Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 11

try estimates of "aset of macroeconomic parameters that are considered

important for policy, using a uniform data set for a relatively large group
of countries and relying on appropriate empirical techniques to obtain
these estimates. Because our interest is in providing reasonable empir-
A Macroeconometric Model for ical estimates of widely used parameters, we construcf a fairly simple
macroeconomic model using widely accepted developing country speci-
Developing Countries fications for the key behavioral relationships wherever possible. The
structural parameters are then estimated as a system.
Although, for the reason just explained, the behavioral relationships
Nadeem U. Haque, Kajal Lahiri, in our model are conventional, our work differs from existing developing
and Peter J. Montie/* country empirical macroeconomic models in two important ways. First,
we assume that expectations are formed rationally by forward-looking
economic agents. Second, we make explicit allowance for the presence

Din developingincreased
ESPITE THE attention that macroeconomic management of capital controls-a feature which, though pervasive in developing
countries has received during the past decade, no con- economies and often mentioned in policy discussions, is invariably
sensus has emerged on the appropriate analytical framework for the neglected when it comes to empirical analysis.
study of developing country macroeconomic issues. Instead, individual The model to be estimated is described in Section 1. Section II de-
models suitable for different tasks have proliferated with different, and scribes the estimation procedure and presents the estimation results. The
often conflicting, assumptions about a wide range of crucial aspects of model estimates are discussed in Section III. The final section provides
these economies, such as the nature of financial markets, the degree of some brief comments on the specification of the model and the estimated
capital mobility, the form and functioning of the exchange rate regime, relationships.
the degree of wage-price flexibility, the determination of aggregate sup-
ply, and the extent to which agents' expectations are forward looking.
This lack of consensus on analytical macroeconomic models for deve·
loping countries is eve'1 more pronounced at the empirical level. This section develops a simple model for a small open developing
Substantial disagreement exists over the general specification of such country, which can be estimated using a pooled sample of time-series
models, as well as over the orders of magnitude of certain key macro- data from a large number of countries. In specifyingthe behavioral rela-
economic parameters-for example, the interest responsiveness of sav- tionships as well as the structure of the economy, we have chosen to work
ing and investment, the "offset coefficient" for monetary policy, the with conventional, widely used specifications to the greatest extent pos-
relative price elasticity of exports and imports, and the importance of sible, subject to the data limitations inherent in developing country
"accelerator" mechanisms in the determination of investment, all of applications. The model is of the Mundell-Fleming variety, with one'
which have important implications for economic policy. Although esti- domestically produced good consumed both at home and abroad and
mates of macroeconomic parameters such as these are indeed available one imported good.1 The specification allows for the existence of capital
for developing countries, they differ greatly with regard to countries and controls, while permitting the degree of effective capital mobility to be
periods'<covered, specifications of estimated equations, and-possibly tested empirically. The discussion is divided into descriptions of ag-
most important-the empirical methodology employed in producing gregate demand, aggregate supply, the money market,"and the govern-
them. Consequently, generalizations across developing countries are ment sector. The last subsection examines the overall structure of the
virtually impossible to make. model.
The aim of this paper is to generate "representative" developing coun-
1 Although a three-good (exportable-importablc-nontraded) structure might
be more appropriate for developing countries, data limitations make it infeasible
*. This paper was published in Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. to implement the estimation of a model with this structure across a large group
(Sertember 1990), pp. 537-59. The authors are grateful to Mohsin Khan for of developing countries.
~fu comments. The views expressed arc the authors' nnd do not necessarily
~ent those of the IMF.
\
tion is constrained by current income (see Flavin (1981)). Finally, the
coefficient of the lagged disposable income term can also provide a test
Real aggregate demand for domestic output is the sum of consump- for the Blanchard hypothesis of finite horizons for private agents. As
tion, investment, government expenditure, and the trade balance: shown in Haque (1988), if the planning horizons of households that do
not face liquidity constraints are effectively of infinite length, 0'.4 = 0;
y., = C, + I , + G , + X , _ e,P,*
P,2, . otherwise, 0'.4 will be negative (see also Haque and Montiel (1989».
Consumer disposable income, a variable used in the consumption
The variables in equation (1) are defined as follows: Y, is real gross function above, is defined to be GDP plus the earnings on net assets held
domestic product (GDP); C, is real private consumption expenditure; I, abroad, minus interest paid on domestic debt and taxes:
is real gross domestic investment expenditure; G, is real government .* F'/",-
Y ,,/ = y.,+ I, c, P, I UJCp,,_1 _ T
expendituf(~ on the domestic good; X, denotes real exports; c, is the , P, . t,

nominal exchange rate (price of foreign currency in domestic currency


terms); Z, is real imports measured in units of the foreign good; P,* is the where ii and i, are the (nominal) foreign and domestic interest rates,
foreign currency price of imports; and P, is the domestic currency price respectively, Fp" is the stock of foreign assets held by _the private sector
of domestic output. (measured in foreign currency terms), Dep,t is the stock of domestic bank
Turning to the components of demand, the consumption function is credit held by the private sector, and T is real taxes. Disposable income
specified as follows: and consumer expenditure are linked to the net change in consumer
wealth by the private sector budget constraint:
log C, = 0'.0 + air, + 0'.2 log C,-l + 0'.3 log Y f + 0'.4 log Y,~" (2)
ytd = C, + It + [(M,- M,-D + e,(Fp.t - Fp.t-I) - (DCp.l- DCp,t-I)]/P"
d
where r, is the domestic real rate of interest, Y t is real disposable in-
come, and the a;'s are coefficients to be estimated.2 The short-run inter- where Mt denotes the. money supply in period t. Disposable incom~ is
est semi-elasticity of consumption is measured by the parameter al.3 In thus allocated to consumption, investment, and net 'changes in financial
this general specification are nested a number of alternative hypotheses assets.
=
about consumption. ,For example, if ao al = "3 = a4 = 0, and a2 = 1, Investment is specified as a function of fairly standard variables-that
the simplest Hall (1978) version of the ,permanent-income hypothesis is, the real interest rate, real output, and the beginning-of-period capital
with no liquidity constraints, in which current consumption is system- stock.4 We adopt a linear formulation, since this permits us to. avoid
atically related only to its own past value, is obtained (see Hall (1978)). the problem of the absence of capital stock data by first-differencing the
If only the disposable income terms are rejected empirically, the specifi- equation. The investment function is .
cation would be consistent with more general Euler-equation ap-
proaches, which predict that, in the absence of new information, con-
sumption grows from period to period at a rate that depends on the rate
of interest (see Rossi (1988) and Giovannini (1985». As a number of
studies have shown, current disposable income would be important (that
is, a3 >4» in all equation of this type estimated with instrumental varia-
bles if liquidity constraints are binding for a significant portion of house-
where k3 = 1 + k;. This transformation eliminates the capital stock, a
holds, since in this case aggregate consumption would include a portion
variable for which no developing country data are available.
that is attributable to liquidity-constrained households whose consump-
Exports are assumed to be a function of the real exchange rate
2 ~~is specificationis.veryclose ~o~hatof Bl!nder and Deaton (1985). See ~lso
(e, Pi/P,) and the level of real output ahroad (Y*), with positive eoeHi-'
Lahlfl (1989), who estImates a sll1l1larfunction for sevcral ASian economics.
J Fewstudieshave found reliable or significantestimates of interest elasticities
4 For a discussionof investment functions in ckvcloping countries, see Blejer
of consumption in developing countries. See, for example, Rossi (1988). and Khan (1984a, 1984b) and Sundararajan and Thakur (1980).
cients for both" variables. S To incorporate partial adjustment, a lagged
dependent v<triable is included in the estimated equativn. The export
equation may therefore be expressed as foUows:t; log K, = 10g[~
1=0
(1- py It-i + (1- PYKo]
, e,P,*
log x~ To + TI log -p; + T2 log Yi + 1'J log X,_ s. (6)
~ log 2 + ~[IOg~ (I - p)' 1.-. + log (1 - pi, K,]
Real imports are related negatively to the real exchange rate and
positively to real domestic output. This specification is conventional.' 1 t-1 . t 1
Again. to capture partial adjustment behavior a lagged import term is in, = log 2 + 210g~ (1- p)' It-; +'2 log (1- p) + 210gKo, (9)
cluded in the estimated equation. Furthermore. since restricted foreign
exchange availability frequentl leads to the imosition of im ort can- where Ko is the initial st~ck of capital. 8
tro s and foreign exchange rationing. which act as a constraint on im- Thus,
Ports in developing countries; the reserve-import ratio lagged one period
log 1'; = log eo + el log K, + G2 log Lr
is often included in this regression (see Khan and Knight (1988». The
import equation can therefore' be written as 1 ,-1
= log eo + el [log 2 + 210g ~ (1 - pY It-;
e,P,* Rr-I
log Z, = 00 + 01 log P + 02 log 1';+ 0) log * Z + 04 log 2'-1, (7)
, Pt-I '-1 + ~ log (1 - p) + ~ log KO] + e2 log L:
where Rr is the foreign exchange value of international reserves.
= eo + el K,'.+ e; log L" (10)

e'o = Iog e log Ko


l
eo + '2
We assume a Cobb-Douglas production function relating labor and
capital to output: .. 1 r-I t .
K,' = log 2 + -2 log 2.: (1 - rY IH + -2 log (1 - p).
1=0

where K and L are measures of the aggregate capital stock and employ- Note that equation (10) can be estimated for different values ofp over
ment and the e;,s (i = 0, 1,2) are coefficients to be estimated. As with the the interval (0,1), and opti:nal values £.f eo, 61> and 62 will correspond to
i,nvestment function, estimation of the supply side of the model is ham- that value of p which maximizes the R,2 in equation (10). By imposing
pered by the shortage of data on aggregate capital stock for developing constant returns to scale (that is, el + e2 = 1), equation (10) can be
countries. The following procedure was therefore adopted. The solution written in per capita terms as .'
to the difference equation K, = (1 - p) K,-l + Ir, where p is the nite of . log (1';ILt) = eo + e1 (K/ -log Lr). (11)
depreciation, can be written (after taking logs) as

8 We used the approximation


S See Goldstein and Khan (1985) for a discussion of empirical estimates of such
an export function. See also Khan (1974) and Khan and Knight (1988) for the log (x + y) "'" log 2 + 2:11'(log x + log y) + 8 (log x - log y)2 + •.. : '
case of developing countries.
6 Note that the Mundell-Fleming structure of this model implies that exports where
1-1
and domestic output are perfect substitutes.
1 Once again, empirical applications of this specification are extensively dis- X = 2: (1- p)i 1'-i
;-0
and y:= (1·- p)' Ko.
cussed in Goldstein and Khan (l9R5).
To allow for lagged adjustment and technical progress over time, we markets. Our formulation follows Edwards and Khan (1985) in speci-
also included log (YIL),-t and a time trend, t, as additional explanatory fying the domestic interest rate as a linear combination of these two
variables in our final specification. Thus, the empirical production polar cases:
function becomes

log (YIL), = 6~ + 61 (K,' -log L,) + gt + 63 log (YIL),-Jo (12) i, = (it + Etet~:- e) -+- (1 - (~)i,.
<\> (16)

The degree of wage-price flexibility in developing countries is an un- Here, E,e'+1 is the expectation at time t of the exchange rate in period
settled issue. The present model is estimated on the assumption of com- t -+- 1; Itis the interest rate that would prevail if the capital account were
plete wage-price flexibility. Under these circumstances, equation (12) closed; and <\> is a capital mobility index ranging between zero and unity.
also represents the economy's aggregate supply function. When <\> = 1, it is implied that the domestic interest rate is determined by
the uncovered interest parity condition, and thus corresponds to perfect
capital mobility, whereas <\> = 0 implies that the domestic interest rate is
I-that is, the rate that would emerge under a completely closed capital
The suppliof money (M) in the economy consists of reserves and account. As <t> increases from zero to unity, the degree of capital mobility
domestic credit, with the latter denoted as DC: increases, since i approaches its uncovered parity value. In these inter-
Mt = e,R, + DC,. (13) mediate cases the equilibrium interest rate is determined by a combina-
tion of domestic and external factors.
Whereas reserves are determined endogenously by the balance of pay- The interest rate that would prevail in an economy with a closed capi~
ments (see bel~w), domestic credit, both to the private sector (DCp,,) tal account (that is, one with no private capital flows), It, can be deter-
and to the public sector (DCc,t), is determined by policy: mined by equating the money supply that would be observed in this case
to the demand for money. Tris "shadow" money supply (denoted by it)
DC,= DCp,,+ DCc". (14)
differs from the supply of money given by equation' (13), in that, the
The demand for money is, as usual, taken to be related negatively to effects of current private capital flows on the central bank's stock of
the nominal rate of interest and positively to the level of income, with a foreign exchange reserVes 'are removed:
partial adjustment mechanism introduced to capture lagged responses:
M = M + e,tlFp.,.
t t (17)
log ~t = [30 + [31 i, + [32 log Y, + [33 log Y,_I + [34 log M -t
t
• (15) Thus, the "shadow" domestic interest rate It can be obtained by solv-
, ~-I
ing the following equation:
The lagged term in Y allows for different speeds of adjustment of the de-
mand for money to changes in interest rates and income.9 itt _ Mt-1
log -p = [30-I' [311t + 132 log Y, + 133 log Yt-1 + 134 log -p. . (18)
The specification of the determination of the domestic nominal inter- I 1- I

est rate allows us to test for the effective degree of capital mobility in
the economy. If capital is perfectly mobile, as is frequently assumed in In this model the authorities use capital controls to pursue an indepc'n-
models of small open economies, nominal interest rates are determined dent monetary policy, as follows: for a desired level of the domestic
by the inte~rest arity condition that equates the domestic nominal inter- interest rate, say It, the levef of the domestic money supply required to
~st rate to the sum of the nomina rate prevatling abroadandtneex- clear the money market, sayM" is given by setting i = Iin the money-
pected chan ein the value of the domestic currency (uncove-red'interest market e~ilibrium condition (15).
parity). In a completely closed economy, nomma mterest rates have no Given M, from equation (15) and the supply of credit DC equation
"
relationship to external rates and are determined purely in domestic (13) determines foreign exchange reserves R,. Subtracting the previous
period's reserves, R,-t> yields the balance of payments (tlR,). Using the
balance of payments identity , , .
9The addi~ional lagged term in ~ permits the demand for money to adjust
more slowly In response to changes In incol!1e than to changes in interest rates.
e, tlRt = CAr - e, (tlFG" + tlFI',r}, (19)
Haque· Lahiri • Montiel

where
interest on its foreign asset holdings. Expenditures (G,) consist of pur-
CA,==P,X,- e,P:Z, + i,*e,(Fr.t-1 + FG.,-t + R,_I), (20) chases of domestic goods for consumption purposes and interest pay-
ments on domestic debt. Combining these elements, the government
the authorities can derive the permissible level of private capital budget constraint can be written as
flows, I:J.Fp./> conditional on the current account, CA" and public capital
outflows, I:J.Fr;.,. e,f1Fa.,- I:J.DCa.,= P,(T,- G,) + i;""e,Fa.,- t - i,DCG.,_I' (22)
The authorities could choose to administer this system in a number of
ways. If either i, or AF"., is treated as an exogenous variable, the other
becomes endogenous and equation (16) drops out of the model. With i,
exogenous, the authorities announce a domestic interest rate, solve for
the v.a~ueof I:J.Fp:, reql,1ired to support it, and permit this degree of capital The model that emerges from this specification is essentially a flexible-
mobilIty. Equation (16) becomes unnecessary, useful only for calculating price dynamic variant of the traditional Mundell-Fleming model with
a period-by-period index <1>, of the degree of capital mobility. Alterna- specific developing country fe~tures. A single good is produced domesti-
tively, the authorities could choose I:J.Fp., exogenously, with equation (19) cally, which can be sold at home or abroad. The home country has some
determining R equation (13) determining M" and equation (15) the monopoly power over the price of its output in world markets.' It is a
"
domestic interest rate. The role of equation (16) would then be as in the price-taker, however, in the market for its imports. However, as is com-
previous case. mon in developing countries, private agents may not be able to satisfy
We ~vil!assume,i!}g~~<L!.h.?-L~he system is r~n somewwt less flexibly. their notional demand for imports, because the authorities impose quan-
The severity ·of capital controls, as measured by the parameter <I> in titative import restrictions .that depend on the adequacy of their foreign
equation (16), is taken as a structurai (institutional) feature of the econ- exchange reserves. On the financial side, the degree of integration of the
omy. In this casG, both i, and I:J.Fn, become endogenous. The domestic home economy with the rest of the world depends on the degree of
interest rate i, will respond to factors affecting both the uncovered parity severity with which capital controls are enforced. In principle, this can
and the shadow interest rate. For the money market to clear I:J.F. must range from financial autarky to perfect capital mobility; The dynamics of
be adjusted in response to these factors as well. Notice that th~ str~~tural the model arise from forward-looking expectations, partial adjustment
interpretation of <I> permits its magnitude to be estimated empirically, in in the behavioral relationships, and stock accumulation. Since the levels
a manner to be discussed in the next section. of investment and the current account are endogenous; the model can
. The real interest rate enters the model in both the consumption and explain medium~tcrm growth and external debt accumulation. Since ex-
Investment functions. It is given by pectations are forward-looking, these phenomena will depend not just
. E,Pt+' - PI on present, but also on future, values of the policy and exogenous
r, == I, - PI (21) variables.

that is, the real interest rate is the nominal interest rate minus the
expected rate of inflation.

The equations to be estimated are (2), (5), (6), (7), (12), (15), and
(16). These are repeated for convenience in Table 1. The approach to
The model's dynamic specification is Completed with a description of estimation used here assumes that the slope parameters do not change
the be~avior of the nonfinancial public sector. The public sector acquires across countries. The estimates should therefore be interpreted as
;Issets III external markets (Fa,,) as well as from the domestic banking "typical" of developing countries in general, rather than as specific to
sector (Da.,).IO For its revenues it relies on tax receipts, T" and on any particular country. This approach allows us to exploit the variation
in data both across countries and within countries over time to estimate
key macroeconomic parameters. We used annual data over 1963-87 for
a function of domestic money-market conditions as well as of the exter-
(2) log C, = ao + a. r, + a, log C, _. + al log Y1 + a. logY: ••
nal interest rate. The solution for the nominal interest rate can be used
(5) " = k, (r, - r, _ .) + kdY. - Y,• ;) + kl', _I
to eliminate it from the money-demand function (15), permitting that
(6) log X. = To + T, log e:~ , + Tl log Yt + Tl log X,_ ,
equation to be expressed in terms of observable variables. The expres-
sion for it can also be substituted into equation (21) to solve for the real
(7) log Z, = 00 + 0, log ~:~ + 8, log Y, + 8l log p. RLZ··!'- + 8. log Z, _ , interest rate '1' This solutiun for the real interest rate can be used to
t t - I I'" I
eliminate '1 from both the consumption function (2) and the investment
(12) log (Y/l) •. = 6~ + 6, (K; - log l,) + gt + 6llog (Y/l),., function (5), rendering these equations in terms of observable variables.
(IS) log~! = [30 + [3, i, + [3,log Y. + [3l log Y,_ 1+ [3. log Mp'~ I
The revised equations (2), (5), and (15) are nonlinear in the structural
C I - I parameters and subject to cross-equation restrictions among these pa-
(16) i, = <bC~ + ~-'·~·e~
- e.) + (I - <!>)i.
rameters. This procedure has the virtue not only of making"it possible to
estimate the parameter <1>, but also of permitting us to extract estimates
of interest rate elasticities in consumption, investment, and money de-
mand, which do not, as is common in much of the developing country
31 developing countriesll collected from the International Monetary literature, depend on proxies for market interest rates such as adminis-
Fund's World Economic Outlook data base and International Financial tered interest rates or inflation rates. The resulting system to be esti-
Statistics. In this section we discuss three estimation issues: the problem mated consists of the revised versions of equations (2), (5), and (15)-
of unobserved variables; the approach to estimation with rational expec- with associated nonlinear parameter and cross-equation restrictions-as
tations; and the treatment of country heterogeneity. The estimated well as equations (6), (7), and (12).
equations themselves are presented in Section III.

The next issue concerns the treatment of expectations in the .estima-


The first estimation issue to be confronted is the absence of data on tion procedure. The assumption of rationality in our model implies that
the market-determined interest rate it and, of course, the shadow interest forward expectations are based on all available information, including
rate f,. In developing countries the relevant market-determined interest the structure of the model. This 'implies the property that prediction
rate is typically that for loans in informal, or "curh" markets. Time- errors should be nonsystematic:
series data on such interest rates are very rare. Published developing
country interest rate data typically refer to central bank discount rates or
to official interest rates on deposits or bank credit. Such interest rates where €i,I+1 is a seriaJly uncorrelated random disturbance term. For esti-
have almost invariably been set by administrative fiat and do not ade- mation a reasonable proxy is needed for EIPi,I+1> which now appears in
quately capture the marginal cost of funds. the revised versions of equations (2) and (5). One such observable proxy
This problem can be addressed by solving equation (18) for the for the unobservable price-~xpectation variable ErPi.t+l> according to
shadow interest rate Jr, and then substituting the resulting expression for equation (23), is the actual Pi•H1• The associated estimation procedure
I, into equation (16) to solve for i,. The result is an equation for the must take account of the errors-in-variables problem implied by (23).
domestic market-determined interest rate that expresses this variable as This errors-in-variables method (EVM), in which the expected forward
price is replaced by the realized (observed) value, and the latter is
11 The countries in the sample are Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecua- treated as an additional endogenous variable of the model, is a well·
dor, Egypt. Ethiopia, Greece, Guatemala, India, Indonesia, Jamaica, Jordan, known approach to estimation under rational expectations.12 An alter~
Kenya, the Republic of Korea, Malawi, Malaysia, Malta. Mexico, Morocco,
Nigeria, Paraguay, the Philippines, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Tanzania, Thai-
land, Tunisi;l, Turkey, Venezuela, and Zambia. 12SceMcCallum (1976), Lahiri (1981), and Wickens (1982). See also B1undell-
Wignall and Masson (1985).
native approach that has been used for estimation of simultaneous
we adopted the alternative approach of variance components. Under this
equation models with rational expectations is the so-called substitution
assumption, the error term of the jth equation, "li> is composed of two
method (SM) where the f<ltionally expected variables are replaced by
terms: 'Tljl, the country-specific effect, which varies only across countries
forecast~ based on a restricted reduced form,l3 Wickens (1982, 1986)
and not across time; and E.jit,an individual random effect which-may
emphasizes many advantages of the EVM approach over the SM method.
differ for all observations. The approach has the advantage that it recog-
He sho~s that in a nonlinear model such as ours, the additional non- nizes the possibility that couritry~specific effects may be correlated across
linearity in the parameters introduced owing to SM will make the esti- equations ..
mation technique hopelessly complicated. Wickens (1982, 1986) also
demonstrates that EVM is in general more robust than SM in cases
where the v~riablc.s in the info~mation set (0,) are incomplete. More-
over, EVM IS relatively easy to Implement, making it more amenable to
repeated experimentation with different specifications of the model. In As is well known, variance-components characterization of country
a.ddition, ~icken: ~1986) shows that until the type of rational expecta- heterogeneity implies that generalized least-squares (GLS) estimation
tIOns solutIOn exhibited by the model is known, it will not be possible to techniques can be used to consistently estimate the model parameters as
select the appropriate fully efficient SM estimator. well as the variance components of the random error term. In oraer to
. Th~ ~educed-form equa~ion. for PI in country i can be obtained by deal with the error-component structure of the variance of the random
hneanzl~g the mo?~I, solvIng It for PIl advancing it one period, taking error term in the model, generalized estimation techniques were imple-
expectations conditional on Oil and solving for EIPjl+l• If we write mented using a two-step procedure.14 At the first stage, the vector of
residuals was calculated from two-stage least-squares (2SLS) estimates
EIPi(. I = n .Xill (24)
of the model. These residual estimates were used to calculate the vari-
where XiI is thc set .of instruments belonging to !l" and n is a vector of ance and covariance components. See Wallace and Hussain (1969) and
reduced-form coefficients, then equation (23) becomes Maddala (1988).
With the variance components estimated, the variance-covariance ma-
trix of the disturbance term can be constructed to allow gencraJized
This equation Can be used to generate the instruments for p. In two-stage or three-stage least squares to be used for consistent estima-
estimating the behavioral equations of the revised model, the;;~~re, tion of the model parameters. Anderson and Hsiao (1982) and Sevestre
EIPit+1 was replaced by Pit+l; and Ci" Ii" XiI> Zit, Mi" Yil, Pi" and Pit+l were and Trognon (1985) have shown that this estimator is consistent and, for
treated as endogenous variables (that is, not part of the set of instru- dynamic models, independent of initial conditions. In our case, a gen-
ments). T~is yields ~onsis.tent estimates of the structural parameters. eralized, nonlinear, three-stage least-squares estimator was used owing
Note that m o~der to IdenUfy and estimate all the structural parameters, to the presence of nonlinearities and cross-equation restrictions. Follow-
we h~ve to estl~a.te the syste:n ~f equations together, incorporating the ing Breusch, Mizon, and Schmidt (1989), the instruments used were the
nonlinear restnctlOns both Within and across equations. within~country variables (Xjil - Xji) and the between-country variables
(Xji); they have shown that the use of this procedure allows efficient
Treatment of Country Heterogeneity estimation in models with panel data.15
~
The use of pooled cross-section, time-series data means that the issue 14 For more detailed discussion of estimation with variance components see
of country heterogeneity has to be confronted. Most studies that use Balestra and Nerlove (1966), Hausman and Taylor (1981), Amemiya and
such data f?r empirical est!mation rely on a fixed-effects model, using McCurdy (1986), Breusch, Mizon, and Schmidt (1989), and Maddala (1988).
15 Before estimating the model, we tested our assumed error-components
dumu:y v~nables to deal With country heterogeneity, primarily for ease structure, and also conducted tests for serial correlation. These tests are de-
of estimatIOn (see, for example, Khan and Knight (1981». In this study scribed in Haque, Lahiri, and Montiel (1990), which also provides a detailed
treatment of estimation issues. The results were consistent with the variance-
I'See Hansen and Sargent (1980,11)1\1) and Wallis (1980). components model, and no signs of serial correlation were delected in the
residuals.
Table 2. Nonlinear Error-Components, Three-Stage
Least-Squares Estimates of Structural Parameters

The error-components, two-stage least~squares (EC2SLS) estimates Parameter


form the basis for the implementation of the error-components, three- Consumption
(Xo == 0.047 5.62*
stage least-squares (EC3SLS) estimation (see Baltngi (1981». The re- (x, == -0.076 -4.08*
sults of the EC3SLS estimation are presented in Table 2. As will be (x, == 1.010 96.28*
(X) == 0.143 3.64*
discussed below, these results indicate that the model fits the data very (x. == -0.149 -4.23*
welt. Almost all the estimates are of the right sign, and a large number IP == 0.997
of them are estimated precisely. In what follows we shall discuss the Investment
estimates of, and the hypotheses embedded in, each Qf the behavioral ko == -0.226 -6.81*
equations separately.16 k, == -0.113 -4.03*
k, == 0.196 9.74*
k, == 0.809 44.94*
iF == 0.980

Production function
0, == 0.112 6.55*
The estimated coefficients of the consumption function are all of the 63.38*
0, = 0.881
anticipated signs. In magnitude, these coefficients also conform well to g =: 0.14\ 6,49'
theory as well as to consumption function t'stimates that are available in IF == 0.979
the literature. Interestingly enough, ct, is negative and significant at the Exports
2.05*
10 percent level, verifying a negative relationshIp between consumption 'T, =: 0.050
1.78'
'T, == 0.084
and the interest rate. Most studies of the consumption function have 82.24*
'T) == 0.925
found this relationship to be statistically insignificant. Our results sug- 7{2 == 0.983
gest that the use of inappropriate proxies for domestic real interest rates Imports
(for example, the rate of inflation) may have contributed to this result.'7 lh =: -0.\57· -5.09'
82 = 0.161 6.02*
The estimated coefficient is, however, quite small, suggesting that 5.96'
8, =: 0.038
changes in interest rates would not induce substantial changes in con- 0." 0.834 43.21*
sumption. This result confirms Rossi's (1988) finding of a significant but It' "" 0.977

small real interest rate elasticity in the consumption function. Money demand
-4.36*
The estimation, as it turns out, supports a number of important hy- /30 == -0.146
-.1.27
/3, == -0.038
potheses relating to the consumption function that were discussed above. /3, =: 0.511 3.99'
The specification is very similar to the Haque and Montiel (1989) version /3) = -0.397 -2.79*
/3. "" 0.881 59.56*
of the permanent income model. The coefficient of lagged consumption ((2 = 0.997

)I, Note,that our model formulation allows all the endogenous variables to be Capitol mobility .
correlated with Tj!iand E.!it in all equations. However. the exogenous variables are 4> "" 1.004
assumed to be uncorrelated withTjji and E.jit. Some of the exogenous variables, .' Note: one asterisk (') indicates paramete~ significance at thc S percent level; two asterisks CO.) indicate not
significantly different from unity; and R 2 denotc. the coefficient of determination corrected for degrees of
however, can be correlated with Tjji. but uncorrelated E.it. Cornwell, Schmidt,
and Wyhowski (1988) refer to this latter group as "sin~lyl, exogenous variables. freedom.
For conshtent estimation, the country means of the Singly exogenous variables
(that is, Xi) should not belong to the lIst of instrumcntal variables. In the context
of EC2SLS estimation of each structural equation, we found that this had negli-
gible effects on the reported estimates. Thus, our list of exogenous variables can
\afdy be treated as "doubly" exogenous.
17 Sce Giovannini (1985) for a discussion of this issue.
i~close to unity and si?nificant, as expected in the Hall (1978) specifica-
tIOn of the permanent Income hypothesis. However, contrary to the Hall vicinity of 0.05.19 The per capita stock of capital affects current output
hypot?esis, disposable income is significant in explaining consumption significantly and positively with a short-run elasticity of 0.12 and of close
b.eh~~lOr.The coefficient of disposable income, Cl3, which is statistically to unity in the long run. At the sample means, our results, which are de-
rived from a log-linear specification, compare quite favorably to the esti-
sIgmfI~ant, su~ge~t~ that abo~t 15 percent of consumers in developing
count:Ies are lIqUIdIty~onstralned, which is on the low end of the range mates of Dadkhah and Zahedi (1986). Nevertheless, the supply equation
of estImates reported In Haque and Montiel (1989). provided the least satisfactory empirical results. The coefficient on the
lagged dependent variable is implausibly high, suggesting that some of
our maintained hypotheses (for example, regarding the form of the pro-
duction function or the degree of wage-price flexibility) require further
investigation.
The specification of the investment function was a relatively simple
?ne. Nevertheles~, it .seems to ~rovide a reasonably good explanation of
Investment behavIOr In developing countries. Most studies of investment
be~avior in such countries do not include interest rates as an explanatory The estimated export function fits the data well, with all coefficients
vanable because of lack of adequate information (see Blejer and Khan bearing the expected signs and reasonable magnitudes. The fitted equa-
~198~a: 19.84b». Our approach to modeling capital mobility allows the tion exhibits a significant export response to relative price changes, al-
IdentIfIcatIOn of the effect of the real interest rate on investment. though one that is somewhat smaller in magnitude than other aviiilable
Although small, th~ c?~fficient of the real interest rate, k •• is negative, estimates.2o The long-run elasticity of 0.66, though considerably higher
as expected, and sIgmflcant at the 5 percent level. Growth in income than the short-run elasticity, still suggests a fairly inelastic response. In
also af~ects investment po.sitivel.y and significantly, in keeping with the estimated (foreign) function for the demand for exports, the coeffi-
the fleXIble-accelerator famIly of Investment theories. The coefficient of cient of foreign income is positive and significant, with a long-run elas-
lagged. investment, k3, is close to but less than unity, indicating both a ticity of 1.12. A fair amount of persistence in the level of exports appears
stable Inv~stme~t fun.ction as well as a fairly protracted period of adjust- to be indicated by the coefficient of lagged exports, whieh is both signifi-
ment. USIng thIS estImate, the long-run interest rate and output elas- cant and c}ose to unity, so that the response to changes in relative prices
ticities can be calculated-they turn out to be 0.59 and 1.02, respectively. and foreign income tends to be quite prolonged over time.
Thus, as can be expected, in the long run, when all adjustments have In the import equation the estimated coefficients also bear the ri,ght
?een completed, the interest elasticity is substantially larger than it is on signs and are all significant at conventional levels. Imports are respon-
~mpact. Moreover, the steady-state. property that per capita output and sive to real exchange rate changes with a short run elasticity of ~0.157
Investment grow at the sam7 rate is satisfied. and a long-run elasticity of about -0.94. Growth in the domestic econ-
omy i.ncreases imports, with an elasticity of 0..16 in the short run and
about 0.96 (not significantly different from unity) in 'the long run. Re-
flecting foreign exchange constraints, the coefficient of the lagged
reserve-import ratio is significant and positive. These estimates are
. All the. va:i~bles in the estimated aggregate supply (production) func- similar to those in Khan and Knight (1988).
~Iona.re.~lgmfIcantand of the right sign. 18 Since 60 contains log Ko, which Our results suggest that the trade equations are not as responsive
IS an InItIal-value parameter representing the initial stock of capital for to real exchange rate changes and inconiegrowth as other studies have
each country, equation (12) was estimated from the "within" dimension
previously estimated. However, when these results are being com-
of the data. The parameter p was estimated to be 0.05, although esti-
mates of 61> g, and 63 were not particularly sensitive to values of p in the
1KS' I 19 It is interesting to note that this 5 percent value is consistent with those in
. mce aggregate emp oyment data arc seldom available for developing coun-
les, we used the populatIon as a proxy for L. Sundararajan and Thakur (1980) and Blejer and Khan (I 984b).
20 See Khan (1974), Goldstein and Khan (1985), and Khan and Knight (1988).
pared: it must be borne in mind that most available estimates of such
equatIOns were constructed in a partial equilibrium setting. The esti- developing country values of the parameters of key macroeconomic
mates prcsent~d here, by contrast, are in the context of a complete behavioral relationships. Although empirical estimates are available for
macroeconomic model. these parameters, the lack of convergence of views reflects differences in
the specifications estimated by various analyst~. in da.ta definitioJ.1sand
time periods and countries covered, and in empirical methodology, In
Money andCapitaf Mobility
this paper, using conventional, widely accepted specifications and appro-
priate econometric techniques, we pooled consistent time-series data for
. ~he coefficients of the estimated money-demand function are all sig- 31 developing countries to derive estimates for the key behavioral pa-
mflcant ,and o,f the, ex~ected sign. Money demand, in keeping with rametersof a small but complete model of a small and open developing
expe~t.atlons, IS qUite mterest inelastic. with the short-run interest economy. The model itself. is innovative only in that expectations are
el<istlcltyestimated at abo~t -OJ)~ and the long-run elasticity estimated formed rationally and that the severity of capital controls is treated as a
at about -0.26. The estimated mcome elasticities are much higher: structural feature of the economy that is subject to empirical estimation.
the sh?rt- a.,nd long-run elasticities turn out to be 0.22 and 1.82, The estimates and test statistics presented above suggest that the
respectIVely, _I
model is not far off the mark as a framework for macroeconomic analysis
As described above, our modeling approach and method of estimation of developing countries. Its estimated parameters, presented in Table I,
allow us to estimate the, effective degree of capital mobility (indexed by generally conform to standard economic theory, and in many cases ap-
th~ parameter <l>? for thiS group ot developing countries. Somewhat sur- proximate those that are available in the literature. Unsati~factory re-
pn.slOgly, the ~sumate of <l> turns out to be insignificantly different from sults emerged only with regard to the economy's supply function, and
u~Jty, suggest 109 that capital was in effect highly mobile for these coun- this suggests an important 'avenue for future research.
tnes over our sample period, This result supports the validity of the The most surprising' result that emerged from the estimation was the
small~open-econ~my approach to modeling the financial sector in de- verification of perfect effective capital mobility for this group of coun-
velopmg econom~e~ and i~plies that economic agents readily find ways tries. Barriers to capital mobility would seem to be totally ineffectual.
~o get aroun.d offlcJa~.barners to capital mobility. Thus, the uncovered This result has important policy implications-that is, it suggests that
mtere~t panty co.ndltlon can be used to proxy for interest rates in little leverage can be exercised on domestic aggregate demand through
modehng developmg economies.22.n
monetary'policy in these countries, even though the effects of changes in
credit policy on the balance of payments may be substantial. This degree
of capital mobility is consistent with the episodes of massive capital flight
that have been observed in a number of developing countries in recent
years. Finally, although we were able to estimate substitution elasticities
This paper .attempts t? fill a void in empirical developing country fairly precisely, our estimated values were in many c~ses somewhat lower
macroeconomICS. There IS at present no consensus on "representative" than available estimates. This interaction of 100v substitution elasticities, .
perfect capital mobility, and forward-looking ·behavior represents a pos-
sible framework within which to study the dynamic response of develop-
ZI Es!imates 0. f in~ome elasticities of money demand substantially above unity ing economies to both exogenous and policy shocks.
ar;z qUite,"commo? In developing countries. See Khan (1980),
~~ vIew of ~hls result •.~e re-estimated the model, imposing perfect ca ital
moblh~y 10 see If .the coeffICIents wc~e altered in any significant manner. Th~ re-
s,ults v.e~e esse~tlaJJy u,n~hanged, WIth ~he exception of the consumption func-
1.1O~. ThiS funct.lOn exlvblt.c<! a substantially greater interest ratc elasticity. The
cstlmate~ fra;ctlOn of liqUIdity-constrained households was about one third
le;.~lt ~hlch IS, much closer t~ the estimates in Haque and Montiel (1989). ' a
EVidence In ~avor of a high degree of capital mobility was also found' Amemiya, Takeshi, and Thomas E, Ml:Cunly, "Instrumental-Variable Estima-
llaque and Montiel (1990a, 1990b). In tion oIan Error-Components Model," 1~'(,()I1()metrica, Vol. 54 (July 1986),
pp. 869-81.
MACRO MODEL FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Anderson. T.W., and Cheng Hsiao, "Formulation and Estimation of Dynamic Hall Robert E., "Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle-Permanent Income
rvlodCls Using Panel Data," Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 18 (January Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86
1982), pp. 47-82. ' (December 1978), pp. 971-87.
Balestra, Pietro, and M. Marc Nerlove, "Pooling Cross Section and Time Series Hansen, L.P., and T.J. Sargent, "Formulating and Estimating Dynamic Linear
Data in the Estimation of a Dynamic Model: The Demand for Natural Rational Expcctations Models," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Con-
Gas," Econometrica, Vol. 34 (1966), pp. 585-612. trol, Vol. 2 (1980), pp. 7-46.
Baltagi, Badi H., ','Simultaneous Equations With Error Components," Journal ___ "Linear Rational Expectations Models for Dynamically Interrelated
of Econometrics, Vol. 17 (November 1981), pp. 189-200. V;riables " Rational Expectations and Econometric Practice, ed. by Robert
E. Lucas,' Jr. and Thomas J. Sargent (Minneapolis, Minnesota: University
Bhargava, A., L. Franzini, and W. Narendranathan, "Serial Correlation and the
of Minnesota Press, 1981).
Fixed Effects Model," Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 49 (OctoberI982),
pp.533-49. Haque, Nadeem U., "Fiscal Policy ana Private S~ctor Saving Behavior in Devel-
oping Economies;" Staff Papers, InternatIOnal Monetary Fund, Vol. 35
Blejer. Mario 1., and Mohsin S. Khan (1984a), "Private Investment in Develop-
(June 1988), pp. 408-15.
ing Countries," Finance & Development, International Monetary Fund and
the World Bank, Vol. 21 (June 1984), pp. 26-29. ___ ' Kajal Lahiri, and Peter Montiel, "Estimation of a Rational Expectations
M~croeconomic Model for Developing Countries with Capital Controls,"
---. (l98.4b):, "Government Policy and Private Investment in Developing IMF Working Paper, WP/90/11 (February 1990).
Countnes, Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 31 (June
Haque, Nadeem U., and Peter J. Montiel, "Consumption in Developing Coun-
1984), pp. 379-403.
tries: Tests for Liquidity Constraints and Finite Horizons," Review of Eco-
Blinder, Alan S., and Angus C Deaton, "The Time Series Consumption nomies and Statistics, Vol. 71 (August 1989), pp. 408-15.
Function Revisited," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity::;2 (1985),
pp. 465-511. ___ (1990a), "How Mobile Is Capital in Developing Countries?" Economics
Leiters, Vol. 33 (August 1990), pp. 359-62.. .
Blundell-Wignall, Adrian, and Paul R. Masson, "Exchange Rate Dynamics and
Intervention Rules," Staff Papers. International Monetary Fund, Vol. 32 ___ (1990b), "Capital Mobility in Developing Countries: Some Empirical
(March 1985), pp. 132-59. Tests" (unpublished; Washington: International Mon~tary Fund).
Breusch, Trevor S., Grayham E. Mizon, and Peter Schmidt, "Efficient Estima- Hausman, Jerry A., imd William E. Taylor, "Panel Data and Unobservable
tion Using Panel Data," Econ(l1lletrica, Vol. 57 (May 1989), pp. 695-700. Individual Effects," Econometrica, Vol. 49 (Novembe.r 1981), pp. 1377-98.
Breusch, Trevor S., and A.R. Pagan, "The Lagrange Multiplier Test and Its Khan, Mohsin S., "Import ~nd Export Demand in Developing Countries," Staff
Applications to Model Specification in Econometrics," Review of Ec01l0mic Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 21 (November 1974),pp. 678-93.
Studies, Vol. 47 (January 1980), pp. 239-53. ___ , "Monetary Shocks and the Dynamics of Inflation," Staff Papers, Inter-.
Cornwell, C, P. Schmidt, and D. Wyhowski, "Simultaneous Equations and national Monetary Fund, Vol.'27 (June 1980), pp. 250-84.
Panel Data," (unpublished; East Lansing, Michigan: Michigan State Uni- ___ , and Malcolm D. Knight, "Stabilization Program~.in Developing Coun-
versity, September 1988). tries: A Formal Framework," Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund,
Vol. 28 (March 1981), pp. 1-53, reprinted in this volume as Chap. 3.
Dadkhah, Kamram M .., and Zahedi, Fatemeh, "Simultaneous Estimation of
Production Functions and Capital Stocks for Developing Countries," Re- ___ , "Import Compression and Export Performance iilDeveloping Coun-
dew of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 68 (August 1986), pp. 443-51. • tries," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 70 (May 1988), pp. 315~2I.
Edwards, Sebastian, and Mohsin S. Khan, "Interest Rate Determination in De- Lahiri, Ashok K., "Dynamics of Asian Savings: The Role of Growth andAge
. veloping Countries: A Conceptual Framework," Staff Papers, International Structure," Staff Paper~, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 36 (March
Monetary Fund, Vol. 32 (September 1985), pp. 377-403. 1989), pp. 228-61.
Flavin, Marjorie, "The Adjustment of Consumption to Changing Expectations Lahiri, Kajal, The Eco~ometrics of Inflationary Expectations (Amsterdam:
About Future Income," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89 (October North-Holland, 1981).
1981), pp. 974-1009. McCallum, B.T., "Rational Expectations and the Natural Rate' Hypothesis:
Giovannini, Alberto, "Saving and thc Real Intcrest Ratc in LDCs," Journal of Some Consistent Estimates," Econometrica, Vol. 44 (January 1976),
Developmem Economics, Vol. 18 (August 1985). pp. 197-217. pp.43-52.
Goldstein, Morris, and Mohsin S. Khan, "Income anu Price Effects in Forcign Maddala, G.S., "Thc Use of Variance Components Models in Pooling Cross
Trade," in Handbook of Intemational Economics. Vol. 2, cd. by Ronald W. Section and Time Series Data," Eco1lometrica, Vol. 39 (March 1971)
Jones and Pctcr B. Kellen (Amsterdam: North-Holland, J985). pp. 341-58.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi