The subsidy in the model
(approximately 95%). In the model, the supply/production side of could be interpreted as a tax reduction or some other kind of
the included DH systems is described in great detail with a large financial support for biofuel production. Except for the biofuel
number of available energy technology options while other parts subsidy and a cost for CO2 emissions, biofuels and conventional
of the energy system, like fuel extraction and end-use technolo- transport fuels (petrol/diesel) are assumed to be subject to equally
gies, are described in a less-detailed way. repressive policy measures (energy taxes, etc.), and these are,
Each DH system in the model is driven by an individual therefore, disregarded in the model.
demand for DH, which is assumed inelastic to price changes. For
DH systems where estimations of future DH demand levels have
been available, these are used.3 None of these estimations cover,
however, the entire studied time period, and for the remaining 3.2. Energy technologies
time period the demands are assumed constant. For DH systems
where no estimations on future demand levels have been The 15 different DH systems included in the model are
available, the delivered DH of 2004 is used as the DH demand described by their current production plants as well as a number
throughout the entire studied time period. Electricity production of possible investment alternatives in new production capacity.
from CHP plants is, in the model, sold at exogenously given market The investment costs and other fixed costs for the set of existing
prices and creates an income to the system and, thereby, a plants are treated as sunk costs and, accordingly, only the variable
lowered system cost. Consequently, there is no electricity demand costs are accounted for in the model. The existing plants are given
that needs to be fulfilled. Biofuels for transport are treated in a an assumed remaining technical lifetime based on when the plant
similar way; they can be sold at exogenously given market prices was taken into operation.
but no specific transport fuel demand exists in the model. Investments in new production capacity can be done from
The total system cost (the objective value) could thus be described model year 2014. The options for investment in new plants differ
as the cost for the system’s DH production when credited for the between the DH systems due to local conditions, e.g. size of the
income of electricity and biofuels sales. DH demand or availability of natural gas, and include a number of
In the present study, the so-called ‘‘lumpy’’ investment option conventional production technologies, see Table 2, as well as
in MARKAL is used. This turns the MARKAL_WS model into a biomass gasification technologies, see Table 3. The biomass
mixed-integer programming (MIP) model rather than a strict LP gasification technologies included are BIGCC CHP plants and
model. With MIP, selected technologies can be restricted to be biorefineries for production of biofuels for transport. In this study,
available only for implementation at discrete capacity levels as biofuels are represented by SNG and DME although, as previously
opposed to be available at any capacity level without economies mentioned, in reality also other fuels can be produced through
or diseconomies of scale (linearly). gasification.
The conventional production technologies can be implemented
at any capacity level, i.e. linearly. However, since the DH systems
3.1. Modelling introduction of biofuels for transport differ widely in size, the typical plant sizes also differ between the
DH systems. To take economies of scale and the fact that different
It has earlier been shown that the cost-effectiveness of plant sizes have different properties into account, there are,
reducing CO2 through use of biofuels in the transportation sector for the same type of technology (Biomass ST CHP, NGCC CHP,
is low compared to CO2 reductions in the stationary energy sector etc.), different input data in different DH systems, see Table 2.
(e.g. Azar et al., 2003). This indicates that an equivalent cost of CO2 The gasification technologies are handled in another way. In the
emissions in all sectors probably does not give enough economic model, these technologies are available at discrete capacity levels
incentives to create a large-scale introduction of biofuels for and can only be implemented in the specific plant sizes presented
transport in the near-term future. To reach current ambitions in Table 3. The different size options available for biomass
regarding biofuels (e.g. European Council, 2007) it is therefore gasification technologies in each DH system are, therefore, not
likely that some kind of sector-specific policy tool promoting linked to the size of the DH system.4

2 4
All costs and prices related to the model description and model results are Due to the iterative modelling procedure with a large number of model runs
expressed in monetary value of 2004. applied in the study, the option to only allow discrete capacity levels also for
3
Estimations are primarily based on data received from DH companies for conventional technology options was rejected since this substantially increases the
projects presented in OPET and SEA (2004) and Nyström et al. (2007). model solving time.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
172 M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180

Table 2
Conventional energy technologies available as investment options in model.

Technology Efficiencya Investment cost Fixed O&M cost Variable O&M cost Available in DH systemsb
Combined heat and power plantsc Electricity/total (%) (MEUR/MWelectr.) (% of inv. cost/year) (EUR/MWhfuel)

Biomass ST CHP 1 25/105 3.9 2 2.6 S


Biomass ST CHP 2 27/110 2.3 2 2.6 M
Biomass ST CHP 3 30/110 1.7 2 2.6 L
Biomass ST CHP 4 34/110 1.3 2 2.6 XL
Natural gas CC CHP 1 45/89 1.0 2 0.9 S (NG)
Natural gas CC CHP 2 46/89 0.90 2 0.9 M (NG)
Natural gas CC CHP 3 49/90 0.73 2 0.9 XL (NG)
Natural gas engine CHP 40/88 0.67 4.2 All (NG)
Waste ST CHP 1 22/95 6.2 3 13.9d M (W), L (W)
Waste ST CHP 2 27/95 4.5 3 13.9d XL (W)
Coal ST CHP 1 25/89 3.7 2.5 3.3 S
Coal ST CHP 2 27/89 2.2 2.5 3.3 M
Coal ST CHP 3 30/89 1.7 2.5 3.3 L
Coal ST CHP 4 34/89 1.3 2.5 3.3 XL

Heat plantse Heat (%) (MEUR/MWheat) (% of inv. cost/year) (EUR/MWhfuel)

Biomass HOB 1 110 0.40 2 2.0 S


Biomass HOB 2 110 0.36 2 2.0 M
Biomass HOB 3 110 0.33 2 2.0 L, XL
Coal HOB 1 89 0.37 2.5 2.7 S
Coal HOB 2 89 0.33 2.5 2.7 M
Coal HOB 3 89 0.30 2.5 2.7 L, XL
Oil HOB 1 90 0.20 2 0.7 S
Oil HOB 2 90 0.17 2 0.7 M
Oil HOB 3 90 0.16 2 0.7 L, XL
Natural gas HOB 1 90 0.11 2 0.7 S (NG)
Natural gas HOB 2 90 0.10 2 0.7 M (NG)
Natural gas HOB 3 90 0.91 2 0.7 XL (NG)
Waste HOB 1 95 1.1 3 15.6d M (W)
Waste HOB 2 95 1.0 3 15.6d L (W), XL (W)
Electric heat pump 320 (COP) 0.60 0.5 0.7 All

The technologies may be implemented at any capacity level without economies or diseconomies of scale (linearly); however, the same technology type has somewhat
different properties in different DH system since typical plant sizes between the DH systems differ.
a
Efficiencies on LHV (lower heating value) basis.
b
Classification of DH systems (see also Table 1): S=small: Skara, Mark, Falköping, Kungälv (NG), Alingsås (NG), Mariestad, Kungsbacka (NG), Vänersborg; M =medium:
Skövde (W), Lidköping (W), Uddevalla (W), Trollhättan, Mölndal (NG); L= large: Borås (W); XL = extra large: Göteborg (NG; W); All: S, M, L and XL; NG= DH systems with
natural gas grid; W=DH systems with permission for incineration of municipal waste.
c
Plant properties for combined heat and power plants are primarily based on Bärring et al. (2003); complimentarily on Gustavsson (1997) and Danish Energy Authority
et al. (2005). For investment costs, scaling has been used with the general relationship: Cost2=Cost1(Size2/Size1)a, where the scale factor a for each technology type has
been estimated from Bärring et al. (2003).
d
Including income from waste disposal fee, assumed to 22 EUR/MWhwaste.
e
For heat plants, efficiencies are based on Ekström et al. (2002), Danish Energy Authority et al. (2005), Knutsson et al. (2006b). Investment costs are based on Ekström
et al. (2002) and Danish Energy Authority et al. (2005). A scale factor a of 0.87 estimated from Gustavsson et al. (1995) has been used (see c). For fixed O&M the same
percentage of investment cost per year as for CHPs are assumed. Variable O&M is based on Knutsson et al. (2006b).

Except for the technology options summarized in Tables 2 currently valid, by authorities determined, permitted levels for
and 3, the model also includes the option to convert existing municipal waste incineration (see Swedish EPA, 2005). Further-
biomass heat-only boilers (HOBs) to CHP production. In reality, more, the natural gas grid, available in five of the included DH
several different concepts are available for such rebuilding, systems, is in the model not possible to extend. Natural gas-fired
and the costs differ from case to case, e.g. depending on how plants and production plants for SNG are only available options in
the HOB is constructed and which power-to-heat ratio is being DH systems connected to the natural gas grid. Since the DH sector
aimed for (OPET and SEA, 2004). In the model, the rebuilding cost is in focus, power plants without DH production are not at all
is assumed to be 1000 EUR/kWe for a power-to-heat ratio of 0.15 included in the model.
(based on OPET and SEA, 2004). As for the biomass gasification
technologies, this technology option is only available in discrete
size levels, which are individually set by each existing convertible 3.3. CO2 tax and promotion of ‘‘green’’ electricity
biomass HOB. In the model, the technology option is available in 7
of the 15 included DH systems. In addition to the biofuel subsidy, described in Section 3.1, the
A few additional model assumptions regarding energy tech- study operates with two different policy tools: a cost for CO2
nologies could be mentioned. Industrial waste heat and combus- emissions and promotion of biomass-based electricity, here
tion of municipal waste are treated in a somewhat simplified way referred to as ‘‘green’’ electricity. Unlike the biofuel subsidy, these
in the model since these options are not of central interest in the policy tools are given to the model in a completely exogenous way,
study. The capacity and use of industrial waste heat are assumed without feedback from the modelling results.
constant at the level of 2004 for the entire studied time period. The cost laid upon emissions of CO2 is denoted ‘‘CO2 tax’’,
The availability of municipal waste is, for each DH system during although the levels used in the study to a higher degree resemble
the entire studied time period, limited corresponding to the the levels of the EU ETS than the Swedish CO2 tax. In contrast to
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180 173

Table 3
Biomass gasification technologies available as investment options in model.

Technology Capacity Efficiencya Investment costb Fixed O&M costc Variable O&M costc Available in DH systemsd
Combined heat (MWelectr./MWheat) Electricity/total (%) (MEUR/MWelectr.) (% of inv. cost/year) (EUR/MWhfuel)
and power plants

BIGCC CHP 1 10/12 40/86 2.6 2.5 3.3 All


BIGCC CHP 2 30/31 42/86 1.9 2.5 3.3 All
BIGCC CHP 3 60/60 43/86 1.5 2.5 3.3 All
BIGCC CHP 4 100/100 43/86 1.3 2.5 3.3 All
BIGCC CHP 5 130/130 43/86 1.2 2.5 3.3 All

Biofuel production plants (MWbiofuel/MWheat) Biofuel/total (%) (MEUR/MWbiofuel) (% of inv. cost/year) (EUR/MWhfuel)

Biorefinery SNG 1 86.5/29 69/92 (63/85) 1.7 3.5 3.3 All (NG)
Biorefinery SNG 2 173/58 69/92 (63/85) 1.4 3.5 3.3 All (NG)
Biorefinery DME 1 79/19 62/77 (55/68) 2.2 3.5 3.3 All
Biorefinery DME 2 158/38 62/77 (55/68) 1.8 3.5 3.3 All

The technologies are in the model only available at the discrete capacity levels presented in the table (not linearly).
a
All efficiencies are on LHV basis. Efficiencies are, for BIGCC CHP plants, based on Gustavsson and Madlener (2003), Marbe et al. (2004), Uddin and Barreto (2007) and,
for biorefineries, on Ingman et al. (2006). The biorefinery efficiencies without brackets are defined as: biofuel produced divided by biomass and electricity consumed; and:
biofuel and heat produced divided by biomass and electricity consumed. For comparison, the corresponding efficiencies if the consumed electricity was produced internally
within the plant with an electrical efficiency of 30% are presented within brackets.
b
Investment costs are for BIGCC CHP plants based on: Gustavsson and Madlener (2003), Marbe et al. (2004); for biorefineries on: Ingman et al. (2006). Scaling has been
used with the general relationship: Cost2= Cost1(Size2/Size1)a. A scale factor a of 0.7 has been used for both BIGCC and biorefineries, see e.g. Marbe et al. (2004).
c
Based on Marbe et al. (2004), Ingman et al. (2006).
d
For DH systems classification, see Table 2.

both the EU ETS and the Swedish CO2 tax (see Section 2), the CO2 justify differentiated pricing, e.g. differences in vehicle price or
tax used in the present study applies equally to all CO2 emissions vehicle energy efficiency, are neglected.
from non-renewable sources5 regardless of sector, i.e. emissions The Swedish electricity price is mainly determined by the
from heat and power production as well as from transportation variable cost of the marginal production technology in the Nordic
are valued the same. Due to the assumed continuously higher electricity system. For some time, the marginal production
ambitions regarding CO2 emission reductions, the CO2 tax is technology has regularly been coal condensing power generation,
assumed to increase during the studied period. As a model base but NGCC could also be a possible future marginal production
assumption, the level rises linearly from 20 EUR/ton CO2 in model technology in the system (e.g. ECON, 2002). In the model, it is
year 2009 to a level of 40 EUR/ton CO2 at the end of the model assumed that the price-setting technology for electricity is either
time horizon, model year 2029. The subsidy level on green NGCC or coal condensing power generation. The lowest variable
electricity production is, as a base assumption, set to 20 EUR/ electricity production cost of these technologies is assumed to
MWhe, comparable with the levels in the Swedish TGC system determine the model electricity price. The production costs
from past years (see Section 2). The subsidy level is constant depend on the fossil fuel prices, which are constant throughout
throughout the entire studied time horizon. the studied time period, and the CO2 tax, which increases. The
electricity price is divided into three periods per year following
3.4. Energy markets and prices the model seasons used. Due to the variation in electricity
demand over the year (low demand in summer, high demand in
In order to keep the assumptions transparent, the fossil fuel winter) and the difference in efficiencies between the coal
prices excluding the CO2 tax are constant throughout the entire condensing power plants in the system, the efficiency of the
studied time period (in real terms). As base assumptions, the possible coal condensing marginal production technology is
international market prices for crude oil, natural gas and coal are assumed to vary between the model seasons. The difference in
assumed to be 26, 20 and 7 EUR/MWh (50, 39 and 14 USD/barrel efficiencies between NGCC plants is assumed to be small and is
of oil equivalents), respectively (primarily based on Mantzos and neglected. Hence, in the model, for each season the price-setting
Capros, 2006). These international prices are recalculated to prices electricity production technology is assumed according to the
for different commodities (light fuel oil, heavy fuel oil, petrol, etc.) following:
and end-users (DH companies and consumers at filling stations)
with assumed price differences based on statistics (SPI, 2007;  Winter: coal condensing plants with electrical efficiency
World Bank, 2007; Dong Energy, 2007). Since there is no demand (Ze)= 35%, or NGCC plants with Ze =55%.
for transport services in the model, petrol and diesel are not  Spring/autumn: coal condensing plants with Ze =40%, or NGCC
explicitly included as energy carriers. Petrol and diesel are, plants with Ze = 55%.
however, assumed to be price-setting for biofuels for transport  Summer: coal condensing plants with Ze = 45%, or NGCC plants
(SNG and DME), which are included in the model. It is assumed with Ze = 55%.
that biofuels at the filling stations could be sold at the same price
(on energy basis) as petrol and diesel, including CO2 tax. This In the model, different supplies of biomass are assumed: a
implies that possible differences between the fuels that could supply of wood chips at a lower cost and a supply of refined
biomass like wood briquettes or pellets at a slightly higher cost.
5
Fossil fuels and peat are here defined as non-renewable while biomass and The supply of wood chips is limited by assumptions on the local/
municipal waste are defined as renewable. regional potential of forest residues and energy crops in the form
ARTICLE IN PRESS
174 M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180

of Salix. Regarding forest residues, a higher supply limit of phase under atmospheric pressure, the handling of the fuel needs
970 kton DS, equivalent to 5.2 TWh, is assumed from model year to be done under a certain overpressure for the fuel to be in liquid
2014 (based on the estimated potential in Västra Götaland, see phase (5–10 bar). This implies that the distribution cost probably
Section 2). Regarding energy crops, the share of arable land used will be higher than for petrol and diesel. In this study, a DME
for Salix cultivation is, in model year 2009, assumed to be equal to distribution cost of 22 EUR/MWh is assumed. This includes both
the national target level of 0.9% (see Section 2), which, for the the costs for transport from the production site to the filling
studied region, corresponds to approximately 4400 ha. Further- station and the costs at the filling station, and is approximately
more, it is assumed that the cultivated area increases with 80% twice the corresponding cost for diesel (based on Brandberg et al.,
every model period (5 years), analogous to the targeted increase 1997).
on national level from 2005 to 2010. Consequently, about 9% of Transportation of SNG can be done in different ways, e.g. in
the total arable land in the studied region, or 45 000 ha, is pipelines or in compressed form on trucks. Since several parts of
assumed to be used for cultivation of Salix in the last model year the distribution chain for SNG are relatively capital intensive, not
(2029). It is further assumed that the Salix production is 60 MWh/ least the filling stations that are significantly costlier than for
ha, which is in the upper range of today’s yields from new Salix liquid fuels, the amount of delivered fuel should be a factor of
plantations (Statistics Sweden et al., 2007). At the end of the significance for the cost-effectiveness of the distribution. In the
studied period, this results in an upper constraint on wood model, two different distribution costs for SNG are assumed: a
chips from energy crops of about 2.7 TWh. Since refined biomass lower one at 28 EUR/MWh6 and a higher one at 39 EUR/MWh.7
like wood briquettes and pellets are less bulky than wood chips The lower cost level represents distribution in the natural gas grid,
and can be more easily transported, an international supply is available in parts of the studied region, and distribution at large
assumed, which, from the perspective of the studied region, is filling stations (in terms of amount delivered fuel). The higher cost
considered to be unlimited. level represents truck distribution in combination with smaller
In the beginning of the studied period, the biomass prices are filling stations. The lower cost distribution is, in the model,
assumed to be approximately equal to the Swedish average prices limited while the higher cost distribution is not. The limitation of
of wood chips and wood pellets/briquettes in 2003–2006 (SEA, the lower cost distribution is in model year 2009 assumed to be
2007). As the CO2 tax rises, the demand for biomass is likely to 0.43 TWh and thereafter is assumed to rise linearly and in model
increase and eventually cause biomass prices to rise. It is assumed year 2029 reach a level of 1.73 TWh. This corresponds to an
that it will be favourable to substitute biomass for coal in coal increase from 2.5% to 10% of the total transport fuel use in the
power plants and that the price of biomass under high CO2 taxes studied region in 2004, or an increase from 5% to 20% of the total
will be connected to the coal price (see also Axelsson et al., 2007). transport fuel use in the municipalities with access to the natural
The price of wood chips is, therefore, in the later part of the gas grid (SEA and Statistics Sweden, 2005).
studied time period, assumed to be equal to the price of coal,
including CO2 tax. The price difference between wood chips and 3.6. Model cases analysed
wood pellets is assumed to be constant throughout the whole
studied period and is determined by the approximate price Except for the reference case (‘‘REF’’), in which the model base
difference in 2003–2006 (SEA, 2007). Assumptions regarding assumptions described in previous sections apply, several addi-
biomass prices and availability of the local supply of wood chips tional cases with alternative assumptions are included in the
are visualized in Fig. 1. analysis. The alternative cases investigate how changes in certain
parameters one at a time affect the model outcome compared to
3.5. Distribution of biofuels for transport the reference case. In each alternative case, one parameter value is
altered while all other parameter values are kept the same, with
As previously mentioned, biofuels for transport are, in this the exception for those parameters directly affected by the change
study, represented by two options, DME and SNG. Since the according to assumed relationships described in earlier sections.
distribution costs for these fuels will differ from conventional The chosen cases represent a selection of relevant variations in
transport fuels (petrol/diesel), distribution costs are included in parameter values for which future levels are highly uncertain. For
the model. all model cases, the subsidy levels required in order to obtain
DME have characteristics similar to LPG (liquefied petroleum different numbers of investments in biorefineries, and thereby to
gas) and can be transported on trucks. Since DME is in gaseous reach certain amounts of transport biofuel production, are
assessed according to the procedure outlined in Section 3.1.
28 9 In Table 4, all analysed cases are presented and important
input parameter values given. In case ‘‘NG Lo’’, the international
26 8
price for natural gas is assumed to be 15 EUR/MWh instead of 20
24 Price Wood Pellets 7 EUR/MWh as in the base assumptions. A lower natural gas price
Availability Energy
22 6 also affects the electricity price (see Section 3.4). Alternative
[EUR/MWh]

Crops (Salix)
assumptions for policy tools are made in cases ‘‘GE Lo’’ and
[TWh]

20 5
18 4 6
Price Wood Chips Cost for distribution of SNG in the natural gas grid is assumed to 15 EUR/
16 3 MWh (based on Ekengren, 2006), investment cost for an SNG filling station is
Availability assumed to 0.4 MEUR, and filling station operation and maintenance cost is
14 Forest Residues 2 assumed to 8 EUR/MWh (based on Petterson et al., 2006). The annual amount of
12 1 delivered fuel is assumed to 8 GWh per filling station (fuel supply to about 700
Price Hard Coal incl. CO2 tax
cars), and an annuity factor of 0.096 (15 years, 5%) is used.
7
10 0 Cost for distribution of compressed SNG on truck is assumed to 18 EUR/MWh
2004 2009 2014 2019 2024 2029 (based on Petterson et al., 2006), investment cost for an SNG filling station is
assumed to 0.4 MEUR, and filling station operation and maintenance cost is
Fig. 1. Base assumptions regarding availability of local, lower cost biomass (wood assumed to 8 EUR/MWh (based on Petterson et al., 2006). The annual amount of
chips) as well as price levels for biomass (wood chips and wood pellets) and coal delivered fuel is assumed to 3 GWh per filling station (fuel supply to about 250
including CO2 tax. cars), and an annuity factor of 0.096 (15 years, 5%) is used.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180 175

Table 4
Important model parameter values regarding policy tools, energy prices and biomass gasification plant investment costs for the reference case (REF) and for the alternative
cases.

REF NG Lo GE Lo BIO Lo OIL Hi CO2 Hi INV Hi

Policy tools
CO2 tax (EUR/ton CO2) 20/40 30/60
Subsidy Green Electricity (EUR/MWh) 20 10

Energy prices
Natural gas (EUR/MWh) 24.7 19.4
Hard coal (EUR/MWh) 7.2
Fuel oil, light (EUR/MWh) 33.8 46.7
Fuel oil, heavy (EUR/MWh) 27.7 40.6
Petrol/diesel (EUR/MWh) 44.8 57.8
a
Wood chips (EUR/MWh) 15.6/20.4 17.1/26.9
Wood pellets (EUR/MWh) 22.2/27.0 23.7/33.6
Electricity Winter (EUR/MWh) 49.0/61.2 44.3/51.7 57.6/68.6
Electricity Intermediate (EUR/MWh) 42.9/59.3 42.9/51.7 51.1/68.6
Electricity Summer (EUR/MWh) 38.1/52.7 38.1/51.7 45.4/67.3

Investment costs
BIGCC CHP 1–5 See Table 3 100% 125%
Biorefinery SNG 1–2 See Table 3 100% 125%
Biorefinery DME 1–2 See Table 3 100% 125%

For the alternative cases, only the parameter values that differ from the base assumptions (in case REF) are given. The fuel prices refer to prices paid by DH plants except for
the price of petrol/diesel, which refer to the price at filling stations (without taxes). The fossil fuel prices are given excluding the CO2 tax. If the parameter value is not
constant throughout the whole studied time period, the values for model year 2009 and 2029 are given (separated with /).
a
Availability of wood chips is unlimited.

‘‘CO2 Hi’’. In GE Lo, the subsidy promoting green electricity assumed conditions, a competitive technology alternative and
production is 50% lower than in the base assumptions, and in CO2 accounts for a considerable part of the DH production. Until the
Hi, the CO2 tax is 50% higher than in the base assumptions. Except last model year (2029), production from BIGCC CHP exclusively
for having an impact on the fossil fuel prices including the cost of takes place in the biggest DH system, Göteborg, in which two
CO2 emissions, a modification of the CO2 tax also changes the 130 MWe BIGCC CHP plants are invested in. In the last model year,
biomass prices as well as the price of electricity (see Section 3.4). two smaller BIGCC CHP plants, 10 and 30 MWe, are also included
In case ‘‘BIO Lo’’, the restrictions on the availability of the lower in the small-/medium-sized DH systems Kungsbacka and
cost biomass are disregarded. In case ‘‘OIL Hi’’, the price of crude Trollhättan, respectively. Also production from municipal waste
oil is 75 USD/barrel instead of 50 USD/barrel as in the base CHP is to some extent increased during the studied time period,
assumptions, i.e. 39 instead of 26 EUR/MWh. In case ‘‘INV Hi’’, the but the assumed permitted level of municipal waste incineration
uncertainty in investment costs for biomass gasification-based constitutes a constraint for further increase.
plants is addressed; the investment costs for these technologies With the base assumptions, which apply in the reference case,
are here assumed to be 25% higher than in the base assumptions. the subsidy threshold level at which production of biofuels begins
A discount rate of 5% is used in all cases. to take place (in 2014) is calculated to 36 EUR/MWh. Fig. 2b
illustrates the DH production in the reference case with the
biofuel subsidy at this level. The introduced biofuel production
4. Results capacity is an SNG plant, placed in Göteborg. Due to economies of
scale, the bigger of the two discrete plant sizes available for this
In this section, the results of the model calculations are technology (see Table 3) is chosen (173 MWSNG). The primary
presented. First, the reference case is analysed and, thereafter, the impact on the system because of the introduction of biofuel
impact on the model results from the parameter variation in the production is that less investment in the BIGCC CHP technology
alternative cases are considered. In the last part of the section, CO2 takes place compared to situations with lower biofuel subsidies.
emissions associated with the studied system are examined. This time, a single 130 MWe BIGCC CHP plant is included in the DH
Fig. 2a–d shows the DH production in the reference case, system of Göteborg, and in the end of the studied period, also in
classified according to technologies for different levels of the this case, two smaller BIGCC CHP plants are included in the
subsidy for transport biofuels. Fig. 2a illustrates the DH previously mentioned two small-/middle-sized DH systems. The
production without biofuel subsidy. As expected, there is no DH production from BIGCC CHP is primarily replaced, except by
biofuel production in a cost-optimized system under these the waste heat from the SNG plant, by a larger production from
conditions. The DH production is, in the first part of the studied conventional biomass ST CHP plants. The main reason for the
time period, to a large degree based on HOBs but, with time, CHP change from BIGCC CHP to biomass ST CHP with an increasing
production increases while HOBs are phased out. Heat pumps biofuel subsidy is the limitations in the local, lower cost, supply of
(HPs) account, in the beginning of the period, for a relatively large biomass (forest residues and energy crops). When a large part of
share of the DH production while in the end of the period the the available lower cost biomass is allocated to biofuel production,
production from HPs is negligible. It is primarily different types of the heat efficiency of biomass CHP technologies becomes of
biomass CHP production plants that account for a production greater significance since a low use of the costlier biomass (wood
increase. Of the existing biomass HOBs, a large share is converted pellets) is strived for. Conventional biomass ST CHP is, therefore,
into CHP units, and there is a significant increase in the relatively more competitive compared to BIGCC CHP in a situation
production from conventional biomass ST CHP. CHP generation with biofuel production (Fig. 2b) than in a situation without
through biomass gasification in BIGCC CHP plants is, under the biofuel production (Fig. 2a).
ARTICLE IN PRESS
176 M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180

10 Other 10 Other
Peat HOB Peat HOB
9 HP NG HOB 9 HP NG HOB SNG Biorefinery

8 8
7 7
NG CHP BIGCC CHP NG CHP BIGCC CHP
6 6
[TWh]

[TWh]
5 Bio ST CHP 5 Bio ST CHP
4 Bio HOB Conv. Bio HOB to CHP 4 Bio HOB Conv. Bio HOB to CHP

3 3
Ind. Waste Heat Ind. Waste Heat
2 2
Waste ST CHP 1 Waste ST CHP
1
Waste HOB Waste HOB
0 0
2004 2009 2014 2019 2024 2029 2004 2009 2014 2019 2024 2029
No biofuel subsidy Biofuel subsidy = 36 EUR/MWh
10 10
Other Peat HOB DME Biorefinery Other Peat HOB DME Biorefinery
9 HP NG HOB SNG Biorefinery 9 HP NG HOB SNG Biorefinery
8 8
7 7
NG CHP NG CHP
6 BIGCC CHP 6

[TWh]
[TWh]

5 Bio ST CHP 5 Bio ST CHP


4 Bio HOB Conv. Bio HOB to CHP 4 Bio HOB Conv. Bio HOB to CHP

3 3
Ind. Waste Heat Ind. Waste Heat
2 2
Waste ST CHP 1 Waste ST CHP
1
Waste HOB Waste HOB
0 0
2004 2009 2014 2019 2024 2029 2004 2009 2014 2019 2024 2029
Biofuel subsidy = 38 EUR/MWh Biofuel subsidy = 39 EUR/MWh

Fig. 2. Production of DH in the reference case for different levels of the biofuel subsidy and, thereby, different numbers of biorefineries included in the system: (a) no
biorefineries, (b) one biorefinery, (c) two biorefineries and (d) three biorefineries

The same general features can be noted when the biofuel ‘‘b’’ denotes a situation with a biofuel production of about 1.4 TWh
subsidy is raised further. In Fig. 2c, the DH production in the (one SNG plant), ‘‘c’’ denotes a situation with a biofuel production
reference case with a biofuel subsidy of 38 EUR/MWh is of about 2.6 TWh (one SNG and one DME plant), and ‘‘d’’ denotes a
illustrated. At this subsidy level, in addition to an SNG plant also situation with a biofuel production of about 3.9 TWh (one SNG
a DME plant is invested in. The DME plant has a capacity of and two DME plants). For comparison, it can be mentioned that
158 MWDME and is placed in Borås, the second largest DH system the biofuel production level in ‘‘d’’ corresponds to about 22% of the
in the studied region. The lower cost quota of the SNG distribution total transport fuel use in the studied region in 2004 (SEA and
(see Section 3.5) is at this point filled, and this is the main reason Statistics Sweden, 2005). The electricity use refers only to the
for a DME plant instead of a second SNG plant. There is, under electricity use in plants connected to DH and the produced
these conditions, place only for one BIGCC CHP plant in the electricity refers only to the production of electricity in CHP plants
system, a 130 MWe plant placed in Göteborg. Heat production connected to DH (other electricity use in the region and electricity
from the biorefineries as well as from HPs constitutes a larger production in power plants not connected to DH is not included in
share of the DH production compared to cases with a lower the model). Note that Fig. 3a and b illustrates the same results but
biofuel subsidy. arranged differently: by biofuel production level (a–d) in Fig. 3a
At a subsidy level of 39 EUR/MWh, three biorefineries for and by model case (REF, NG Lo, GE Lo, BIO Lo, OIL Hi, CO2 Hi,
production of biofuels for transport are invested in, one SNG plant INV Hi) in Fig. 3b.
and two DME plants. The second DME plant (again with a capacity The reference case and the alternative cases show the same
of 158 MWDME) is placed in the DH system of Mölndal. Fig. 2d kind of results regarding the trade-off between biofuels and
illustrates the cost-optimized DH production under these condi- electricity. All cases have in common that as the production of
tions. With this amount of biofuel production in the system, no biofuels increases due to higher subsidies, the production of
investments in BIGCC CHP take place. Instead, conventional electricity decreases and at the same time the use of electricity
biomass ST CHP gets a major share of the DH production. increases. As previously stated for the reference case, it is
Fig. 3a and b illustrates the electricity production, electricity particularly the conditions for investments in BIGCC CHP that
use, production of biofuels and the corresponding required biofuel deteriorate with increasing biofuel subsidy, mainly due to the
subsidy level, for all analysed cases for model year 2019. For each thereby following increased competition for the local, lower cost,
case, four different threshold levels for the biofuel subsidy and, biomass. The increased use of electricity is primarily because of
thereby, four different amounts of produced biofuel are calculated. the electricity use in biorefineries and in HPs. In most cases, no
In all tested cases, the same biorefineries as in the reference case BIGCC CHP plants are included in the system by a subsidy level
are invested in and utilized to full extent. Consequently, all cases that allows three biorefineries.
have the same levels of biofuel production. In the figures, the Lower natural gas prices could lead to lower electricity prices,
different biofuel production levels within each case are labelled and lower electricity prices decrease the incentives for BIGCC CHP.
a–d; ‘‘a’’ denotes a situation without biofuel production (0 plants), This situation is observed in case NG Lo. Already with one
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180 177

Use El. Biofuel Fossil El. Bio El. BIGCC El. Biofuel Sub.
8000 45

7000 40

6000

Subsidy Biofuel [EUR/MWh]


35
Production [GWh]

5000 30

4000 25

3000 20

2000 15

1000 10

0 5

-1000 0
REF
NGLo
GELo
BIOLo
OILHi
CO2Hi
INVHi
REF
NGLo
GELo
BIOLo
OILHi
CO2Hi
INVHi
REF
NGLo
GELo
BIOLo
OILHi
CO2Hi
INVHi
REF
NGLo
GELo
BIOLo
OILHi
CO2Hi
INVHi
a b c d

Use El. Bio El. BIGCC El. Fossil El. Biofuel Biofuel Sub.
8000 45

7000 40

6000 35

Subsidy Biofuel [EUR/MWh]


5000 30
Production [GWh]

4000 25

3000 20

2000 15

1000 10

0 5

-1000 0
a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d

REF NG Lo GE Lo BIO Lo OIL Hi CO2 Hi INV Hi

Fig. 3. The charts show electricity production, use of electricity (Use El.), production of biofuels for transport (Biofuel) and the corresponding required biofuel subsidy level
(Biofuel Sub.) for all analysed cases in model year 2019. The electricity production is divided in production from: fossil fuel CHP (Fossil El.), conventional biomass CHP
including converted biomass HOBs (Bio El.) and BIGCC CHP (BIGCC El.). For each model case, four biofuel subsidy threshold levels (indicated by filled circles) for when a new
biorefinery is included in the system have been calculated: (a) no biorefineries, (b) one biorefinery, (c) two biorefineries and (d) three biorefineries. In (a), the results are
arranged by number of biorefineries (or equally; amount of biofuel produced) and in (b), by model case.

biorefinery in the system, the conditions for BIGCC CHP are not irrelevant. The result is that BIGCC CHP is used to a substantially
favourable enough for investment. Poorer conditions for BIGCC higher degree, and conventional biomass ST CHP to a substantially
CHP reduce the competition for biomass and, consequently, lower degree, than in the reference case. However, due to the fact
biofuel production becomes profitable at a somewhat lower that the demand for DH is limited, there is still a competition
subsidy level for the corresponding amount of biofuel. A redu- between biofuel production and BIGCC CHP production. As
ced subsidy for green electricity, as in case GE Lo, has a similar mentioned earlier, the model requires a demand for all heat
impact. Again, BIGCC CHP production becomes a less attr- produced; cooling of excess heat is not allowed.
active investment alternative than in the reference case. The Since oil just in a very marginal way is used for DH production
biofuel production pushes the BIGCC CHP out of the system at in the reference case, a higher oil price, as in case OIL Hi, is
lower production level, and the required level of the biofuel essentially limited to influence the threshold levels of the biofuel
subsidy, for the same amount of biofuel, is lower than in the subsidy through a higher petrol/diesel price. A higher petrol/
reference case. diesel price means that biofuels can be sold at a higher price, and
An unlimited supply of the lower cost biomass (wood chips), as the biofuel subsidy level needed to make biofuel production
in case BIO Lo, makes the issue of competition for biomass profitable is, therefore, lower.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
178 M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180

CO2 Electricity CO2 Biofuels CO2 Fossil Fuels Biomass Use


4000 12

3500
10
3000
Negative CO2 Emissions [kton]

2500 8

Biomass Use [TWh]


2000
6
1500

1000 4

500
2
0

-500 0
a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d a b c d

REF NG Lo GE Lo BIO Lo OIL Hi CO2 Hi INV Hi

Fig. 4. The chart shows the studied system’s negative CO2 emissions and total use of biomass for all analysed cases in model year 2019. The electricity production is
assumed to replace (fossil) electricity production at the margin and the biofuels are assumed to replace petrol or diesel. Within each model case, different levels of the
biofuel subsidy give rise to different numbers of biorefineries in the system: (a) no biorefineries, (b) one biorefinery, (c) two biorefineries and (d) three biorefineries. For the
same number of biorefineries, the same amount of biofuel is produced.

A higher tax on CO2 emissions, as in case CO2 Hi, has somewhat bars while the ‘‘saved’’ CO2 emissions outside the system,
counteracting effects. On the one hand, the electricity price is due to the net production of electricity9 and production of
higher, which is favourable for the BIGCC CHP technology, but on biofuels10 within the system, are represented as positive bars. For
the other hand, the biomass prices are also higher, due to the all tested cases, it is clear that the CO2 emission savings outside
assumed connection to the coal price (see Section 3.4). In total, the system by far exceed the CO2 emissions from the system’s use
the conditions for BIGCC CHP are more advantageous than in the of fossil fuels. The CO2 emissions due to the fossil fuel use is
reference case, i.e. the higher electricity price has a greater impact relatively constant on a comparably low level for all model cases
than the higher biomass prices. Due to the higher carbon content and biofuel production levels (a–d), while the CO2 emission
in coal compared to oil, an increase of the CO2 tax increases savings differ in a wider range. It is notable that although biofuels
the biomass prices relatively more than the petrol/diesel price. for transport are regarded as completely CO2 neutral and to full
This, in combination with the higher electricity price and the more extent replace petrol and diesel, the CO2 benefit of biofuels are
advantageous conditions for BIGCC CHP, makes production of in many cases small and in some cases even negative, i.e. as the
biofuels less favourable than in the reference case, and higher production of biofuels increases in each model case (from ‘‘a’’ to
biofuel subsidy levels are therefore required for the same amount ‘‘d’’) the CO2 emission savings increase very little or in some cases
of biofuel production. decrease slightly. This is explained by the decrease in electricity
Higher investment costs for biomass gasification-based plants production and the increase in electricity use that follow from the
obviously decreases the competitiveness for these technologies. The biofuel production. As previously stated, the marginal electricity
impact on the production and on the required biofuel subsidy for a production that is affected by the studied system’s activities
25% increase of the investment costs compared to the reference case is assumed to be based on fossil fuels, either coal or natural gas
is seen in case INV Hi. The resulting production is very similar to (see Section 3.4). As opposed to the modest CO2 emission savings,
what earlier have been described for NG Lo and GE Lo. However, the a distinct increase in the total use of biomass can, for each model
required biofuel subsidy levels are, in this case, higher. case, be seen from an increased biofuel production.
The studied system, i.e. the DH sector in Västra Götaland and in
Greater Göteborg, gives rise to CO2 emissions due to its use of
fossil fuels8 and electricity. However, the production of biofuels
and electricity within the studied system will replace conven-
9
tional transport fuels (petrol and diesel) and electricity production The net electricity production (electricity produced subtracted with
electricity used) is assumed to replace electricity production on the margin. As
outside the system and, thereby, contribute to less CO2 emissions.
previously mentioned, see Section 3.4, the marginal electricity production is
The studied system’s net impact on CO2 emissions is, therefore, different for different model cases, model seasons and model years but is either
of relevance. Fig. 4 illustrates the negative CO2 emissions, or the NGCC or coal condensing power generation (with varying efficiencies). For all cases
CO2 emission savings, together with the total biomass use of the except for NG Lo and CO2 Hi, the marginal electricity production is in model year
system for all analysed cases for model year 2019. The CO2 2019 based on coal in summer and in spring/autumn while based on natural gas in
winter. For NG Lo and CO2 Hi, also the marginal production in spring/autumn is
emissions from fossil fuel use are represented as negative
based on natural gas (the resulting electricity CO2 emission factors that give rise to
Fig. 4 are in the range 367–820 kg CO2/MWhe).
10
The biofuels are assumed to replace petrol or diesel. A CO2 emission factor
8
Biomass is considered CO2 neutral. for petrol/diesel of 259 kg CO2/MWhf is used.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180 179

5. Discussion and conclusions With a limited amount of resources, prioritizing between


available options is essential. In the context of this study, in
In the present study, the cost-effectiveness of different particular the constraint on the availability of the local, lower cost
applications of biomass gasification is analysed. The study biomass and the restriction of the DH demand are of importance,
investigates whether, and under what conditions, combined heat and prioritizing between whether to produce green electricity or
and power (CHP) generation in biomass integrated gasification transport biofuels is necessary. Even though imported biomass is
combined cycle (BIGCC) plants, as well as production of biofuels available to an unlimited extent, just slightly more expensive than
for transport in biomass gasification biorefineries, could be the local biomass, the study clearly shows a trade-off situation
competitive alternatives to conventional technology options in between investments in BIGCC CHP and investments in biorefi-
district heating (DH) systems. neries and, thereby, between production of electricity and
In the model-generated results, CHP generation in BIGCC plants is production of transport biofuels. What is observed in the model
to a high degree included in cost-optimized DH systems and is results is that when a large part of the available lower cost
thereby, under the assumed conditions, a cost-competitive technol- biomass resources is allocated to production of biofuels through
ogy alternative. Most favourable conditions for the BIGCC CHP high biofuel subsidy levels, conventional biomass ST CHP with
technology is found in the biggest DH system in the studied region, high heat efficiency satisfies the heat demand to a lower total
Göteborg, since the heat demand in this system is high enough to system cost than the BIGCC CHP technology. The best conditions
allow a BIGCC CHP plant of larger size, which is advantageous due to for BIGCC CHP plants are, therefore, found in situations with low
economies of scale. In the present study, the influence of plant size ambitions regarding biofuel production, i.e. with low biofuel
on costs for distribution of biomass and heat is, however, not taken subsidy levels. With a marginal electricity production based on
into account. These are factors that work against positive plant size fossil fuels, the negative impact regarding CO2 emissions of less
scale effects (see e.g. Dornburg and Faaij, 2001). The income from production of electricity in CHP plants is significant. Since a high
electricity production is a central parameter regarding the competi- biofuel production level means a lower production level of
tiveness of the BIGCC technology since the main difference in output electricity in the system than what otherwise is possible, the
between a capital-intensive BIGCC CHP plant and a conventional net CO2 benefit of biofuels for transport is small. Goals of
biomass steam turbine (ST) CHP plant is the power-to-heat ratio, increasing renewable electricity production and at the same time
which is higher for the BIGCC option. The income from the electricity increasing production of biofuels could therefore, to some extent,
production depends on the electricity price and on the level of the be counteractive. If cooling of waste heat, or biorefineries and
green electricity subsidy. The electricity price depends in turn on biomass power plants not connected to DH, were included options
several factors, such as fuel prices and the CO2 tax level. While a high in the analysis, the competition induced by the limited DH
CO2 tax level is favourable for the BIGCC technology, the study demand would to large extent be removed. However, from the
indicates that the opposite could be the case for biorefineries perspective of efficient resource utilization it is desirable to make
producing biofuels for transport. use of waste heat from production of electricity and biofuels.
In the present study, synthetic natural gas (SNG) and dimethyl In the present study, a tax for regulation of CO2 emissions is
ether (DME) are included transport biofuel options. Also for assumed. If instead, a well-functioning CO2 emission cap system is
biorefineries, the plant size is a factor of importance for the assumed, the difference in CO2 emissions due to technical changes
economic performance. Since the heat production from biorefi- would always be zero (an emission reduction would be replaced
neries often is small compared to the output of biofuels, there are, by a corresponding emission increase elsewhere in the system).
however, several more possible DH systems that allow a larger The cost to reach the emission cap level will, however, be different
scale biorefinery than a larger scale BIGCC CHP plant. Biorefineries depending on which technical solutions that are applied. The
constitute in such way a possibility to make use of economies of interpretation of the results of the present study (Fig. 4) in the
scale also in small- and mid-sized DH systems. With the oil price light of a CO2 emission cap system would therefore be that
assumptions used in the study (50–75 USD/barrel), biofuels solutions that cause high CO2 emissions would imply high costs to
cannot economically compete with petrol and diesel without reach emission cap levels, and vice versa.
promotion by policy measures. For the introduction of large-scale Quantitative results, such as cost-effective, technology-specific
biofuel production in cost-optimized DH systems, a required production levels or required biofuel subsidy levels, are by their
biofuel subsidy level of 30–40 EUR/MWh was calculated under character to a large extent related to the assumptions made and
assumptions of an oil price of 50 USD/barrel, a CO2 tax level the region studied, in this case the Västra Götaland region and
increasing from 20 to 40 EUR/ton CO2 from 2009 to 2029 and with Greater Göteborg. However, similar regions with, for instance,
base assumptions regarding plant investment costs.11 A higher oil a large DH system surrounded by smaller DH systems of different
price would imply a lower subsidy level requirement, while a sizes or with a comparable blend of existing production
higher CO2 tax would lead to a higher required subsidy level since technologies can be found in many locations, and the results
this would involve an increased competition for biomass and ought thus to be relevant also for other regions. The study
higher biomass prices. In a situation where biomass prices are illustrates that regional energy planning could have an important
connected to the coal price including the cost of CO2, as suggested role to play in order to achieve energy-efficient and cost-efficient
in the present study, an increase in CO2 tax implies a larger energy systems. The approach could not only generate knowledge
increase in biomass prices than in the petrol/diesel price, due to of appropriate technology choices but also give insights of suitable
the higher carbon content in coal, and this would lower the plant locations to a higher degree than what is possible with more
profitability of biofuels for transport. aggregated approaches regarding geography and system design.
The system that is here studied and optimized is, however, not
controlled by a single actor who simply could implement suitable
11
If adding the estimated required subsidy levels to the assumed CO2 tax we actions on the regional level. Instead, the system consists of a
receive figures that can be compared to the currently used taxation system in number of subsystems, each controlled by different actors with
Sweden. For example, in model year 2029 the CO2 tax is 40 EUR/ton CO2 or about probably a bigger interest of optimizing their own subsystem
10 EUR/MWh for petrol/diesel. Required subsidy levels of 30–40 EUR/MWh plus
the CO2 tax then add up to 40–50 EUR/MWh. Today’s fuel taxes in Sweden on
than the overall system as a whole. The likely outcome would be a
petrol and diesel, which biofuels currently are exempt from, are 61 and 41 EUR/ sub-optimized overall system and not an optimized system, which
MWh, respectively. is the case in the present study. The results are, therefore, not so
ARTICLE IN PRESS
180 M. Börjesson, E.O. Ahlgren / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 168–180

much a prediction of a future development but rather an Johansson, T., 2001. Biobränslen i Västra Götaland—en förstudie (Biomass in Västra
illustration of what could be, and the interpretation of the results Götaland—a prestudy). The County Administration of Västra Götaland,
Publication 2001: 26, Vänersborg (in Swedish).
must be done in the light of these prerequisites. KAM, 2003. Final report from the ecocyclic pulp mill programme, 1996–2002.
KAM-Report A100, STFI Packforsk, Stockholm.
Knutsson, D., 2005. Simulating conditions for combined heat and power in the
Acknowledgments Swedish District Heating Sector. Diss. Chalmers University of Technology,
Göteborg, New Series No. 2356.
Knutsson, D., Sahlin, J., Werner, S., Ekvall, T., Ahlgren, E.O., 2006a. HEATSPOT—a
The authors are grateful for the funding of this study provided simulation tool for national district heating analyses. Energy 31, 278–293.
through the Biokombi Rya project by Göteborg Energi AB, Göteborg Knutsson, D., Werner, S., Ahlgren., E.O., 2006b. Combined heat and power in the
Swedish district heating sector—impact of green certificates and CO2 trading
Energi Research Foundation and the Swedish Energy Agency, as on new investments. Energy Policy 34, 3942–3952.
well as through a research grant from the Adlerbertska Research Lolou, R., Goldstein, G., Noble, K., 2004. Documentation for the MARKAL family of
Foundation. Thanks to Bengt Johansson, FOI (Swedish Defence models. Energy Technology Systems Analysis Programme. Available at /http://
www.etsap.orgS (2004-11-16).
Research Agency)/Lund University, for valuable comments. Mantzos, L., Capros, P., 2006. European Energy and Transport Trends to
2030—Update 2005. Directorate-General for Energy and Transport, European
References Commission, Luxembourg.
Marbe, Å., Harvey, S., Berntsson, T., 2004. Biofuel gasification combined heat and
power—new implementation opportunities resulting from combined supply of
Axelsson, E., Harvey, S., Berntsson, T., 2007. A tool for creating energy market process steam and district heating. Energy 29, 1117–1137.
scenarios for evaluation of investments in energy intensive industry. In: Nyström, I., Ahlgren, E., Andersson, E., Börjesson, M., Fahle n, E., Harvey, S., Ingman,
Proceedings of the 20th International Conference ECOS, Padova, June 25–28, D., Karlsson, S., Larsson, E., Löfgren, Å., 2007. Biokombi Rya—Biobränsleför-
2007, pp. 1587–1594. gasning satt i system (Biokombi Rya—Biomass Gasification in a
Azar, C., Lindgren, K., Andersson, B.A., 2003. Global energy scenarios meeting System). Chalmers Energy Centre—CEC, Report CEC 2007:2, Göteborg
stringent CO2 constraints—cost-effective fuel choices in the transportation (in Swedish).
sector. Energy Policy 31, 961–976. OPET, SEA (Swedish Energy Agency), 2004. OPET RES-e: El från förnybara
Brandberg, Å., Sävmark, B., Landälv, I., Lindblom, M., 1997. DME—drivmedel för energikällor—Förutsättningar för småskalig kraftvärmeproduktion från
dieselmotorer (DME—fuel for diesel engines). Swedish Transport and Com- biobränsle i Västra Götaland (Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources—
munication Research Board, KFB-meddelande 1997, vol. 30, Stockholm Conditions for Small Scale Combined Heat and Power Production from Biomass
(in Swedish). in Västra Götaland). Available at /www.opet.seS (2006-03-22) (in Swedish).
Bärring, M., Nyström, O., Nilsson, P.-A., Olsson, F., Egard, M., Jonsson, P., 2003. El Petterson, A., Losciale, M., Liljemark, S., 2006. LCNG-studie—Möjligheter med LNG
från nya anläggningar—2003 (Power from new plants—2003). Elforsk, Report i fordonsgasförsörjningen i Sverige (LCNG-study—possibilities with LNG in the
03:14, Stockholm (in Swedish). vehicle gas supply in Sweden). Report SGC 167, Malmö (in Swedish).
Carlson, A., 2003. Energy systems and the climate dilemma: reflecting the impact Renova A.B., 2005. Miljörapport 2004 (Environmental Report 2004). Renova AB,
on CO2 emissions by reconstructing regional energy systems. Energy Policy 31, Göteborg (in Swedish).
951–959. Salvia, M., Pietrapertosa, F., Cosmi, C., Cuomo, V., Macchiato, M., 2004. Approaching
Danish Energy Authority, Elkraft System, Eltra, 2005. Technology Data for the Kyoto targets: a case study for Basilicata region (Italy). Renewable and
Electricity and Heat Generating Plants. Danish Energy Authority, Copenhagen. Sustainable Energy Reviews 8, 73–90.
Dong Energy, 2007. Listpris på naturgas (list price on natural gas). Website SEA (Swedish Energy Agency) and Statistics Sweden, 2005. Deliveries of gasoline
information. Available at /www.dongenergy.seS (2007-02-18) (in Swedish). and fuel oil divided into municipalities in 2004. Statistics Sweden, EN 13 SM
Dornburg, V., Faaij, A.P.C., 2001. Efficiency and economy of wood-fired biomass 0501, Örebro.
energy systems in relation to scale regarding heat and power generation using SEA (Swedish Energy Agency), 2006a. Energy in Sweden 2006. Swedish Energy
combustion and gasification technologies. Biomass and Bioenergy 21, 91–108. Agency, ET 2006:45. Eskilstuna.
ECON, 2002. Marginal elproduktion och CO2-utsläpp i Sverige (Marginal electricity SEA (Swedish Energy Agency), 2006b. Energy in Sweden 2006—Facts and Figures.
production and CO2 emissions in Sweden). Swedish Energy Agency, ER Swedish Energy Agency, ET 2006:44, Eskilstuna.
14:2002, Eskilstuna (in Swedish). SEA (Swedish Energy Agency), 2007. Prisblad för biobränslen, torv m.m. Nr 3/2007
Ekengren, T., 2006. Fordonsgas Sverige AB personal communication. (Price sheet for biofuel, peat etc. No. 3/2007). Swedish Energy Agency,
Ekström, C., Amnell, G., Anheden, M., Eidenstam, L., Kirkegaard, G., 2002. Eskilstuna (in Swedish).
Biobränsle från skogen (biofuel from the forest). Swedish Energy Agency, ER SOU (The Swedish Government Official Reports), 2004. Introduktion av förnybara
9:2002, Eskilstuna (in Swedish). fordonsbränslen (Introduction of renewable fuels for vehicles). SOU 2004: 133,
European Commission, 2000. Action plan to improve energy efficiency in the Ministry of the Environment, Stockholm (in Swedish).
European Community. Communication from the Commission to the Council, SOU (The Swedish Government Official Reports), 2007. Bioenergi från jordbruket—
the European Parliament, the Economic and Social Committee and the en växande resurs (Bio energy from the agriculture—a growing resource). SOU
Committee of the Regions, COM (2000), 247, Brussels. 2007: 36, Ministry of Agriculture, Stockholm (in Swedish).
European Commission, 2003. Directive 2003/30/EC of the European Parliament Statistics Sweden, 2006. Kommunala energibalanser (Municipal energy balances).
and of the Council of 8 May 2003 on the promotion of the use of biofuels and Website information. Available at /www.scb.se/EN0203S (2006-08-15) (in
other renewable fuels for transport. Official Journal of the European Union Swedish).
L123/42. Statistics Sweden, 2007. Population statistics. Website information. Available at
European Commission, 2007. Promoting biofuels as credible alternative to oil in /www.scb.se/BE0101-ENS (2007-08-15).
transport. Memo/07/5, Date 10/01/2007. Statistics Sweden, Swedish Board of Agriculture, Swedish Environmental Protec-
European Council, 2007. Brussels European Council 8/9 March 2007. Presidency tion Agency, The Federation of Swedish Farmers, 2007. Hållbarhet i svenskt
Conclusions, Nr: 7224/1/07 REV1. jordbruk 2007 (Sustainability in Swedish Agriculture 2007). Statistics Sweden,
Fahle n, E., Ahlgren, E.O., in press. Assessment of integration of different biomass Örebro (in Swedish).
gasification alternatives in a district-heating system. Energy, corrected proof. Svenska Kraftnät, 2007. Marknadsstatistik för elcertifikatsystemet (market statis-
Gustavsson, L., Börjesson, P., Johansson, B., Svenningsson, P., 1995. Reducing CO2 tics for the electricity certificate system). Website information. Available at:
emissions by substituting biomass for fossil fuels. Energy 20, 1097–1113. /https://elcertifikat.svk.se/S (2007-09-25) (in Swedish).
Gustavsson, L., 1997. Energy efficiency and competitiveness of biomass based Swedish District Heating Association, 2006. Statistik 2004 (Statistics 2004).
energy systems. Energy 22, 959–967. Swedish District Heating Association, Report February 2006, Stockholm (in
Gustavsson, L., Madlener, R., 2003. CO2 mitigation costs of large-scale bioenergy Swedish).
technologies in competitive electricity markets. Energy 28, 1405–1425. Swedish EPA (Environmental Protection Agency), 2005. Strategi för hållbar
Göteborg Energi, 2005. Miljörapporter 2004 (Environmental Reports 2004). avfallshantering (Strategy for Sustainable Waste Disposal). Swedish Environ-
Göteborg Energi AB, Göteborg (in Swedish). mental Protection Agency, Stockholm (in Swedish).
Hiremath, R.B., Shikha, S., Ravindranath, N.H., 2007. Decentralized energy Swedish Petroleum Institute (SPI), 2007. Statistics Sweden—Prices. Website
planning; modeling and application—a review. Renewable and Sustainable information. Available at /www.spi.se/eng/S (2007-03-15).
Energy Reviews 11, 729–752. Uddin, S.N., Barreto, L., 2007. Biomass-fired cogeneration systems with CO2 capture
Ingman, D., Larsson, E., Waldheim, L., 2006. Biobränsleförgasning för kraftvärme and storage. Renewable Energy 32, 1006–1019.
respektive energikombinat—integration med Rya kraftvärmeverk i UN (United Nations), 1993. Agenda 21: Earth Summit—The United Nations
Göteborg (biomass gasification for combined heat and power and energy Programme of Action from Rio. United Nations Department of Public
combine—integration with Rya CHP in Göteborg). In: Ahlgren, E., Andersson, Information, New York.
E., Axelsson, E., Börjesson, M., Fahle n, E., Harvey, S., Ingman, D., Karlsson, S., Unger, T., Ahlgren, E.O., 2005. Impacts of a common green certificate market on
Larsson, E., Löfgren, Å., Waldheim, L. Ådahl, A., 2007. Biokombi Rya—Slu- electricity and CO2-emission markets in the Nordic countries. Energy Policy 33,
trapporter från ingående delprojekt (Biokombi Rya—final reports from 2152–2163.
part projects). Chalmers Energy Centre—CEC, Report CEC 2007:3, Göteborg World Bank, 2007. Commodity Price Data (Pink Sheet). January 4, 2007, World
(in Swedish). Bank, Washington, DC. Available at /www.worldbank.orgS (2007-01-19).

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi