Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 229

Equity Instruments & Markets: Part II

B40.3331
Relative Valuation and Private Company
Valuation
Aswath Damodaran

Aswath Damodaran 1
The Essence of relative valuation?

 In relative valuation, the value of an asset is compared to the values assessed


by the market for similar or comparable assets.
 To do relative valuation then,
• we need to identify comparable assets and obtain market values for these assets
• convert these market values into standardized values, since the absolute prices
cannot be compared This process of standardizing creates price multiples.
• compare the standardized value or multiple for the asset being analyzed to the
standardized values for comparable asset, controlling for any differences between
the firms that might affect the multiple, to judge whether the asset is under or over
valued

Aswath Damodaran 2
Relative valuation is pervasive…

 Most valuations on Wall Street are relative valuations.


• Almost 85% of equity research reports are based upon a multiple and comparables.
• More than 50% of all acquisition valuations are based upon multiples
• Rules of thumb based on multiples are not only common but are often the basis for
final valuation judgments.
 While there are more discounted cashflow valuations in consulting and
corporate finance, they are often relative valuations masquerading as
discounted cash flow valuations.
• The objective in many discounted cashflow valuations is to back into a number that
has been obtained by using a multiple.
• The terminal value in a significant number of discounted cashflow valuations is
estimated using a multiple.

Aswath Damodaran 3
Why relative valuation?

“If you think I’m crazy, you should see the guy who lives across the hall”
Jerry Seinfeld talking about Kramer in a Seinfeld episode

“ A little inaccuracy sometimes saves tons of explanation”


H.H. Munro

“ If you are going to screw up, make sure that you have lots of company”
Ex-portfolio manager
Aswath Damodaran 4
So, you believe only in intrinsic value? Here’s why you
should still care about relative value

 Even if you are a true believer in discounted cashflow valuation, presenting


your findings on a relative valuation basis will make it more likely that your
findings/recommendations will reach a receptive audience.
 In some cases, relative valuation can help find weak spots in discounted cash
flow valuations and fix them.
 The problem with multiples is not in their use but in their abuse. If we can
find ways to frame multiples right, we should be able to use them better.

Aswath Damodaran 5
Multiples are just standardized estimates of price…

 You can standardize either the equity value of an asset or the value of the
asset itself, which goes in the numerator.
 You can standardize by dividing by the
• Earnings of the asset
– Price/Earnings Ratio (PE) and variants (PEG and Relative PE)
– Value/EBIT
– Value/EBITDA
– Value/Cash Flow
• Book value of the asset
– Price/Book Value(of Equity) (PBV)
– Value/ Book Value of Assets
– Value/Replacement Cost (Tobin’s Q)
• Revenues generated by the asset
– Price/Sales per Share (PS)
– Value/Sales
• Asset or Industry Specific Variable (Price/kwh, Price per ton of steel ....)

Aswath Damodaran 6
The Four Steps to Understanding Multiples

 Define the multiple


• In use, the same multiple can be defined in different ways by different users. When comparing
and using multiples, estimated by someone else, it is critical that we understand how the
multiples have been estimated
 Describe the multiple
• Too many people who use a multiple have no idea what its cross sectional distribution is. If
you do not know what the cross sectional distribution of a multiple is, it is difficult to look at a
number and pass judgment on whether it is too high or low.
 Analyze the multiple
• It is critical that we understand the fundamentals that drive each multiple, and the nature of the
relationship between the multiple and each variable.
 Apply the multiple
• Defining the comparable universe and controlling for differences is far more difficult in
practice than it is in theory.

Aswath Damodaran 7
Definitional Tests

 Is the multiple consistently defined?


• Proposition 1: Both the value (the numerator) and the standardizing variable
( the denominator) should be to the same claimholders in the firm. In other
words, the value of equity should be divided by equity earnings or equity book
value, and firm value should be divided by firm earnings or book value.
 Is the multiple uniformly estimated?
• The variables used in defining the multiple should be estimated uniformly across
assets in the “comparable firm” list.
• If earnings-based multiples are used, the accounting rules to measure earnings
should be applied consistently across assets. The same rule applies with book-
value based multiples.

Aswath Damodaran 8
Descriptive Tests

 What is the average and standard deviation for this multiple, across the
universe (market)?
 What is the median for this multiple?
• The median for this multiple is often a more reliable comparison point.
 How large are the outliers to the distribution, and how do we deal with the
outliers?
• Throwing out the outliers may seem like an obvious solution, but if the outliers all
lie on one side of the distribution (they usually are large positive numbers), this
can lead to a biased estimate.
 Are there cases where the multiple cannot be estimated? Will ignoring these
cases lead to a biased estimate of the multiple?
 How has this multiple changed over time?

Aswath Damodaran 9
Analytical Tests

 What are the fundamentals that determine and drive these multiples?
• Proposition 2: Embedded in every multiple are all of the variables that drive every
discounted cash flow valuation - growth, risk and cash flow patterns.
• In fact, using a simple discounted cash flow model and basic algebra should yield
the fundamentals that drive a multiple
 How do changes in these fundamentals change the multiple?
• The relationship between a fundamental (like growth) and a multiple (such as PE)
is seldom linear. For example, if firm A has twice the growth rate of firm B, it will
generally not trade at twice its PE ratio
• Proposition 3: It is impossible to properly compare firms on a multiple, if we
do not know the nature of the relationship between fundamentals and the
multiple.

Aswath Damodaran 10
Application Tests

 Given the firm that we are valuing, what is a “comparable” firm?


• While traditional analysis is built on the premise that firms in the same sector are
comparable firms, valuation theory would suggest that a comparable firm is one
which is similar to the one being analyzed in terms of fundamentals.
• Proposition 4: There is no reason why a firm cannot be compared with
another firm in a very different business, if the two firms have the same risk,
growth and cash flow characteristics.
 Given the comparable firms, how do we adjust for differences across firms on
the fundamentals?
• Proposition 5: It is impossible to find an exactly identical firm to the one you
are valuing.

Aswath Damodaran 11
Price Earnings Ratio: Definition

PE = Market Price per Share / Earnings per Share


 There are a number of variants on the basic PE ratio in use. They are based upon how
the price and the earnings are defined.
 Price:
• is usually the current price (though some like to use average price over last 6 months or year)
EPS:
• Time variants: EPS in most recent financial year (current), EPS in most recent four quarters
(trailing), EPS expected in next fiscal year or next four quartes (both called forward) or EPS in
some future year
• Primary, diluted or partially diluted
• Before or after extraordinary items
• Measured using different accounting rules (options expensed or not, pension fund income
counted or not…)

Aswath Damodaran 12
PE Ratio: Distribution for the US: January 2004

Aswath Damodaran 13
PE: Deciphering the Distribution

Current PE Trailing PE Forward PE


Mean 41.41 41.53 30.90
Standard Error 2.42 3.64 1.10
Median 20.76 19.39 19.21
Kurtosis 1062.81 700.63 252.62
Skewness 27.78 24.21 12.48
Minimum 0.40 1.22 2.57
Maximum 6841.25 7184.00 1430.00
Count 4032 3492 2281
500th largest 54.50 43.98 31.13
500th smallest 11.31 11.13 14.29

Aswath Damodaran 14
Comparing PE Ratios: US, Europe, Japan and Emerging
Markets Median PE
Japan = 24.74
US = 20.76
Em. Mkts = 18.87
Europe = 15.99

Aswath Damodaran 15
PE Ratio: Understanding the Fundamentals

 To understand the fundamentals, start with a basic equity discounted cash


flow model.
 With the dividend discount model,
DPS1
P0 =
r ! gn
 Dividing both sides by the current earnings per share,

P0 Payout Ratio * (1 + g n )
= PE =
EPS0 r-gn
 If this had been a FCFE Model,

FCFE1
P0 =
r ! gn
P0 (FCFE/Earnings) * (1+ g n )
= PE =
EPS0 r-g n
Aswath Damodaran 16

!
PE Ratio and Fundamentals

 Proposition: Other things held equal, higher growth firms will have
higher PE ratios than lower growth firms.
 Proposition: Other things held equal, higher risk firms will have lower
PE ratios than lower risk firms
 Proposition: Other things held equal, firms with lower reinvestment
needs will have higher PE ratios than firms with higher reinvestment
rates.
 Of course, other things are difficult to hold equal since high growth firms,
tend to have risk and high reinvestment rats.

Aswath Damodaran 17
Using the Fundamental Model to Estimate PE For a High
Growth Firm

 The price-earnings ratio for a high growth firm can also be related to
fundamentals. In the special case of the two-stage dividend discount model,
this relationship can be made explicit fairly simply:
" (1+ g)n %
EPS0 * Payout Ratio *(1+ g)* $1 !
# (1+ r) n & EPS0 * Payout Ratio n *(1+ g)n *(1+ g n )
P0 = +
r-g (r -g n )(1+ r)n

• For a firm that does not pay what it can afford to in dividends, substitute
FCFE/Earnings for the payout ratio.
 Dividing both sides by the earnings per share:
" (1 + g)n %
Payout Ratio * (1 + g) * $ 1 ! '
P0 # (1+ r) n & Payout Ratio n *(1+ g) n * (1 + gn )
= +
EPS0 r -g (r - g n )(1+ r) n

Aswath Damodaran 18
Expanding the Model

 In this model, the PE ratio for a high growth firm is a function of growth, risk
and payout, exactly the same variables that it was a function of for the stable
growth firm.
 The only difference is that these inputs have to be estimated for two phases -
the high growth phase and the stable growth phase.
 Expanding to more than two phases, say the three stage model, will mean that
risk, growth and cash flow patterns in each stage.

Aswath Damodaran 19
A Simple Example

 Assume that you have been asked to estimate the PE ratio for a firm which
has the following characteristics:
Variable High Growth Phase Stable Growth Phase
Expected Growth Rate 25% 8%
Payout Ratio 20% 50%
Beta 1.00 1.00
Number of years 5 years Forever after year 5
 Riskfree rate = T.Bond Rate = 6%
 Required rate of return = 6% + 1(5.5%)= 11.5%

# (1.25) 5 &
0.2 * (1.25) * %1" 5( 5
$ (1.115) ' 0.5 * (1.25) * (1.08)
PE = + = 28.75
(.115 - .25) (.115 - .08) (1.115) 5

!
Aswath Damodaran 20
PE and Growth: Firm grows at x% for 5 years, 8% thereafter

PE Ratios and Expected Growth: Interest Rate Scenarios

180

160

140

120

100 r=4%
PE Ratio

r=6%
r=8%
80 r=10%

60

40

20

0
5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50%
Expected Growth Rate

Aswath Damodaran 21
PE Ratios and Length of High Growth: 25% growth for n
years; 8% thereafter

Aswath Damodaran 22
PE and Risk: Effects of Changing Betas on PE Ratio:
Firm with x% growth for 5 years; 8% thereafter

PE Ratios and Beta: Growth Scenarios

50

45

40

35

30
g=25%
Ratio

g=20%
25
g=15%
PE

g=8%
20

15

10

0
0.75 1.00 1.25 1.50 1.75 2.00
Beta

Aswath Damodaran 23
PE and Payout

Aswath Damodaran 24
I. Assessing Emerging Market PE Ratios - Early 2000

PE: Emerging Markets

35

30

25

20

15

10

0
Mexico Malaysia Singapore Taiwan Hong Kong Venezuela Brazil Argentina Chile

Aswath Damodaran 25
Comparisons across countries

 In July 2000, a market strategist is making the argument that Brazil and
Venezuela are cheap relative to Chile, because they have much lower PE
ratios. Would you agree?
 Yes
 No
 What are some of the factors that may cause one market’s PE ratios to be
lower than another market’s PE?

Aswath Damodaran 26
II. A Comparison across countries: June 2000

Country PE Dividend Yield 2-yr rate 10-yr rate 10yr - 2yr


UK 22.02 2.59% 5.93% 5.85% -0.08%
Germany 26.33 1.88% 5.06% 5.32% 0.26%
France 29.04 1.34% 5.11% 5.48% 0.37%
Switzerland 19.6 1.42% 3.62% 3.83% 0.21%
Belgium 14.74 2.66% 5.15% 5.70% 0.55%
Italy 28.23 1.76% 5.27% 5.70% 0.43%
Sweden 32.39 1.11% 4.67% 5.26% 0.59%
Netherlands 21.1 2.07% 5.10% 5.47% 0.37%
Australia 21.69 3.12% 6.29% 6.25% -0.04%
Japan 52.25 0.71% 0.58% 1.85% 1.27%
US 25.14 1.10% 6.05% 5.85% -0.20%
Canada 26.14 0.99% 5.70% 5.77% 0.07%

Aswath Damodaran 27
Correlations and Regression of PE Ratios

 Correlations
• Correlation between PE ratio and long term interest rates = -0.733
• Correlation between PE ratio and yield spread = 0.706
 Regression Results
PE Ratio = 42.62 - 3.61 (10’yr rate) + 8.47 (10-yr - 2 yr rate) R2 = 59%
Input the interest rates as percent. For instance, the predicted PE ratio for Japan with
this regression would be:
PE: Japan = 42.62 - 3.61 (1.85) + 8.47 (1.27) = 46.70
At an actual PE ratio of 52.25, Japanese stocks are slightly overvalued.

Aswath Damodaran 28
Predicted PE Ratios

Country Actual PE Predicted PE Under or Over Valued


UK 22.02 20.83 5.71%
Germany 26.33 25.62 2.76%
France 29.04 25.98 11.80%
Switzerland 19.6 30.58 -35.90%
Belgium 14.74 26.71 -44.81%
Italy 28.23 25.69 9.89%
Sweden 32.39 28.63 13.12%
Netherlands 21.1 26.01 -18.88%
Australia 21.69 19.73 9.96%
Japan 52.25 46.70 11.89%
United States 25.14 19.81 26.88%
Canada 26.14 22.39 16.75%

Aswath Damodaran 29
III. An Example with Emerging Markets: June 2000

Country PE Ratio Interest GDP Real Country


Rates Growth Risk
Argentina 14 18.00% 2.50% 45
Brazil 21 14.00% 4.80% 35
Chile 25 9.50% 5.50% 15
Hong Kong 20 8.00% 6.00% 15
India 17 11.48% 4.20% 25
Indonesia 15 21.00% 4.00% 50
Malaysia 14 5.67% 3.00% 40
Mexico 19 11.50% 5.50% 30
Pakistan 14 19.00% 3.00% 45
Peru 15 18.00% 4.90% 50
Phillipines 15 17.00% 3.80% 45
Singapore 24 6.50% 5.20% 5
South Korea 21 10.00% 4.80% 25
Thailand 21 12.75% 5.50% 25
Turkey 12 25.00% 2.00% 35
Venezuela 20 15.00% 3.50% 45

Aswath Damodaran 30
Regression Results

 The regression of PE ratios on these variables provides the following –


PE = 16.16 - 7.94 Interest Rates
+ 154.40 Growth in GDP
- 0.1116 Country Risk
R Squared = 73%

Aswath Damodaran 31
Predicted PE Ratios

Country PE Ratio Interest GDP Real Country Predicted PE


Rates Growth Risk
Argentina 14 18.00% 2.50% 45 13.57
Brazil 21 14.00% 4.80% 35 18.55
Chile 25 9.50% 5.50% 15 22.22
Hong Kong 20 8.00% 6.00% 15 23.11
India 17 11.48% 4.20% 25 18.94
Indonesia 15 21.00% 4.00% 50 15.09
Malaysia 14 5.67% 3.00% 40 15.87
Mexico 19 11.50% 5.50% 30 20.39
Pakistan 14 19.00% 3.00% 45 14.26
Peru 15 18.00% 4.90% 50 16.71
Phillipines 15 17.00% 3.80% 45 15.65
Singapore 24 6.50% 5.20% 5 23.11
South Korea 21 10.00% 4.80% 25 19.98
Thailand 21 12.75% 5.50% 25 20.85
Turkey 12 25.00% 2.00% 35 13.35
Venezuela 20 15.00% 3.50% 45 15.35

Aswath Damodaran 32
IV. Comparisons of PE across time: PE Ratio for the S&P
500

Aswath Damodaran 33
Is low (high) PE cheap (expensive)?

 A market strategist argues that stocks are over priced because the PE ratio
today is too high relative to the average PE ratio across time. Do you agree?
 Yes
 No
 If you do not agree, what factors might explain the higher PE ratio today?

Aswath Damodaran 34
E/P Ratios , T.Bond Rates and Term Structure

Aswath Damodaran 35
Regression Results

 There is a strong positive relationship between E/P ratios and T.Bond rates, as
evidenced by the correlation of 0.69 between the two variables.,
 In addition, there is evidence that the term structure also affects the PE ratio.
 In the following regression, using 1960-2003 data, we regress E/P ratios
against the level of T.Bond rates and a term structure variable (T.Bond -
T.Bill rate)
E/P = 2.03% + 0.753 T.Bond Rate - 0.355 (T.Bond Rate-T.Bill Rate)
(2.19) (6.38) (-1.38)
R squared = 50.85%

Aswath Damodaran 36
Estimate the E/P Ratio Today

 T. Bond Rate =
 T.Bond Rate - T.Bill Rate =
 Expected E/P Ratio =
 Expected PE Ratio =

Aswath Damodaran 37
V. Comparing PE ratios across firms

Company Name Tr ailing PE Expected Gr owth Standar d Dev


Coca-Cola Bottling 29.18 9.50% 20.58%
Molson Inc. Ltd. 'A' 43.65 15.50% 21.88%
Anheuser -Busch 24.31 11.00% 22.92%
Cor by Distiller ies Ltd. 16.24 7.50% 23.66%
Chalone Wine Gr oup Ltd. 21.76 14.00% 24.08%
Andr es Wines Ltd. 'A' 8.96 3.50% 24.70%
Todhunter Int'l 8.94 3.00% 25.74%
Br own-For man 'B' 10.07 11.50% 29.43%
Coor s (Adolph) 'B' 23.02 10.00% 29.52%
PepsiCo, Inc. 33.00 10.50% 31.35%
Coca-Cola 44.33 19.00% 35.51%
Boston Beer 'A' 10.59 17.13% 39.58%
Whitman Cor p. 25.19 11.50% 44.26%
Mondavi (Rober t) 'A' 16.47 14.00% 45.84%
Coca-Cola Enter pr ises 37.14 27.00% 51.34%
Hansen Natur al Cor p 9.70 17.00% 62.45%

Aswath Damodaran 38
A Question

You are reading an equity research report on this sector, and the analyst claims
that Andres Wine and Hansen Natural are under valued because they have
low PE ratios. Would you agree?
 Yes
 No
 Why or why not?

Aswath Damodaran 39
VI. Comparing PE Ratios across a Sector

Company Name PE Growth


PT Indosat ADR 7.8 0.06
Telebras ADR 8.9 0.075
Telecom Corporation of New Zealand ADR 11.2 0.11
Telecom Argentina Stet - France Telecom SA ADR B 12.5 0.08
Hellenic Telecommunication Organization SA ADR 12.8 0.12
Telecomunicaciones de Chile ADR 16.6 0.08
Swisscom AG ADR 18.3 0.11
Asia Satellite Telecom Holdings ADR 19.6 0.16
Portugal Telecom SA ADR 20.8 0.13
Telefonos de Mexico ADR L 21.1 0.14
Matav RT ADR 21.5 0.22
Telstra ADR 21.7 0.12
Gilat Communications 22.7 0.31
Deutsche Telekom AG ADR 24.6 0.11
British Telecommunications PLC ADR 25.7 0.07
Tele Danmark AS ADR 27 0.09
Telekomunikasi Indonesia ADR 28.4 0.32
Cable & Wireless PLC ADR 29.8 0.14
APT Satellite Holdings ADR 31 0.33
Telefonica SA ADR 32.5 0.18
Royal KPN NV ADR 35.7 0.13
Telecom Italia SPA ADR 42.2 0.14
Nippon Telegraph & Telephone ADR 44.3 0.2
France Telecom SA ADR 45.2 0.19
Korea Telecom ADR 71.3 0.44

Aswath Damodaran 40
PE, Growth and Risk

Dependent variable is: PE

R squared = 66.2% R squared (adjusted) = 63.1%

Variable Coefficient SE t-ratio prob


Constant 13.1151 3.471 3.78 0.0010
Growth rate 1.21223 19.27 6.29 ≤ 0.0001
Emerging Market -13.8531 3.606 -3.84 0.0009
Emerging Market is a dummy: 1 if emerging market
0 if not

Aswath Damodaran 41
Is Telebras under valued?

 Predicted PE = 13.12 + 1.2122 (7.5) - 13.85 (1) = 8.35


 At an actual price to earnings ratio of 8.9, Telebras is slightly overvalued.

Aswath Damodaran 42
Using comparable firms- Pros and Cons

 The most common approach to estimating the PE ratio for a firm is


• to choose a group of comparable firms,
• to calculate the average PE ratio for this group and
• to subjectively adjust this average for differences between the firm being valued
and the comparable firms.
 Problems with this approach.
• The definition of a 'comparable' firm is essentially a subjective one.
• The use of other firms in the industry as the control group is often not a solution
because firms within the same industry can have very different business mixes and
risk and growth profiles.
• There is also plenty of potential for bias.
• Even when a legitimate group of comparable firms can be constructed, differences
will continue to persist in fundamentals between the firm being valued and this
group.

Aswath Damodaran 43
Using the entire crosssection: A regression approach

 In contrast to the 'comparable firm' approach, the information in the entire


cross-section of firms can be used to predict PE ratios.
 The simplest way of summarizing this information is with a multiple
regression, with the PE ratio as the dependent variable, and proxies for risk,
growth and payout forming the independent variables.

Aswath Damodaran 44
PE versus Growth

Current PE vs Expected Growth in EPS


January 2004: US Companies
1 20

1 00

80

60

40
Current PE

20

0
-20 0 20 40 60 80

Expected Growth in E PS: next 5 y ears

Aswath Damodaran 45
PE Ratio: Standard Regression for US stocks - January 2004

Mod el Summary

Adjusted R Std. Er ror of the


Mode l R R Square Square Estimate
1 .467 a .21 8 .217 1049.7506205 340
a. Predictor s: ( Constant), PAYOUT, Regre ssion Be ta , Expected
Gr owth in EPS: next 5 years

Co effici entsa,b

Unstandardized Standar dized


Coefficients Coefficients
Mode l B Std. Error Beta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 9.475 .96 1 9.862 .000
Expected G rowth in
EPS: next 5 years .814 .04 6 .375 17.55 8 .000

Regr ession B eta 6.283 .43 7 .298 14.37 5 .000


PAYOUT 6.E-02 .01 4 .092 4.161 .000
a. Dependent Va riable: Current PE
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighted by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran 46
Problems with the regression methodology

 The basic regression assumes a linear relationship between PE ratios and the
financial proxies, and that might not be appropriate.
 The basic relationship between PE ratios and financial variables itself might
not be stable, and if it shifts from year to year, the predictions from the model
may not be reliable.
 The independent variables are correlated with each other. For example, high
growth firms tend to have high risk. This multi-collinearity makes the
coefficients of the regressions unreliable and may explain the large changes in
these coefficients from period to period.

Aswath Damodaran 47
The Multicollinearity Problem
Correlatio ns

Expected
Growth in
Revenues: Regr ession
next 5 ye ars Beta PAYOUT
Expected G rowth in Pear son Correlation 1 .031 -.325**
Reven ues: next 5 year s Sig. (2 -tailed) . .228 .000
N 147 2 1472 1185
Regression Bet a Pear son Correlation .03 1 1 -.183**
Sig. (2 -tailed) .22 8 . .000
N 147 2 6933 4187
PAYOUT Pear son Correlation -.325** -.183** 1
Sig. (2 -tailed) .00 0 .000 .
N 118 5 4187 4187
**. Correlation is significa nt at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).

Aswath Damodaran 48
Using the PE ratio regression

 Assume that you were given the following information for Dell. The firm has
an expected growth rate of 10%, a beta of 1.20 and pays no dividends. Based
upon the regression, estimate the predicted PE ratio for Dell.
Predicted PE =

 Dell is actually trading at 22 times earnings. What does the predicted PE tell
you?

Aswath Damodaran 49
The value of growth

Time Period Value of extra 1% of growth Equity Risk Premium


January 2004 0.812 3.69%
July 2003 1.228 3.88%
January 2003 2.621 4.10%
July 2002 0.859 4.35%
January 2002 1.003 3.62%
July 2001 1.251 3.05%
January 2001 1.457 2.75%
July 2000 1.761 2.20%
January 2000 2.105 2.05%
The value of growth is in terms of additional PE…

Aswath Damodaran 50
Investment Strategies that compare PE to the expected
growth rate

 If we assume that all firms within a sector have similar growth rates and risk,
a strategy of picking the lowest PE ratio stock in each sector will yield
undervalued stocks.
 Portfolio managers and analysts sometimes compare PE ratios to the expected
growth rate to identify under and overvalued stocks.
• In the simplest form of this approach, firms with PE ratios less than their expected
growth rate are viewed as undervalued.
• In its more general form, the ratio of PE ratio to growth is used as a measure of
relative value.

Aswath Damodaran 51
Problems with comparing PE ratios to expected growth

 In its simple form, there is no basis for believing that a firm is undervalued
just because it has a PE ratio less than expected growth.
 This relationship may be consistent with a fairly valued or even an overvalued
firm, if interest rates are high, or if a firm is high risk.
 As interest rate decrease (increase), fewer (more) stocks will emerge as
undervalued using this approach.

Aswath Damodaran 52
PE Ratio versus Growth - The Effect of Interest rates:
Average Risk firm with 25% growth for 5 years; 8% thereafter

Aswath Damodaran 53
PE Ratios Less Than The Expected Growth Rate

 In January 2004,
• 33% of firms had PE ratios lower than the expected 5-year growth rate
• 67% of firms had PE ratios higher than the expected 5-year growth rate
 In comparison,
• 38.1% of firms had PE ratios less than the expected 5-year growth rate in
September 1991
• 65.3% of firm had PE ratios less than the expected 5-year growth rate in 1981.

Aswath Damodaran 54
PEG Ratio: Definition

 The PEG ratio is the ratio of price earnings to expected growth in earnings per
share.
PEG = PE / Expected Growth Rate in Earnings
 Definitional tests:
• Is the growth rate used to compute the PEG ratio
– on the same base? (base year EPS)
– over the same period?(2 years, 5 years)
– from the same source? (analyst projections, consensus estimates..)
• Is the earnings used to compute the PE ratio consistent with the growth rate
estimate?
– No double counting: If the estimate of growth in earnings per share is from the current
year, it would be a mistake to use forward EPS in computing PE
– If looking at foreign stocks or ADRs, is the earnings used for the PE ratio consistent with
the growth rate estimate? (US analysts use the ADR EPS)

Aswath Damodaran 55
PEG Ratio: Distribution

Aswath Damodaran 56
PEG Ratios: The Beverage Sector

Company Name Tr ailing PE Gr owth Std Dev P EG


Coca-Cola Bottling 29.18 9.50% 20.58% 3.07
Molson Inc. Ltd. 'A' 43.65 15.50% 21.88% 2.82
Anheuser -Busch 24.31 11.00% 22.92% 2.21
Cor by Distiller ies Ltd. 16.24 7.50% 23.66% 2.16
Chalone Wine Gr oup Ltd. 21.76 14.00% 24.08% 1.55
Andr es Wines Ltd. 'A' 8.96 3.50% 24.70% 2.56
Todhunter Int'l 8.94 3.00% 25.74% 2.98
Br own-For man 'B' 10.07 11.50% 29.43% 0.88
Coor s (Adolph) 'B' 23.02 10.00% 29.52% 2.30
PepsiCo, Inc. 33.00 10.50% 31.35% 3.14
Coca-Cola 44.33 19.00% 35.51% 2.33
Boston Beer 'A' 10.59 17.13% 39.58% 0.62
Whitman Cor p. 25.19 11.50% 44.26% 2.19
Mondavi (Rober t) 'A' 16.47 14.00% 45.84% 1.18
Coca-Cola Enter pr ises 37.14 27.00% 51.34% 1.38
Hansen Natur al Cor p 9.70 17.00% 62.45% 0.57
Aver age 22.66 0.13 0.33 2.00

Aswath Damodaran 57
PEG Ratio: Reading the Numbers

 The average PEG ratio for the beverage sector is 2.00. The lowest PEG ratio
in the group belongs to Hansen Natural, which has a PEG ratio of 0.57. Using
this measure of value, Hansen Natural is
 the most under valued stock in the group
 the most over valued stock in the group
 What other explanation could there be for Hansen’s low PEG ratio?

Aswath Damodaran 58
PEG Ratio: Analysis

 To understand the fundamentals that determine PEG ratios, let us return again
to a 2-stage equity discounted cash flow model
" (1+ g)n %
EPS0 * Payout Ratio *(1+ g)* $1 !
# (1+ r) n & EPS0 * Payout Ratio n *(1+ g)n *(1+ g n )
P0 = +
r-g (r -g n )(1+ r)n

 Dividing both sides of the equation by the earnings gives us the equation for
the PE ratio. Dividing it again by the expected growth ‘g’

" (1+ g)n %


Payout Ratio *(1 + g) * $ 1 !
# (1 + r) n & Payout Ratio n * (1+ g)n * (1+ g n )
PEG = +
g(r - g) g(r - gn )(1 + r)n

Aswath Damodaran 59
PEG Ratios and Fundamentals

 Risk and payout, which affect PE ratios, continue to affect PEG ratios as well.
• Implication: When comparing PEG ratios across companies, we are making
implicit or explicit assumptions about these variables.
 Dividing PE by expected growth does not neutralize the effects of expected
growth, since the relationship between growth and value is not linear and
fairly complex (even in a 2-stage model)

Aswath Damodaran 60
A Simple Example

 Assume that you have been asked to estimate the PEG ratio for a firm which
has the following characteristics:
Variable High Growth Phase Stable Growth Phase
Expected Growth Rate 25% 8%
Payout Ratio 20% 50%
Beta 1.00 1.00
 Riskfree rate = T.Bond Rate = 6%
 Required rate of return = 6% + 1(5.5%)= 11.5%
 The PEG ratio for this firm can be estimated as follows:

# (1.25) 5 &
0.2 * (1.25) * %1" 5(
$ (1.115) ' 0.5 * (1.25) 5 * (1.08)
PEG = + = 115 or 1.15
.25(.115 - .25) .25(.115 - .08) (1.115) 5

Aswath Damodaran 61
!
PEG Ratios and Risk

Aswath Damodaran 62
PEG Ratios and Quality of Growth

Aswath Damodaran 63
PE Ratios and Expected Growth

Aswath Damodaran 64
PEG Ratios and Fundamentals: Propositions

 Proposition 1: High risk companies will trade at much lower PEG ratios than
low risk companies with the same expected growth rate.
• Corollary 1: The company that looks most under valued on a PEG ratio basis in a
sector may be the riskiest firm in the sector
 Proposition 2: Companies that can attain growth more efficiently by investing
less in better return projects will have higher PEG ratios than companies that
grow at the same rate less efficiently.
• Corollary 2: Companies that look cheap on a PEG ratio basis may be companies
with high reinvestment rates and poor project returns.
 Proposition 3: Companies with very low or very high growth rates will tend to
have higher PEG ratios than firms with average growth rates. This bias is
worse for low growth stocks.
• Corollary 3: PEG ratios do not neutralize the growth effect.

Aswath Damodaran 65
PE, PEG Ratios and Risk

45 2.5

40

2
35

30

1.5
25
PE
PEG Ratio
20
1

15

10
0.5

0 0
Lowest 2 3 4 Highest

Aswath Damodaran 66
PEG Ratio: Returning to the Beverage Sector
Company Name Tr ailing PE Gr owth Std Dev P EG
Coca-Cola Bottling 29.18 9.50% 20.58% 3.07
Molson Inc. Ltd. 'A' 43.65 15.50% 21.88% 2.82
Anheuser -Busch 24.31 11.00% 22.92% 2.21
Cor by Distiller ies Ltd. 16.24 7.50% 23.66% 2.16
Chalone Wine Gr oup Ltd. 21.76 14.00% 24.08% 1.55
Andr es Wines Ltd. 'A' 8.96 3.50% 24.70% 2.56
Todhunter Int'l 8.94 3.00% 25.74% 2.98
Br own-For man 'B' 10.07 11.50% 29.43% 0.88
Coor s (Adolph) 'B' 23.02 10.00% 29.52% 2.30
PepsiCo, Inc. 33.00 10.50% 31.35% 3.14
Coca-Cola 44.33 19.00% 35.51% 2.33
Boston Beer 'A' 10.59 17.13% 39.58% 0.62
Whitman Cor p. 25.19 11.50% 44.26% 2.19
Mondavi (Rober t) 'A' 16.47 14.00% 45.84% 1.18
Coca-Cola Enter pr ises 37.14 27.00% 51.34% 1.38
Hansen Natur al Cor p 9.70 17.00% 62.45% 0.57
Aver age 22.66 0.13 0.33 2.00

Aswath Damodaran 67
Analyzing PE/Growth

 Given that the PEG ratio is still determined by the expected growth rates, risk
and cash flow patterns, it is necessary that we control for differences in these
variables.
 Regressing PEG against risk and a measure of the growth dispersion, we get:
PEG = 3.61 -.0286 (Expected Growth) - .0375 (Std Deviation in Prices)
R Squared = 44.75%
 In other words,
• PEG ratios will be lower for high growth companies
• PEG ratios will be lower for high risk companies
 We also ran the regression using the deviation of the actual growth rate from
the industry-average growth rate as the independent variable, with mixed
results.

Aswath Damodaran 68
Estimating the PEG Ratio for Hansen

 Applying this regression to Hansen, the predicted PEG ratio for the firm can
be estimated using Hansen’s measures for the independent variables:
• Expected Growth Rate = 17.00%
• Standard Deviation in Stock Prices = 62.45%
 Plugging in,
Expected PEG Ratio for Hansen = 3.61 - .0286 (17) - .0375 (62.45)
= 0.78
 With its actual PEG ratio of 0.57, Hansen looks undervalued, notwithstanding
its high risk.

Aswath Damodaran 69
Extending the Comparables

 This analysis, which is restricted to firms in the software sector, can be


expanded to include all firms in the firm, as long as we control for differences
in risk, growth and payout.
 To look at the cross sectional relationship, we first plotted PEG ratios against
expected growth rates.

Aswath Damodaran 70
PEG versus Growth

PEG Ratio v s Expected Growth in EPS


January 2004: US Companies
10

4
PEG Ratio

0
-20 0 20 40 60 80 1 00

Expected Growth in E PS: next 5 y ears

Aswath Damodaran 71
Analyzing the Relationship

 The relationship in not linear. In fact, the smallest firms seem to have the
highest PEG ratios and PEG ratios become relatively stable at higher growth
rates.
 To make the relationship more linear, we converted the expected growth rates
in ln(expected growth rate). The relationship between PEG ratios and
ln(expected growth rate) was then plotted.

Aswath Damodaran 72
PEG versus ln(Expected Growth)

PEG vs ln (Expected Growth)


January 2004: US Companies
10

4
PEG Ratio

0
0 1 2 3 4 5

ln (Exp ected Gro wth R ate)

Aswath Damodaran 73
PEG Ratio Regression - US stocks in January 2004

Model Summary

Adjusted R Std. Er ror of the


Mode l R R Square Squar e Estimate
1 a
.492 .242 .241 91. 242648963259
a. Predictors: ( Constant), LNGROWTH, Re gression B eta,
PAYOUT

Co ef fici entsa,b

Unstandard ized Standar dized


Coefficients Coefficients
Mode l B Std. Er ror Beta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 4.308 .15 5 27. 774 .000
Regr ession B eta .539 .03 8 .293 14. 249 .000
PAYOUT 6.E-03 .00 1 .116 5.262 .000
LNGROWTH -1.042 .05 5 -.404 -18.86 .000
a. Dependent Va riable: PE G Ratio
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran 74
Applying the PEG ratio regression

 Consider Dell again. The stock has an expected growth rate of 10%, a beta of
1.20 and pays out no dividends. What should its PEG ratio be?

 If the stock’s actual PE ratio is 23, what does this analysis tell you about the
stock?

Aswath Damodaran 75
A Variant on PEG Ratio: The PEGY ratio

 The PEG ratio is biased against low growth firms because the relationship
between value and growth is non-linear. One variant that has been devised to
consolidate the growth rate and the expected dividend yield:
PEGY = PE / (Expected Growth Rate + Dividend Yield)
 As an example, Con Ed has a PE ratio of 16, an expected growth rate of 5% in
earnings and a dividend yield of 4.5%.
• PEG = 16/ 5 = 3.2
• PEGY = 16/(5+4.5) = 1.7

Aswath Damodaran 76
Relative PE: Definition

 The relative PE ratio of a firm is the ratio of the PE of the firm to the PE of
the market.
Relative PE = PE of Firm / PE of Market
 While the PE can be defined in terms of current earnings, trailing earnings or
forward earnings, consistency requires that it be estimated using the same
measure of earnings for both the firm and the market.
 Relative PE ratios are usually compared over time. Thus, a firm or sector
which has historically traded at half the market PE (Relative PE = 0.5) is
considered over valued if it is trading at a relative PE of 0.7.
 Relative PE ratios are also used when comparing companies across markets
with different PE ratios (Japanese versus US stocks, for example).

Aswath Damodaran 77
Relative PE: Determinants

 To analyze the determinants of the relative PE ratios, let us revisit the discounted cash
flow model we developed for the PE ratio. Using the 2-stage DDM model as our basis
(replacing the payout ratio with the FCFE/Earnings Ratio, if necessary), we get

" (1+ g j )n %
Payout Ratio j *(1 + g j ) * $ 1 ! '
# (1+ rj )n & Payout Ratio j,n *(1 + g j )n *(1 + g j,n )
+
rj - g j (rj - g j,n )(1 + rj )n
Relative PE j =
"$ (1+ g m ) n %'
Payout Ratio m * (1+ g m )* 1 !
# (1+ rm )n & Payout Ratio m,n * (1+ g m )n *(1 + gm, n )
+ n
where r - g
Payout , g , r = Payout, growth and risk of the firm
m m (r m - g m,n )(1+ rm )
j j j
Payoutm, gm, rm = Payout, growth and risk of the market

Aswath Damodaran 78
Relative PE: A Simple Example

 Consider the following example of a firm growing at twice the rate as the
market, while having the same growth and risk characteristics of the market:
Firm Market
Expected growth rate 20% 10%
Length of Growth Period 5 years 5 years
Payout Ratio: first 5 yrs 30% 30%
Growth Rate after yr 5 6% 6%
Payout Ratio after yr 5 50% 50%
Beta 1.00 1.00
Riskfree Rate = 6%

Aswath Damodaran 79
Estimating Relative PE

 The relative PE ratio for this firm can be estimated in two steps. First, we
compute the PE ratio for the firm and the market separately:
5
" (1.20) %
0.3 * (1.20) * $ 1!
# (1.115) 5 & 0.5 * (1.20)5 * (1.06)
PE firm = + = 15.79
(.115 - .20) (.115 -.06) (1.115)5

" (1.10)5 %
0.3 * (1.10) * $ 1!
# (1.115)5 & 0.5 * (1.10) 5 *(1.06)
PE market = + 5 = 10.45
(.115 - .10) (.115-.06) (1.115)

 Relative PE Ratio = 15.79/10.45 = 1.51

Aswath Damodaran 80
Relative PE and Relative Growth

Aswath Damodaran 81
Relative PE: Another Example

 In this example, consider a firm with twice the risk as the market, while
having the same growth and payout characteristics as the firm:
Firm Market
Expected growth rate 10% 10%
Length of Growth Period 5 years 5 years
Payout Ratio: first 5 yrs 30% 30%
Growth Rate after yr 5 6% 6%
Payout Ratio after yr 5 50% 50%
Beta in first 5 years 2.00 1.00
Beta after year 5 1.00 1.00
Riskfree Rate = 6%

Aswath Damodaran 82
Estimating Relative PE

 The relative PE ratio for this firm can be estimated in two steps. First, we
compute the PE ratio for the firm and the market separately:
" (1.10) 5 %
0.3 * (1.10) * $ 1 !
# (1.17) 5 & 5
0.5 * (1.10) * (1.06)
PE firm = + = 8.33
(.17 - .10) (.115- .06) (1.17)5

" (1.10)5 %
0.3 * (1.10) * $ 1!
# (1.115)5 & 0.5 * (1.10) 5 *(1.06)
PE market = + 5 = 10.45
(.115 - .10) (.115-.06) (1.115)

 Relative PE Ratio = 8.33/10.45 = 0.80

Aswath Damodaran 83
Relative PE and Relative Risk

Relative PE and Relative Risk: Stable Beta Scenarios

4.5

3.5

2.5
Beta stays at current level
Beta drops to 1 in stable phase
2

1.5

0.5

0
0.25 0.5 0.75 1 1.25 1.5 1.75 2

Aswath Damodaran 84
Relative PE: Summary of Determinants

 The relative PE ratio of a firm is determined by two variables. In particular, it


will
• increase as the firm’s growth rate relative to the market increases. The rate of
change in the relative PE will itself be a function of the market growth rate, with
much greater changes when the market growth rate is higher. In other words, a
firm or sector with a growth rate twice that of the market will have a much higher
relative PE when the market growth rate is 10% than when it is 5%.
• decrease as the firm’s risk relative to the market increases. The extent of the
decrease depends upon how long the firm is expected to stay at this level of
relative risk. If the different is permanent, the effect is much greater.
 Relative PE ratios seem to be unaffected by the level of rates, which might
give them a decided advantage over PE ratios.

Aswath Damodaran 85
Relative PE Ratios: The Auto Sector

Relative PE Ratios: Auto Stocks

1.20

1.00

0.80

Ford
0.60 Chrysler
GM

0.40

0.20

0.00
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Aswath Damodaran 86
Using Relative PE ratios

 On a relative PE basis, all of the automobile stocks looked cheap in 2000


because they were trading at their lowest relative PE ratios than 1993. Why
might the relative PE ratio be lower in 2000 than in 1993?

Aswath Damodaran 87
Relative PE Ratios: US stocks

Model Su mmar y

Adjusted R Std. Er ror of


Mode l R R Square Square the Estimate
1 .467 a .21 8 .217 41.97324
a. Predictors: ( Constant), Regr ession Bet a, RELGR,
RELPA YO U

Co ef fici entsa,b

Unstandard ized Standar dized


Coefficients Coefficients
Mode l B Std. Er ror Beta t Sig.
1 (Constant) .379 .03 8 9.862 .000
RELPAYO U 4.E-02 .00 9 .092 4.161 .000
RELG R .506 .02 9 .375 17. 558 .000
Regr ession B eta .251 .01 7 .298 14. 375 .000
a. Dependent Va riable: RELPE
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran 88
Value/Earnings and Value/Cashflow Ratios

 While Price earnings ratios look at the market value of equity relative to
earnings to equity investors, Value earnings ratios look at the market value of
the operating assets of the firm (Enterprise value or EV) relative to operating
earnings or cash flows.
 The form of value to cash flow ratios that has the closest parallels in DCF
valuation is the value to Free Cash Flow to the Firm, which is defined as:
EV/FCFF = (Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt-Cash)
EBIT (1-t) - (Cap Ex - Deprecn) - Chg in Working Cap

Aswath Damodaran 89
Value of Firm/FCFF: Determinants

 Reverting back to a two-stage FCFF DCF model, we get:


! (1 + g)n $
FCFF (1 + g) # 1- &
0 " (1+ WACC) % n FCFF (1+ g)n (1+ g )
V0 = + 0 n
WACC - g (WACC - g )(1 + WACC)n
n
• V0 = Value of the firm (today)
• FCFF0 = Free Cashflow to the firm in current year
• g = Expected growth rate in FCFF in extraordinary growth period (first n years)
• WACC = Weighted average cost of capital
• gn = Expected growth rate in FCFF in stable growth period (after n years)

Aswath Damodaran 90
Value Multiples

 Dividing both sides by the FCFF yields,


!# (1 + g)n $
(1 + g) 1-
V0 " (1 + WACC)n % (1+ g)n (1+ gn )
= + n
FCFF0 WACC - g (WACC - gn )(1 + WACC)

 The value/FCFF multiples is a function of


• the cost of capital
• the expected growth

Aswath Damodaran 91
Alternatives to FCFF - EBIT and EBITDA

 Most analysts find FCFF to complex or messy to use in multiples (partly


because capital expenditures and working capital have to be estimated). They
use modified versions of the multiple with the following alternative
denominator:
• after-tax operating income or EBIT(1-t)
• pre-tax operating income or EBIT
• net operating income (NOI), a slightly modified version of operating income,
where any non-operating expenses and income is removed from the EBIT
• EBITDA, which is earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization.

Aswath Damodaran 92
Value/FCFF Multiples and the Alternatives

 Assume that you have computed the value of a firm, using discounted cash
flow models. Rank the following multiples in the order of magnitude from
lowest to highest?
 Value/EBIT
 Value/EBIT(1-t)
 Value/FCFF
 Value/EBITDA
 What assumption(s) would you need to make for the Value/EBIT(1-t) ratio to
be equal to the Value/FCFF multiple?

Aswath Damodaran 93
Illustration: Using Value/FCFF Approaches to value a firm:
MCI Communications

 MCI Communications had earnings before interest and taxes of $3356 million
in 1994 (Its net income after taxes was $855 million).
 It had capital expenditures of $2500 million in 1994 and depreciation of
$1100 million; Working capital increased by $250 million.
 It expects free cashflows to the firm to grow 15% a year for the next five years
and 5% a year after that.
 The cost of capital is 10.50% for the next five years and 10% after that.
 The company faces a tax rate of 36%.

 (1.15)5 
(1.15)  1-
(1.105)5 
5
V0 (1.15) (1.05)
= + 5
= 31.28
FCFF0 .105 -.15 (.10 - .05)(1.105)

Aswath Damodaran 94
Multiple Magic

 In this case of MCI there is a big difference between the FCFF and short cut
measures. For instance the following table illustrates the appropriate multiple
using short cut measures, and the amount you would overpay by if you used
the FCFF multiple.
Free Cash Flow to the Firm
= EBIT (1-t) - Net Cap Ex - Change in Working Capital
= 3356 (1 - 0.36) + 1100 - 2500 - 250 = $ 498 million
$ Value Correct Multiple
FCFF $498 31.28382355
EBIT (1-t) $2,148 7.251163362
EBIT $ 3,356 4.640744552
EBITDA $4,456 3.49513885

Aswath Damodaran 95
Reasons for Increased Use of Value/EBITDA

1. The multiple can be computed even for firms that are reporting net losses, since
earnings before interest, taxes and depreciation are usually positive.
2. For firms in certain industries, such as cellular, which require a substantial
investment in infrastructure and long gestation periods, this multiple seems to
be more appropriate than the price/earnings ratio.
3. In leveraged buyouts, where the key factor is cash generated by the firm prior
to all discretionary expenditures, the EBITDA is the measure of cash flows
from operations that can be used to support debt payment at least in the short
term.
4. By looking at cashflows prior to capital expenditures, it may provide a better
estimate of “optimal value”, especially if the capital expenditures are unwise
or earn substandard returns.
5. By looking at the value of the firm and cashflows to the firm it allows for
comparisons across firms with different financial leverage.

Aswath Damodaran 96
Enterprise Value/EBITDA Multiple

 The Classic Definition


Value Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt
=
EBITDA Earnings before Interest, Taxes and Depreciation

 The No-Cash Version

Enterprise Value Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt - Cash


=
EBITDA Earnings before Interest, Taxes and Depreciation

Aswath Damodaran 97
Enterprise Value/EBITDA Distribution - US in January 2004

Aswath Damodaran 98
Value/EBITDA Multiple: Europe, Japan and Emerging
Markets in January 2004

Aswath Damodaran 99
The Determinants of Value/EBITDA Multiples: Linkage to
DCF Valuation

 The value of the operating assets of a firm can be written as:


FCFF1
V0 =
WACC - g
 The numerator can be written as follows:
FCFF = EBIT (1-t) - (Cex - Depr) - Δ Working Capital
= (EBITDA - Depr) (1-t) - (Cex - Depr) - Δ Working Capital
= EBITDA (1-t) + Depr (t) - Cex - Δ Working Capital

Aswath Damodaran 100


From Firm Value to EBITDA Multiples

 Now the Value of the firm can be rewritten as,


EBITDA (1- t) + Depr (t) - Cex - ! Working Capital
Value =
WACC - g

 Dividing both sides of the equation by EBITDA,


Value (1- t) Depr (t)/EBITDA CEx/EBITDA ! Working Capital/EBITDA
= + - -
EBITDA WACC- g WACC -g WACC - g WACC - g

Aswath Damodaran 101


A Simple Example

 Consider a firm with the following characteristics:


• Tax Rate = 36%
• Capital Expenditures/EBITDA = 30%
• Depreciation/EBITDA = 20%
• Cost of Capital = 10%
• The firm has no working capital requirements
• The firm is in stable growth and is expected to grow 5% a year forever.

Aswath Damodaran 102


Calculating Value/EBITDA Multiple

 In this case, the Value/EBITDA multiple for this firm can be estimated as
follows:
Value (1- .36) (0.2)(.36) 0.3 0
= + - - = 8.24
EBITDA .10 -.05 .10 -.05 .10 - .05 .10 - .05

Aswath Damodaran 103


Value/EBITDA Multiples and Taxes

Aswath Damodaran 104


Value/EBITDA and Net Cap Ex

Aswath Damodaran 105


Value/EBITDA Multiples and Return on Capital

Aswath Damodaran 106


Value/EBITDA Multiple: Trucking Companies

Company Name Value EBITDA Value/EBITDA


KLLM Trans. Svcs. $ 114.32 $ 48.81 2.34
Ryder System $ 5,158.04 $ 1,838.26 2.81
Rollins Truck Leasing $ 1,368.35 $ 447.67 3.06
Cannon Express Inc. $ 83.57 $ 27.05 3.09
Hunt (J.B.) $ 982.67 $ 310.22 3.17
Yellow Corp. $ 931.47 $ 292.82 3.18
Roadway Express $ 554.96 $ 169.38 3.28
Marten Transport Ltd. $ 116.93 $ 35.62 3.28
Kenan Transport Co. $ 67.66 $ 19.44 3.48
M.S. Carriers $ 344.93 $ 97.85 3.53
Old Dominion Freight $ 170.42 $ 45.13 3.78
Trimac Ltd $ 661.18 $ 174.28 3.79
Matlack Systems $ 112.42 $ 28.94 3.88
XTRA Corp. $ 1,708.57 $ 427.30 4.00
Covenant Transport Inc $ 259.16 $ 64.35 4.03
Builders Transport $ 221.09 $ 51.44 4.30
Werner Enterprises $ 844.39 $ 196.15 4.30
Landstar Sys. $ 422.79 $ 95.20 4.44
AMERCO $ 1,632.30 $ 345.78 4.72
USA Truck $ 141.77 $ 29.93 4.74
Frozen Food Express $ 164.17 $ 34.10 4.81
Arnold Inds. $ 472.27 $ 96.88 4.87
Greyhound Lines Inc. $ 437.71 $ 89.61 4.88
USFreightways $ 983.86 $ 198.91 4.95
Golden Eagle Group Inc. $ 12.50 $ 2.33 5.37
Arkansas Best $ 578.78 $ 107.15 5.40
Airlease Ltd. $ 73.64 $ 13.48 5.46
Celadon Group $ 182.30 $ 32.72 5.57
Amer. Freightways $ 716.15 $ 120.94 5.92
Transfinancial Holdings $ 56.92 $ 8.79 6.47
Vitran Corp. 'A' $ 140.68 $ 21.51 6.54
Interpool Inc. $ 1,002.20 $ 151.18 6.63
Intrenet Inc. $ 70.23 $ 10.38 6.77
Swift Transportation $ 835.58 $ 121.34 6.89
Landair Services $ 212.95 $ 30.38 7.01
CNF Transportation $ 2,700.69 $ 366.99 7.36
Budget Group Inc $ 1,247.30 $ 166.71 7.48
Caliber System $ 2,514.99 $ 333.13 7.55
Knight Transportation Inc $ 269.01 $ 28.20 9.54
Heartland Express $ 727.50 $ 64.62 11.26
Greyhound CDA Transn Corp $ 83.25 $ 6.99 11.91
Mark VII $ 160.45 $ 12.96 12.38
Coach USA Inc $ 678.38 $ 51.76 13.11
US 1 Inds Inc. $ 5.60 $ (0.17) NA
Average 5.61

Aswath Damodaran 107


A Test on EBITDA

 Ryder System looks very cheap on a Value/EBITDA multiple basis, relative


to the rest of the sector. What explanation (other than misvaluation) might
there be for this difference?

Aswath Damodaran 108


Analyzing the Value/EBITDA Multiple

 While low value/EBITDA multiples may be a symptom of undervaluation, a


few questions need to be answered:
• Is the operating income next year expected to be significantly lower than the
EBITDA for the most recent period? (Price may have dropped)
• Does the firm have significant capital expenditures coming up? (In the trucking
business, the life of the trucking fleet would be a good indicator)
• Does the firm have a much higher cost of capital than other firms in the sector?
• Does the firm face a much higher tax rate than other firms in the sector?

Aswath Damodaran 109


Value/EBITDA Multiples: Market

 The multiple of value to EBITDA varies widely across firms in the market,
depending upon:
• how capital intensive the firm is (high capital intensity firms will tend to have
lower value/EBITDA ratios), and how much reinvestment is needed to keep the
business going and create growth
• how high or low the cost of capital is (higher costs of capital will lead to lower
Value/EBITDA multiples)
• how high or low expected growth is in the sector (high growth sectors will tend to
have higher Value/EBITDA multiples)

Aswath Damodaran 110


US Market: Cross Sectional Regression
January 2004
Model Summary

Adjusted R Std. Er ror of the


Mode l R R Square Square Estimate
1 a
.583 .34 0 .33 8 653 .801855 07239
a. Predictor s: ( Constant), Reinvestment Rate, Expected Gr owth
in Revenues: next 5 years, Eff Tax Rat e

Co ef fici entsa,b

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 10. 073 .768 13.121 .00 0
Eff T ax Rate -.152 .022 -.174 -6.878 .00 0
Expected G rowth in
.907 .039 .563 23.464 .00 0
Revenues: next 5 year s
Reinvestment Rate -.015 .006 -.062 -2.420 .01 6
a. Dependent Va riable: EV /EBITDA
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran 111


Europe: Cross Sectional Regression
January 2004

Model Summary

Adjusted R
Mode l R R Square Square Std. Er ror of the Estimate
1 .542 a .293 .292 1581.333005721082 000
a. Predictors: ( Constant), Tax Rate , Reinv Rate , Market Debt to Ca pital

Coefficientsa,b

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 8.419 1.2 79 6.580 .00 0
Mar ket Debt t o Capital .58 9 .021 .511 28. 035 .00 0
Reinv Ra te -.051 .009 -.099 -5.472 .00 0
Tax Rat e -.152 .029 -.095 -5.236 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: EV/EBITDA
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - Weig hted by Marke t Capitalization

Aswath Damodaran 112


Price-Book Value Ratio: Definition

 The price/book value ratio is the ratio of the market value of equity to the
book value of equity, i.e., the measure of shareholders’ equity in the balance
sheet.
 Price/Book Value = Market Value of Equity
Book Value of Equity
 Consistency Tests:
• If the market value of equity refers to the market value of equity of common stock
outstanding, the book value of common equity should be used in the denominator.
• If there is more that one class of common stock outstanding, the market values of
all classes (even the non-traded classes) needs to be factored in.

Aswath Damodaran 113


Price to Book Value: US stocks

Aswath Damodaran 114


Price to Book: Europe, Japan and Emerging Markets

Aswath Damodaran 115


Price Book Value Ratio: Stable Growth Firm

Going back to a simple dividend DPS1 model,


 P 0 =discount
r ! gn

 Defining the return on equity (ROE) = EPS0 / Book Value of Equity, the value of equity
can be written as:
BV 0 * ROE * Payout Ratio * (1 + gn )
P0 =
r-gn
P0 ROE * Payout Ratio * (1 + g n )
= PBV =
BV 0 r-g n

 If the return on equity is based upon expected earnings in the next time period, this can
be simplified to,

P0 ROE * Payout Ratio


= PBV =
BV 0 r-g n

Aswath Damodaran 116


Price Book Value Ratio: Stable Growth Firm
Another Presentation

 This formulation can be simplified even further by relating growth to the


return on equity:
g = (1 - Payout ratio) * ROE
 Substituting back into the P/BV equation,
P0 ROE - g n
= PBV =
BV0 r-g n

 The price-book value ratio of a stable firm is determined by the differential


between the!return on equity and the required rate of return on its projects.

Aswath Damodaran 117


Price Book Value Ratio for High Growth Firm

 The Price-book ratio for a high-growth firm can be estimated beginning with
a 2-stage discounted cash" flow model:
(1+ g)n %
EPS0 * Payout Ratio * (1 + g) * $ 1 ! '
# (1+ r) n & EPS0 * Payout Ratio n * (1+ g)n *(1+ g n )
P0 = +
r -g (r - g n )(1+ r) n

 Dividing both sides of the equation by the book value of equity:


' "$ (1+ g)n % *
ROE* Payout Ratio *(1+ g)* 1 !
P0 ) # (1+ r) n & ROE n * Payout Ratio n *(1+ g)n *(1+ g n ) ,
=) + ,
BV0 r-g (r - gn )(1+ r)n
) ,
( +

where ROE = Return on Equity in high-growth period


ROEn = Return on Equity in stable growth period

Aswath Damodaran 118


PBV Ratio for High Growth Firm: Example

 Assume that you have been asked to estimate the PBV ratio for a firm which
has the following characteristics:
High Growth Phase Stable Growth Phase
Length of Period 5 years Forever after year 5
Return on Equity 25% 15%
Payout Ratio 20% 60%
Growth Rate .80*.25=.20 .4*.15=.06
Beta 1.25 1.00
Cost of Equity 12.875% 11.50%
The riskfree rate is 6% and the risk premium used is 5.5%.

Aswath Damodaran 119


Estimating Price/Book Value Ratio

 The price/book value ratio for this firm is:

' "$ (1.20) 5 % *


0.25 * 0.2 * (1.20) * 1!
) # (1.12875) 5 & 0.15 * 0.6 * (1.20)5 * (1.06) ,
PBV = ) + = 2.66
(.12875 - .20) (.115 - .06) (1.12875) 5 ,
) ,
( +

Aswath Damodaran 120


PBV and ROE: The Key

PBV and ROE: Risk Scenarios

3.5

3
Ratios

2.5
Value

Beta=0.5
2 Beta=1
Beta=1.5
Price/Book

1.5

0.5

0
10% 15% 20% 25% 30%
ROE

Aswath Damodaran 121


PBV/ROE: European Banks
Bank Symbol PBV ROE
Banca di Roma SpA BAHQE 0.60 4.15%
Commerzbank AG COHSO 0.74 5.49%
Bayerische Hypo und Vereinsbank AG BAXWW 0.82 5.39%
Intesa Bci SpA BAEWF 1.12 7.81%
Natexis Banques Populaires NABQE 1.12 7.38%
Almanij NV Algemene Mij voor Nijver ALPK 1.17 8.78%
Credit Industriel et Commercial CIECM 1.20 9.46%
Credit Lyonnais SA CREV 1.20 6.86%
BNL Banca Nazionale del Lavoro SpA BAEXC 1.22 12.43%
Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena SpA MOGG 1.34 10.86%
Deutsche Bank AG DEMX 1.36 17.33%
Skandinaviska Enskilda Banken SKHS 1.39 16.33%
Nordea Bank AB NORDEA 1.40 13.69%
DNB Holding ASA DNHLD 1.42 16.78%
ForeningsSparbanken AB FOLG 1.61 18.69%
Danske Bank AS DANKAS 1.66 19.09%
Credit Suisse Group CRGAL 1.68 14.34%
KBC Bankverzekeringsholding KBCBA 1.69 30.85%
Societe Generale SODI 1.73 17.55%
Santander Central Hispano SA BAZAB 1.83 11.01%
National Bank of Greece SA NAGT 1.87 26.19%
San Paolo IMI SpA SAOEL 1.88 16.57%
BNP Paribas BNPRB 2.00 18.68%
Svenska Handelsbanken AB SVKE 2.12 21.82%
UBS AG UBQH 2.15 16.64%
Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria SA BBFUG 2.18 22.94%
ABN Amro Holding NV ABTS 2.21 24.21%
UniCredito Italiano SpA UNCZA 2.25 15.90%
Rolo Banca 1473 SpA ROGMBA 2.37 16.67%
Dexia DECCT 2.76 14.99%
Average 1.60 14.96%
Aswath Damodaran 122
PBV versus ROE regression

 Regressing PBV ratios against ROE for banks yields the following regression:
PBV = 0.81 + 5.32 (ROE) R2 = 46%
 For every 1% increase in ROE, the PBV ratio should increase by 0.0532.

Aswath Damodaran 123


Under and Over Valued Banks?

Bank Actual Predicted Under or Over


Banca di Roma SpA 0.60 1.03 -41.33%
Commerzbank AG 0.74 1.10 -32.86%
Bayerische Hypo und Vereinsbank AG 0.82 1.09 -24.92%
Intesa Bci SpA 1.12 1.22 -8.51%
Natexis Banques Populaires 1.12 1.20 -6.30%
Almanij NV Algemene Mij voor Nijver 1.17 1.27 -7.82%
Credit Industriel et Commercial 1.20 1.31 -8.30%
Credit Lyonnais SA 1.20 1.17 2.61%
BNL Banca Nazionale del Lavoro SpA 1.22 1.47 -16.71%
Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena SpA 1.34 1.39 -3.38%
Deutsche Bank AG 1.36 1.73 -21.40%
Skandinaviska Enskilda Banken 1.39 1.68 -17.32%
Nordea Bank AB 1.40 1.54 -9.02%
DNB Holding ASA 1.42 1.70 -16.72%
ForeningsSparbanken AB 1.61 1.80 -10.66%
Danske Bank AS 1.66 1.82 -9.01%
Credit Suisse Group 1.68 1.57 7.20%
KBC Bankverzekeringsholding 1.69 2.45 -30.89%
Societe Generale 1.73 1.74 -0.42%
Santander Central Hispano SA 1.83 1.39 31.37%
National Bank of Greece SA 1.87 2.20 -15.06%
San Paolo IMI SpA 1.88 1.69 11.15%
BNP Paribas 2.00 1.80 11.07%
Svenska Handelsbanken AB 2.12 1.97 7.70%
UBS AG 2.15 1.69 27.17%
Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria SA 2.18 2.03 7.66%
ABN Amro Holding NV 2.21 2.10 5.23%
UniCredito Italiano SpA 2.25 1.65 36.23%
Rolo Banca 1473 SpA 2.37 1.69 39.74%
Dexia 2.76 1.61 72.04%

Aswath Damodaran 124


Looking for undervalued securities - PBV Ratios and ROE

 Given the relationship between price-book value ratios and returns on equity,
it is not surprising to see firms which have high returns on equity selling for
well above book value and firms which have low returns on equity selling at
or below book value.
 The firms which should draw attention from investors are those which provide
mismatches of price-book value ratios and returns on equity - low P/BV ratios
and high ROE or high P/BV ratios and low ROE.

Aswath Damodaran 125


The Valuation Matrix

MV/BV

Overvalued
Low ROE High ROE
High MV/BV High MV/BV

ROE-r

Undervalued
Low ROE High ROE
Low MV/BV Low MV/BV

Aswath Damodaran 126


Price to Book vs ROE: Largest Market Cap Firms in the
United States: September 2003

20

SAP DE LL

G
BUD

PFE
BSX GS K
EBAY O RCL
10 MMM

MDT PG
DAZN
WMT JNJ MRK
Q COM BMY UL

AMAT K MB MO
FNM
PBV Ratio

ABN

SC
0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70

ROE

Aswath Damodaran 127


PBV Matrix: Telecom Companies

12
TelAzteca

10

TelNZ Vimple
8 Carlton

Teleglobe
FranceTel Cable&W
6
DeutscheTel
BritTel
TelItalia
Portugal AsiaSat
HongKong
BCE Royal
4 Hellenic
Nippon
DanmarkChinaTel
Espana Indast
Telmex
TelArgFrance
PhilTel Televisas
TelArgentina
2 TelIndo
TelPeru

APT
CallNet
Anonima GrupoCentro

0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60

ROE

Aswath Damodaran 128


PBV, ROE and Risk: Large Cap US firms

16
BUD G
14
PFE
12
O RCL
10 MMM EBAY

PBV R atio PG
8 MDT D
UL MRK
6 WMT T SM
QCOM
FNMK MB AMAT
4

2 FRE
AOL
SC V IA/B
70 60 4
50 40 3
30 20 2
10 0 1
0 Regressio n Beta
ROE

Aswath Damodaran 129


IBM: The Rise and Fall and Rise Again

10.00 50.00%

9.00
40.00%

8.00
30.00%

7.00
20.00%

6.00

10.00%

Return on Equity
Price to Book

5.00

0.00%

4.00

-10.00%
3.00

-20.00%
2.00

-30.00%
1.00

0.00 -40.00%
1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Year

PBV ROE

Aswath Damodaran 130


PBV Ratio Regression: US
January 2004
Mod el Su mmar y

Adjusted R Std. Er ror of the


a
Mode l R R Square Square Estimate
1 .943 b .889 .889 117.0574933200291
a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R
Square measures the proportion of the variability in the
dependent varia ble about the origin explained by regre ssion.
This CANNOT b e compared to R Squar e for models which
include an intercept.
b. Predictors: ROE, R egr ession B eta, PAYOU T, Expected Growth
in EPS: next 5 year s

Co effici entsa,b,c

Unstandardized Standar dized


Coefficients Coefficients
Mode l B Std. Error Beta t Sig.
1 Expected G rowth in
8.E-02 .00 4 .256 21.93 5 .000
EPS: next 5 years
PAYOUT 2.E-03 .00 1 .017 1.551 .121
Regr ession B eta .599 .04 2 .151 14.24 9 .000
ROE .140 .00 3 .628 50.73 1 .000
a. Dependent Va riable: PBV Ratio
b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin
c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weig hted by Marke t Cap

Aswath Damodaran 131


PBV Ratio Regression- Europe
January 2004
Mod el Summary

Adjusted R
a
Mode l R R Square Squar e Std. Error of the Estimate
1 .830 b .689 .689 154.4404 7748882220
a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R Squar e
mea sur es the prop or tion of the va riability in the depende nt variable
about the origin explained by regression. This CA NNOT be compare d
to R Square for models which include an inter cept.
b. Predictors: ROE, Payout Ra tio, B ETA

Coefficientsa ,b,c

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 Payout Ratio 8.E-03 .002 .074 3.667 .00 0
BE TA 1.399 .114 .291 12. 279 .00 0
ROE .10 4 .004 .537 28. 148 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: PB V
b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin
c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weighted by Marke t Capitalization

Aswath Damodaran 132


PBV Regression: Emerging Markets
January 2004

Mod el Summary

Adjusted R
a
Mode l R R Square Square Std. Er ror of the Estimate
1 .795 b .63 1 .631 2.0708694 612 34543
a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept m odel) , R Square
mea sur es the proportion of the va riability in the d ependent va riable
about the origin explained b y regression. This CANNOT be
compared to R Square f or models which include an inter cept.
b. Predictors: ROE, Payout Ratio, BETA

Coefficientsa ,b

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 Payout Ratio 5.E-03 .001 .076 4.148 .00 0
BE TA .80 5 .088 .213 9.164 .00 0
ROE 9.E-02 .003 .579 29. 414 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: PB V
b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin

Aswath Damodaran 133


PBV Ratio: Japan in January 2004
Model Su mmar y

R
Net Income
> 0 Adjusted R Std. Er ror of the
Mode l (Selected) R Sq uare a Squar e Estimate
1 b
.815 .664 .664 848.8652 371625490 00
a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R Square
mea sur es the prop or tion of the va riability in the depende nt va riable
about the origin explained b y regression. This CANNOT be compare d
to R Square for models which include an intercept.
b. Predictors: B ETA, ROE Co ef fici entsa,b,c,d

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 ROE .189 .007 .597 28.912 .00 0
BE TA .973 .073 .276 13.359 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: PBV
b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin
c. Weighted Least Square s R egression - Weighted by Mar ket
Capitalization
d. Selecting only cases for which Net Income > 0

Aswath Damodaran 134


Value/Book Value Ratio: Definition

 While the price to book ratio is a equity multiple, both the market value and
the book value can be stated in terms of the firm.
 Value/Book Value = Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt
Book Value of Equity + Book Value of Debt

Aswath Damodaran 135


Determinants of Value/Book Ratios

 To see the determinants of the value/book ratio, consider the simple free cash
flow to the firm model:
FCFF1
V0 =
WACC - g

 Dividing both sides by the book value, we get:


V0 FCFF1 /BV
=
BV WACC - g

 If we replace, FCFF = EBIT(1-t) - (g/ROC) EBIT(1-t),we get

V0 ROC - g
=
BV WACC - g
Aswath Damodaran 136
Value/Book Ratio: An Example

 Consider a stable growth firm with the following characteristics:


• Return on Capital = 12%
• Cost of Capital = 10%
• Expected Growth = 5%
 The value/BV ratio for this firm can be estimated as follows:
Value/BV = (.12 - .05)/(.10 - .05) = 1.40
 The effects of ROC on growth will increase if the firm has a high growth
phase, but the basic determinants will remain unchanged.

Aswath Damodaran 137


Value/Book and the Return Spread

Aswath Damodaran 138


Value/Book Capital Regression - US
Model Su mmar y

Adjusted R
Mode l R R Square Square Std. Er ror of the Estimate
1 a
.758 .575 .574 135.06239892 7610600
a. Predictors: ( Constant), Market Debt to Cap ital, Expected Growth
in Revenues: next 5 years, ROC

Co ef fici entsa,b

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 3.041 .133 22.838 .00 0
Expected G rowth in
Revenues: next 5 year s 1.E-02 .008 .026 1.3 30 .18 4

ROC 9.E-02 .004 .446 22.992 .00 0


Marke t Debt to Capital -.066 .003 -.473 -23.04 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: Value/BV of Capital
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran 139


Price Sales Ratio: Definition

 The price/sales ratio is the ratio of the market value of equity to the sales.
 Price/ Sales= Market Value of Equity
Total Revenues
 Consistency Tests
• The price/sales ratio is internally inconsistent, since the market value of equity is
divided by the total revenues of the firm.

Aswath Damodaran 140


Price/Sales Ratio: US stocks

Revenue Multiples: US Companies in January 2004

600

500

400

300
Price to Sales
EV/Sales

200

100

0
<0.1 0.1- 0.2- 0.3- 0.4- 0.5- 0.75-1 1-1.25 1.25- 1.5- 1.75-2 2-2.5 2.5-3 3-3.5 3.5-4 4-5 5-10 >10
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.75 1.5 1.75

Aswath Damodaran 141


Price to Sales: Europe, Japan and Emerging Markets

Aswath Damodaran 142


Price/Sales Ratio: Determinants

 The price/sales ratio of a stable growth firm can be estimated beginning with a
2-stage equity valuation model:
DPS1
P0 =
r ! gn

 Dividing both sides by the sales per share:

P0 Net Profit Margin* Payout Ratio *(1+ g n )


= PS =
Sales 0 r-g n

Aswath Damodaran 143


Price/Sales Ratio for High Growth Firm

 When the growth rate is assumed to be high for a future period, the dividend
discount model can be written as
n
follows:
" (1+ g) %'
EPS0 * Payout Ratio * (1 + g) * $ 1 !
# (1+ r) n & EPS0 * Payout Ratio n * (1+ g)n *(1+ g n )
P0 = +
r -g (r - g n )(1+ r) n

 Dividing both sides by the sales per share:


' "$ (1+ g) n % *
Net Margin * Payout Ratio * (1+ g)* 1 !
P0 ) # (1+ r)n & Net Marginn * Payout Ratio n * (1+ g) n *(1 + gn ) ,
= +
Sales 0 ) r -g (r - gn )(1 + r)n ,
) ,
( +
where Net Marginn = Net Margin in stable growth phase

Aswath Damodaran 144


Price Sales Ratios and Profit Margins

 The key determinant of price-sales ratios is the profit margin.


 A decline in profit margins has a two-fold effect.
• First, the reduction in profit margins reduces the price-sales ratio directly.
• Second, the lower profit margin can lead to lower growth and hence lower price-
sales ratios.
Expected growth rate = Retention ratio * Return on Equity
= Retention Ratio *(Net Profit / Sales) * ( Sales / BV of Equity)
= Retention Ratio * Profit Margin * Sales/BV of Equity

Aswath Damodaran 145


Price/Sales Ratio: An Example

High Growth Phase Stable Growth


Length of Period 5 years Forever after year 5
Net Margin 10% 6%
Sales/BV of Equity 2.5 2.5
Beta 1.25 1.00
Payout Ratio 20% 60%
Expected Growth (.1)(2.5)(.8)=20% (.06)(2.5)(.4)=.06
Riskless Rate =6%

' "$ (1.20)5 % *


0.10 * 0.2 * (1.20) * 1 !
) # (1.12875)5 & 0.06 * 0.60 * (1.20) 5 * (1.06) ,
PS = ) + , = 1.06
(.12875 - .20) (.115 -.06) (1.12875) 5
) ,
( +

Aswath Damodaran 146


Effect of Margin Changes

Price/Sales Ratios and Net Margins

1.8

1.6

1.4

1.2

1
PS Ratio

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0
2% 4% 6% 8% 10% 12% 14% 16%
Net Margin

Aswath Damodaran 147


PS/Margins: European Retailers - September 2003

Aswath Damodaran 148


Regression Results: PS Ratios and Margins

 Regressing PS ratios against net margins,


PS = -.39 + 0.6548 (Net Margin) R2 = 43.5%
 Thus, a 1% increase in the margin results in an increase of 0.6548 in the price
sales ratios.
 The regression also allows us to get predicted PS ratios for these firms

Aswath Damodaran 149


Current versus Predicted Margins

 One of the limitations of the analysis we did in these last few pages is the
focus on current margins. Stocks are priced based upon expected margins
rather than current margins.
 For most firms, current margins and predicted margins are highly correlated,
making the analysis still relevant.
 For firms where current margins have little or no correlation with expected
margins, regressions of price to sales ratios against current margins (or price
to book against current return on equity) will not provide much explanatory
power.
 In these cases, it makes more sense to run the regression using either
predicted margins or some proxy for predicted margins.

Aswath Damodaran 150


A Case Study: The Internet Stocks

30

PKSI

LCOS SPYG
20
INTM MMXI
SCNT

MQST FFIV ATHM


A
CNET DCLK
d
j INTW RAMP
P 10 CSGP CBIS NTPA
S NETO SONEPCLN
APNT CLKS
EDGRPSIX ATHY AMZN
SPLN BIDS ALOY ACOM EGRP
BIZZ IIXL
ITRA ANET
ONEM FATB ABTL INFO TMNT GEEK
RMII
-0 TURF PPOD BUYX ELTX
GSVI ROWE

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2


AdjMargin

Aswath Damodaran 151


PS Ratios and Margins are not highly correlated

 Regressing PS ratios against current margins yields the following


PS = 81.36 - 7.54(Net Margin) R2 = 0.04
(0.49)
 This is not surprising. These firms are priced based upon expected margins,
rather than current margins.

Aswath Damodaran 152


Solution 1: Use proxies for survival and growth: Amazon in
early 2000

 Hypothesizing that firms with higher revenue growth and higher cash
balances should have a greater chance of surviving and becoming profitable,
we ran the following regression: (The level of revenues was used to control
for size)
PS = 30.61 - 2.77 ln(Rev) + 6.42 (Rev Growth) + 5.11 (Cash/Rev)
(0.66) (2.63) (3.49)
R squared = 31.8%
Predicted PS = 30.61 - 2.77(7.1039) + 6.42(1.9946) + 5.11 (.3069) = 30.42
Actual PS = 25.63
Stock is undervalued, relative to other internet stocks.

Aswath Damodaran 153


Solution 2: Use forward multiples

 You can always estimate price (or value) as a multiple of revenues, earnings
or book value in a future year. These multiples are called forward multiples.
 For young and evolving firms, the values of fundamentals in future years may
provide a much better picture of the true value potential of the firm. There are
two ways in which you can use forward multiples:
• Look at value today as a multiple of revenues or earnings in the future (say 5 years
from now) for all firms in the comparable firm list. Use the average of this multiple
in conjunction with your firm’s earnings or revenues to estimate the value of your
firm today.
• Estimate value as a multiple of current revenues or earnings for more mature firms
in the group and apply this multiple to the forward earnings or revenues to the
forward earnings for your firm. This will yield the expected value for your firm in
the forward year and will have to be discounted back to the present to get current
value.

Aswath Damodaran 154


An Example of Forward Multiples: Global Crossing

 Global Crossing lost $1.9 billion in 2001 and is expected to continue to lose money for
the next 3 years. In a discounted cashflow valuation (see notes on DCF valuation) of
Global Crossing, we estimated an expected EBITDA for Global Crossing in five years
of $ 1,371 million.
 The average enterprise value/ EBITDA multiple for healthy telecomm firms is 7.2
currently.
 Applying this multiple to Global Crossing’s EBITDA in year 5, yields a value in year 5
of
• Enterprise Value in year 5 = 1371 * 7.2 = $9,871 million
• Enterprise Value today = $ 9,871 million/ 1.1385 = $5,172 million
(The cost of capital for Global Crossing is 13.80%)
• The probability that Global Crossing will not make it as a going concern is 77% and the
distress sale value is only a $ 1 billion (1/2 of book value of assets).
• Adjusted Enterprise value = 5172 * .23 + 1000 (.77) = 1,960 million

Aswath Damodaran 155


PS Regression: United States - January 2004
Mod el Summary

Adjusted R Std. Error of the


a
Mode l R R Square Square Estimate
1 .932 b .869 .868 114.3056698264723 0
a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R
Square measures the proport ion of the variability in the
dependent varia ble about the origin explained by regre ssion.
This CANNOT be compared to R Squar e for models which
include an intercept.
b. Predictors: Net Mar gin, Regression Beta, PAYOUT, Expe cted
Growth in EPS: Co
next 5 years
effici entsa,b,c

Unstandardized Standar dized


Coefficients Coefficients
Mode l B Std. Error Beta t Sig.
1 Expected G rowth in
4.E-02 .00 4 .136 10.19 5 .000
EPS: next 5 years
PAYOUT -.011 .00 1 -.110 -9.425 .000
Regr ession B eta .549 .04 3 .156 12.65 8 .000
Net Margin .234 .00 4 .799 59.92 6 .000
a. Dependent Va riable: PS_RATIO
b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin
c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weig hted by Marke t Cap

Aswath Damodaran 156


PS Regression: Europe in January 2004
Model Summary

Adjusted R Std. Er ror of the


a
Mode l R R Square Square Estimate
1 .757 b .57 4 .573 134.938678072015
a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept m odel) ,
R Sq uare measures the proportion of the variab ility in the
dependent varia ble about the origin explained by
regression. This CANNO T be compar ed to R Square for
models which include an intercept.
b. Predictors: Net Mar gin, Payout Ra tio, BETA
Coefficientsa ,b,c

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 Payout Ratio 5.E-03 .002 .065 2.777 .00 6
BE TA .93 7 .095 .261 9.909 .00 0
Net Margin .11 0 .004 .516 26. 153 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: PS
b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin
c. Weighted Least Squares R egre ssion - Weighted by Marke t Capitalization

Aswath Damodaran 157


PS Regression in Emerging Markets - January 2004
Model Summary

R
Net Income
> .00 Adjusted R Std. Er ror of the
Mode l (Selected) R Sq uare a Squar e Estimate
1 b
.834 .696 .695 2.308859441838714
a. For r egression through the origin (the no-intercept model) , R
Square measures the proport ion of the variability in the depen dent
variable abou t the origin explaine d by re gression. This CANNOT be
compared to R Squar e for models which include an intercept.
b. Predictors: Net Mar gin, Payout Ra tio, BETA
Coefficientsa ,b,c

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 Payout Ratio 7.E-03 .001 .083 4.962 .00 0
BE TA .14 2 .087 .030 1.631 .10 3
Net Margin .14 3 .003 .766 47. 061 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: PS
b. Linear Regr ession through the Origin
c. Selecting only cases for which Ne t Income > .00

Aswath Damodaran 158


PS Regression in Japan: January 2004
Model Summary

R
Net Income
> 0 Adjusted R
Mode l (Selected) R Sq uare Squar e Std. Er ror of the Estimate
1 a
.721 .519 .518 549.1390 58787986000
a. Predictors: ( Constant), Payout Ratio, Net Mar gin

Coefficientsa ,b,c

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 2.E-02 .081 .242 .80 8
Net Margin .24 3 .007 .737 34. 627 .00 0
Payout Ratio 8.E-03 .002 .079 3.719 .00 0
a. Dependent Va riable: PS
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighted by Mar ket Capitalization
c. Selecting only cases for which Ne t Income > 0

Aswath Damodaran 159


Value/Sales Ratio: Definition

 The value/sales ratio is the ratio of the market value of the firm to the sales.
 Value/ Sales= Market Value of Equity + Market Value of Debt-Cash
Total Revenues

Aswath Damodaran 160


Value/Sales Ratios: Analysis of Determinants

 If pre-tax operating margins are used, the appropriate value estimate is that of
the firm. In particular, if one makes the assumption that
• Free Cash Flow to the Firm = EBIT (1 - tax rate) (1 - Reinvestment Rate)
 Then the Value of the Firm can be written as a function of the after-tax
operating margin= (EBIT (1-t)/Sales
( n +
" (1 + g) %
*(1 - RIRgrowth)(1 + g) * $1 ! n' n -
Value * # (1 + WACC) & (1 - RIR stable)(1 + g) * (1 + g n ) -
= After - tax Oper. Margin * +
Sales 0 * WACC - g (WACC - g n )(1 + WACC) n -
* -
) ,

g = Growth rate in after-tax operating income for the first n years


gn = Growth rate in after-tax operating income after n years forever (Stable growth
rate)
RIRGrowth, Stable = Reinvestment rate in high growth and stable periods
WACC = Weighted average cost of capital

Aswath Damodaran 161


Value/Sales Ratio: An Example

 Consider, for example, the Value/Sales ratio of Coca Cola. The company had
the following characteristics:
After-tax Operating Margin =18.56% Sales/BV of Capital = 1.67
Return on Capital = 1.67* 18.56% = 31.02%
Reinvestment Rate= 65.00% in high growth; 20% in stable growth;
Expected Growth = 31.02% * 0.65 =20.16% (Stable Growth Rate=6%)
Length of High Growth Period = 10 years
Cost of Equity =12.33% E/(D+E) = 97.65%
After-tax Cost of Debt = 4.16% D/(D+E) 2.35%
Cost of Capital= 12.33% (.9765)+4.16% (.0235) =12.13%

( " (1.2016)1 0 % +
* (1- .65)(1.2016)* $1! 10' 1 0 -
Value of Firm 0 * # (1.1213) & (1- .20)(1.2016) * (1.06) -
= .1856* + = 6.10
Sales 0 * .1213- .2016 (.1213- .06)(1.1213)1 0 -
* -
) ,

Aswath Damodaran 162


Value Sales Ratios and Operating Margins

Aswath Damodaran 163


U.S. Specialty Retailers: V/S vs Operating Margin
2.0 LUX
CDWC
CHCS
ISEE
DABR BID

VVTV MBAY
TOO

BFCI

1.5 SCC
TWTR
CPWM
HOTT

TLB

PCCC WSM
SATH JWL PLCE
PSUN CLE
FOSL
V 1.0
/ ORLYZLC
S LTD
a BBY
NSIT AZO
CWTRMIKE IPAR ANN
l ZQK GLBE
RAYS PIR
e
LE LIN MDLK
MENS
s HLYW
SCHS MNRO
GBIZ DAP RUS
CAO
CC ITN BEBE
0.5 PGDA AEOS
ROST
URBN
MTMC PBY HMY
Z CHRS PSS BKE
ANIC VOXX
CLWY IBI
CELL JILL FNLY
GADZ DBRN WLSN
RUSH MDA
SAH
LVC SPGLA TWMC
FLWS ROSI FINL
PSRC ZANY
MHCO
GDYS RET.TO MLG
-0.0 MSEL

-0.000 0.075 0.150 0.225


Operating Margin
Aswath Damodaran 164
Brand Name Premiums in Valuation

 You have been hired to value Coca Cola for an analyst reports and you have
valued the firm at 6.10 times revenues, using the model described in the last
few pages. Another analyst is arguing that there should be a premium added
on to reflect the value of the brand name. Do you agree?
 Yes
 No
 Explain.

Aswath Damodaran 165


The value of a brand name

 One of the critiques of traditional valuation is that is fails to consider the


value of brand names and other intangibles.
 The approaches used by analysts to value brand names are often ad-hoc and
may significantly overstate or understate their value.
 One of the benefits of having a well-known and respected brand name is that
firms can charge higher prices for the same products, leading to higher profit
margins and hence to higher price-sales ratios and firm value. The larger the
price premium that a firm can charge, the greater is the value of the brand
name.
 In general, the value of a brand name can be written as:
Value of brand name ={(V/S)b-(V/S)g }* Sales
(V/S)b = Value of Firm/Sales ratio with the benefit of the brand name
(V/S)g = Value of Firm/Sales ratio of the firm with the generic product

Aswath Damodaran 166


Illustration: Valuing a brand name: Coca Cola

Coca Cola Generic Cola Company


AT Operating Margin 18.56% 7.50%
Sales/BV of Capital 1.67 1.67
ROC 31.02% 12.53%
Reinvestment Rate 65.00% (19.35%) 65.00% (47.90%)
Expected Growth 20.16% 8.15%
Length 10 years 10 yea
Cost of Equity 12.33% 12.33%
E/(D+E) 97.65% 97.65%
AT Cost of Debt 4.16% 4.16%
D/(D+E) 2.35% 2.35%
Cost of Capital 12.13% 12.13%
Value/Sales Ratio 6.10 0.69

Aswath Damodaran 167


Value of Coca Cola’s Brand Name

 Value of Coke’s Brand Name= ( 6.10 - 0.69) ($18,868 million)


= $102 billion
 Value of Coke as a company = 6.10 ($18,868 million) = $ 115 Billion
 Approximately 88.69% of the value of the company can be traced to brand
name value

Aswath Damodaran 168


Value/Sales Ratio Regression: US in January 2004
Model Summary

Adjusted R Std. Error of the


Mode l R R Square Square Estimate
1 .726 a .527 .526 150 .9882839615558
a. Predictors: ( Constant), Expected G rowth in Revenue s: next 5
year s, After-tax Oper ating Ma rgin, Mar ket Debt t o Capital

Co ef fici entsa,b

Unstandardized Standardized
Coefficie nts Coefficie nts
Mode l B Std. Er ror Be ta t Sig.
1 (Constant) 1.252 .118 10.576 .00 0
After-tax Oper ating
.135 .004 .605 32.945 .00 0
Margin
Marke t Debt to Capital -.043 .003 -.300 -14.99 .00 0
Expected G rowth in
8.E-02 .009 .175 8.7 56 .00 0
Revenues: next 5 year s
a. Dependent Va riable: EV /Sales
b. Weighted Least Square s Regression - We ighte d by Mar ket Cap

Aswath Damodaran 169


Choosing Between the Multiples

 As presented in this section, there are dozens of multiples that can be


potentially used to value an individual firm.
 In addition, relative valuation can be relative to a sector (or comparable firms)
or to the entire market (using the regressions, for instance)
 Since there can be only one final estimate of value, there are three choices at
this stage:
• Use a simple average of the valuations obtained using a number of different
multiples
• Use a weighted average of the valuations obtained using a nmber of different
multiples
• Choose one of the multiples and base your valuation on that multiple

Aswath Damodaran 170


Averaging Across Multiples

 This procedure involves valuing a firm using five or six or more multiples and
then taking an average of the valuations across these multiples.
 This is completely inappropriate since it averages good estimates with poor
ones equally.
 If some of the multiples are “sector based” and some are “market based”, this
will also average across two different ways of thinking about relative
valuation.

Aswath Damodaran 171


Weighted Averaging Across Multiples

 In this approach, the estimates obtained from using different multiples are
averaged, with weights on each based upon the precision of each estimate.
The more precise estimates are weighted more and the less precise ones
weighted less.
 The precision of each estimate can be estimated fairly simply for those
estimated based upon regressions as follows:
Precision of Estimate = 1 / Standard Error of Estimate
where the standard error of the predicted value is used in the denominator.
 This approach is more difficult to use when some of the estimates are
subjective and some are based upon more quantitative techniques.

Aswath Damodaran 172


Picking one Multiple

 This is usually the best way to approach this issue. While a range of values
can be obtained from a number of multiples, the “best estimate” value is
obtained using one multiple.
 The multiple that is used can be chosen in one of two ways:
• Use the multiple that best fits your objective. Thus, if you want the company to be
undervalued, you pick the multiple that yields the highest value.
• Use the multiple that has the highest R-squared in the sector when regressed
against fundamentals. Thus, if you have tried PE, PBV, PS, etc. and run
regressions of these multiples against fundamentals, use the multiple that works
best at explaining differences across firms in that sector.
• Use the multiple that seems to make the most sense for that sector, given how
value is measured and created.

Aswath Damodaran 173


Self Serving Multiple Choice

 When a firm is valued using several multiples, some will yield really high
values and some really low ones.
 If there is a significant bias in the valuation towards high or low values, it is
tempting to pick the multiple that best reflects this bias. Once the multiple that
works best is picked, the other multiples can be abandoned and never brought
up.
 This approach, while yielding very biased and often absurd valuations, may
serve other purposes very well.
 As a user of valuations, it is always important to look at the biases of the
entity doing the valuation, and asking some questions:
• Why was this multiple chosen?
• What would the value be if a different multiple were used? (You pick the specific
multiple that you want to see tried.)

Aswath Damodaran 174


The Statistical Approach

 One of the advantages of running regressions of multiples against


fundamentals across firms in a sector is that you get R-squared values on the
regression (that provide information on how well fundamentals explain
differences across multiples in that sector).
 As a rule, it is dangerous to use multiples where valuation fundamentals (cash
flows, risk and growth) do not explain a significant portion of the differences
across firms in the sector.
 As a caveat, however, it is not necessarily true that the multiple that has the
highest R-squared provides the best estimate of value for firms in a sector.

Aswath Damodaran 175


A More Intuitive Approach

 Managers in every sector tend to focus on specific variables when analyzing


strategy and performance. The multiple used will generally reflect this focus.
Consider three examples.
• In retailing: The focus is usually on same store sales (turnover) and profit margins.
Not surprisingly, the revenue multiple is most common in this sector.
• In financial services: The emphasis is usually on return on equity. Book Equity is
often viewed as a scarce resource, since capital ratios are based upon it. Price to
book ratios dominate.
• In technology: Growth is usually the dominant theme. PEG ratios were invented in
this sector.

Aswath Damodaran 176


Conventional Usage: A Summary

 As a general rule of thumb, the following table provides a way of picking a


multiple for a sector
Sector Multiple Used Rationale
Cyclical Manufacturing PE, Relative PE Often with normalized earnings
High Tech, High Growth PEG Big differences in growth across
firms
High Growth/No Earnings PS, VS Assume future margins will be good
Heavy Infrastructure VEBITDA Firms in sector have losses in early
years and reported earnings can vary
depending on depreciation method
REITa P/CF Generally no cap ex investments
from equity earnings
Financial Services PBV Book value often marked to market
Retailing PS If leverage is similar across firms
VS If leverage is different

Aswath Damodaran 177


Sector or Market Multiples

 The conventional approach to using multiples is to look at the sector or


comparable firms.
 Whether sector or market based multiples make the most sense depends upon
how you think the market makes mistakes in valuation
• If you think that markets make mistakes on individual firm valuations but that
valuations tend to be right, on average, at the sector level, you will use sector-
based valuation only,
• If you think that markets make mistakes on entire sectors, but is generally right on
the overall market level, you will use only market-based valuation
 It is usually a good idea to approach the valuation at two levels:
• At the sector level, use multiples to see if the firm is under or over valued at the
sector level
• At the market level, check to see if the under or over valuation persists once you
correct for sector under or over valuation.

Aswath Damodaran 178


A Test

 You have valued Earthlink Networks, an internet service provider, relative to


other internet companies using Price/Sales ratios and find it to be under
valued almost 50% .When you value it relative to the market, using the
market regression, you find it to be overvalued by almost 50%. How would
you reconcile the two findings?
 One of the two valuations must be wrong. A stock cannot be under and over
valued at the same time.
 It is possible that both valuations are right.
What has to be true about valuations in the sector for the second statement to be
true?

Aswath Damodaran 179


Reviewing: The Four Steps to Understanding Multiples

 Define the multiple


• Check for consistency
• Make sure that they are estimated uniformly
 Describe the multiple
• Multiples have skewed distributions: The averages are seldom good indicators of
typical multiples
• Check for bias, if the multiple cannot be estimated
 Analyze the multiple
• Identify the companion variable that drives the multiple
• Examine the nature of the relationship
 Apply the multiple

Aswath Damodaran 180


Private Company Valuation

Aswath Damodaran

Aswath Damodaran 181


Process of Valuing Private Companies

 Choosing the right model


• Valuing the Firm versus Valuing Equity
• Steady State, Two-Stage or Three-Stage
 Estimating a Discount Rate
• Cost of Equity
– Estimating Betas
• Cost of Debt
– Estimating Default Risk
– Estimating an after-tax cost of debt
• Cost of Capital
– Estimating a Debt Ratio
 Estimating Cash Flows
 Completing the Valuation: Depends upon why and for whom the valuation is
being done.

Aswath Damodaran 182


Private Company Valuation: Motive matters

 You can value a private company for


• Legal purposes: Estate tax and divorce court
• Sale or prospective sale to another individual or private entity.
• Sale of one partner’s interest to another
• Sale to a publicly traded firm
• As prelude to setting offering price in an initial public offering
 You can value a division or divisions of a publicly traded firm
• As prelude to a spin off
• For sale to another entity
• To do a sum-of-the-parts valuation to determine whether a firm will be worth more
broken up or if it is being efficiently run.

Aswath Damodaran 183


Estimating Cost of Equity for a Private Firm

 Most models of risk and return (including the CAPM and the APM) use past
prices of an asset to estimate its risk parameters (beta(s)).
 Private firms and divisions of firms are not traded, and thus do not have past
prices.
 Thus, risk estimation has to be based upon an approach that does not require
past prices

Aswath Damodaran 184


I. Comparable Firm Betas

 Collect a group of publicly traded comparable firms, preferably in the same


line of business, but more generally, affected by the same economic forces
that affect the firm being valued.
• A Simple Test: To see if the group of comparable firms is truly comparable,
estimate a correlation between the revenues or operating income of the comparable
firms and the firm being valued. If it is high (and positive), of course, your have
comparable firms.
 If the private firm operates in more than one business line collect comparable
firms for each business line

Aswath Damodaran 185


Estimating comparable firm betas

 Estimate the average beta for the publicly traded comparable firms.
 Estimate the average market value debt-equity ratio of these comparable
firms, and calculate the unlevered beta for the business.
βunlevered = βlevered / (1 + (1 - tax rate) (Debt/Equity))
 Estimate a debt-equity ratio for the private firm, using one of two assumptions:
• Assume that the private firm will move to the industry average debt ratio. The beta
for the private firm will converge on the industry average beta.
β private firm = βunlevered (1 + (1 - tax rate) (Industry Average Debt/Equity))
• Estimate the optimal debt ratio for the private firm, based upon its operating
income and cost of capital.
β private firm = βunlevered (1 + (1 - tax rate) (Optimal Debt/Equity))
 Estimate a cost of equity based upon this beta.

Aswath Damodaran 186


Accounting Betas

 Step 1: Collect accounting earnings for the private company for as long as
there is a history.
 Step 2: Collect accounting earnings for the S&P 500 for the same time period.
 Step 3: Regress changes in earnings for the private company against changes
in the S&P 500.
 Step 4: The slope of the regression is the accounting beta
 There are two serious limitations -
(a) The number of observations in the regression is small
(b) Accountants smooth earnings.

Aswath Damodaran 187


Estimating a Beta for the NY Yankees

 You have three choices for comparable firms:


• Firms that derive a significant portion of their revenues from baseball (Traded
baseball teams, baseball cards & memorabilia…)
• Firms that derive a significant portion of their revenues from sports
• Firms that derive a significant portion of their revenues from entertainment.
Comparable firms Levered Beta Unlevered Beta
Baseball firms (2) 0.70 0.64
Sports firms (22) 0.98 0.90
Entertainment firms (91) 0.87 0.79 Management target
 Levered Beta for Yankees = 0.90 ( 1 + (1-.4) (.25)) = 1.04
 Cost of Equity = 6.00% + 1.04 (4%) = 10.16%

Aswath Damodaran 188


Estimating a beta for InfoSoft: A private software firm

 Comparable firms include all software firms, with market capitalization of


less than $ 500 million.
 The average beta for these firms is 1.29 and the average debt to equity ratio
for these firms is 7.09%. With a 35% tax rate, this yields an unlevered beta of
Unlevered Beta = 1.29/ (1 + (1-.35) (.0709)) = 1.24
 We will assume that InfoSoft will have a debt to equity ratio comparable to
the average for the comparable firms and a similar tax rate, which results in a
levered beta of 1.29.
 Cost of Equity = 6.00% + 1.29 (4%) = 11.16%

Aswath Damodaran 189


Is beta a good measure of risk for a private firm?

 The beta of a firm measures only market risk, and is based upon the
assumption that the investor in the business is well diversified. Given that
private firm owners often have all or the bulk of their wealth invested in the
private business, would you expect their perceived costs of equity to be higher
or lower than the costs of equity from using betas?
 Higher
 Lower

Aswath Damodaran 190


Total Risk versus Market Risk

 Adjust the beta to reflect total risk rather than market risk. This adjustment is
a relatively simple one, since the correlation with the market measures the
proportion of the risk that is market risk.
Total Beta = Market Beta / Correlation with market
 In the New York Yankees example, where the market beta is 0.85 and the R-
squared for comparable firms is 25% (correlation is therefore 0.5),
• Total Unlevered Beta = 0.90/0. 5= 1.80
• Total Levered Beta = 1.80 (1 + (1-0.4)(0.25)) =2.07
• Total Cost of Equity = 6% + 2.07 (4%)= 14.28%

Aswath Damodaran 191


When would you use this total risk measure?

 Under which of the following scenarios are you most likely to use the total
risk measure:
 when valuing a private firm for an initial public offering
 when valuing a private firm for sale to a publicly traded firm
 when valuing a private firm for sale to another private investor
 Assume that you own a private business. What does this tell you about the
best potential buyer for your business?

Aswath Damodaran 192


Estimating the Cost of Debt for a Private Firm

 Basic Problem: Private firms generally do not access public debt markets, and
are therefore not rated.
 Most debt on the books is bank debt, and the interest expense on this debt
might not reflect the rate at which they can borrow (especially if the bank debt
is old.)

Aswath Damodaran 193


Estimation Options for Cost of Debt

 Solution 1: Assume that the private firm can borrow at the same rate as
similar firms (in terms of size) in the industry.
Cost of Debt for Private firm = Cost of Debt for similar firms in the industry
 Solution 2: Estimate an appropriate bond rating for the company, based upon
financial ratios, and use the interest rate estimated bond rating.
Cost of Debt for Private firm = Interest Rate based upon estimated bond rating (If
using optimal debt ratio, use corresponding rating)
 Solution 3: If the debt on the books of the company is long term and recent,
the cost of debt can be calculated using the interest expense and the debt
outstanding.
Cost of Debt for Private firm = Interest Expense / Outstanding Debt
If the firm borrowed the money towards the end of the financial year, the interest
expenses for the year will not reflect the interest rate on the debt.

Aswath Damodaran 194


Estimating a Cost of Debt for Yankees and InfoSoft

 For the Yankee’s, we will use the interest rate from the most recent loans that
the firm has taken on:
• Interest rate on debt = 7.00%
• After-tax cost of debt = 7% (1-.4) = 4.2%
 For InfoSoft, we will use the interest coverage ratio estimated using the
operating income and interest expenses from the most recent year:
• Interest coverage ratio = EBIT/ Interest expenses = 2000/315 = 6.35
• Rating based upon interest coverage ratio = A+
• Interest rate on debt = 6% + 0.80% = 6.80%
• After-tax cost of debt = 6.80% (1-.35) = 4.42%

Aswath Damodaran 195


Estimating the Cost of Capital

 Basic problem: The debt ratios for private firms are stated in book value
terms, rather than market value. Furthermore, the debt ratio for a private firm
that plans to go public might change as a consequence of that action.
 Solution 1: Assume that the private firm will move towards the industry
average debt ratio.
Debt Ratio for Private firm = Industry Average Debt Ratio
 Solution 2: Assume that the private firm will move towards its optimal debt
ratio.
Debt Ratio for Private firm = Optimal Debt Ratio
 Consistency in assumptions: The debt ratio assumptions used to calculate
the beta, the debt rating and the cost of capital weights should be
consistent.

Aswath Damodaran 196


Estimating Costs of Capital

New York InfoSoft


Yankees Corporation
Cost of Equity 14.28%(total beta) 11.16%(market beta)
E/ (D+E) 80.00% 93.38%
Cost of Debt 7.00% 6.80%
AT Cost of Debt 4.20% 4.42%
D/(D+E) 20.00% 6.62%
Cost of Capital 12.26% 10.71%

Aswath Damodaran 197


Estimating Cash Flows for a Private Firm

 Shorter history: Private firms often have been around for much shorter time
periods than most publicly traded firms. There is therefore less historical
information available on them.
 Different Accounting Standards: The accounting statements for private
firms are often based upon different accounting standards than public firms,
which operate under much tighter constraints on what to report and when to
report.
 Intermingling of personal and business expenses: In the case of private
firms, some personal expenses may be reported as business expenses.
 Separating “Salaries” from “Dividends”: It is difficult to tell where salaries
end and dividends begin in a private firm, since they both end up with the
owner.

Aswath Damodaran 198


Estimating Private Firm Cash Flows

 Restate earnings, if necessary, using consistent accounting standards.


• To get a measure of what is reasonable, look at profit margins of comparable
publicly traded firms in the same business
 If any of the expenses are personal, estimate the income without these
expenses.
 Estimate a “reasonable” salary based upon the services the owner provides the
firm.

Aswath Damodaran 199


The Yankee’s Revenues

Pittsburg Pirates Baltimore Orioles New York Yankees


Net Home Game Receipts $ 22,674,597 $ 47,353,792 $ 52,000,000
Road Receipts $ 1,613,172 $ 7,746,030 $ 9,000,000
Concessions & Parking $ 3,755,965 $ 22,725,449 $ 25,500,000
National TV Revenues $ 15,000,000 $ 15,000,000 $ 15,000,000
Local TV Revenues $ 11,000,000 $ 18,183,000 $ 90,000,000
National Licensing $ 4,162,747 $ 3,050,949 $ 6,000,000
Stadium Advertising $ 100,000 $ 4,391,383 $ 5,500,000
Other Revenues $ 1,000,000 $ 9,200,000 $ 6,000,000
Total Revenues $ 59,306,481 $ 127,650,602 $ 209,000,000

Aswath Damodaran 200


The Yankee’s Expenses

Pittsburg Pirates Baltimore Orioles New York Yankees


Player Salaries $ 33,155,366 $ 62,771,482 $ 91,000,000
Team Operating Expenses $ 6,239,025 $ 6,803,907 $ 7,853,000
Player Development $ 8,136,551 $ 12,768,399 $ 15,000,000
Stadium & Game Operations$ 5,270,986 $ 4,869,790 $ 7,800,000
Other Player Costs $ 2,551,000 $ 6,895,751 $ 7,500,000
G & A Costs $ 6,167,617 $ 9,321,151 $ 11,000,000
Broadcasting $ 1,250,000 $ - $ -
Rent & Amortization $ - $ 6,252,151 $ -
Total Operating Expenses $ 62,770,545 $ 109,682,631 $ 140,153,000

Aswath Damodaran 201


Adjustments to Operating Income

Pittsburg Pirates Baltimore Orioles New York Yankees


Total Revenues $59,306,481 $127,650,602 $209,000,000
Total Operating Expenses $62,770,545 $109,682,631 $140,153,000
EBIT -$3,464,064 $17,967,971 $68,847,000
Adjustments $1,500,000 $2,200,000 $4,500,000
Adjusted EBIT -$1,964,064 $20,167,971 $73,347,000
Taxes (at 40%) -$785,626 $8,067,189 $29,338,800
EBIT (1-tax rate) -$1,178,439 $12,100,783 $44,008,200

Aswath Damodaran 202


InfoSoft’s Operating Income

Stated Operating Income


Sales & Other Operating Revenues $20,000.00
- Operating Costs & Expenses $13,000.00
- Depreciation $1,000.00
- Research and Development Expenses $4,000.00
Operating Income $2,000.00
Adjusted Operating Income
Operating Income $ 2000.00
+ R& D Expenses $ 4000.00
- Amortization of Research Asset $ 2311.00
Adjusted Operating Income $ 3689.00

Aswath Damodaran 203


Estimating Cash Flows for Yankees

 We will assume a 3% growth rate in perpetuity for operating income. To


generate this growth, we will assume that the Yankee’s will earn 20% on their
new investments. This yields a reinvestment rate of
 Reinvestment rate = g/ ROC = 3%/20% = 15%
 Estimated Free Cash Flow to Firm
EBIT (1- tax rate) = $ 44,008,200
- Reinvestment = $ 6,601,230
FCFF $ 37,406,970

Aswath Damodaran 204


From Cash Flows to Value

 Once you have estimated the cash flows and the cost of capital, you can value
a private firm using conventional methods.
 If you are valuing a firm for sale to a private business,
• Use the total beta and the cost of equity emerging from that to estimate the cost of
capital.
• Discount the cash flows using this cost of capital
 If you are valuing a firm for an initial public offering, stay with the market
beta and cost of capital.

Aswath Damodaran 205


Valuing the Yankees

FCFF = $ 37,406,970
Cost of capital = 12.26%
Expected Growth rate= 3.00%

Value of Yankees = $ 37,406,970 (1.03)/(.1226-.03)


= $ 415,902,192

Aswath Damodaran 206


What if?

 We are assuming that the Yankees have to reinvest to generate growth. If they
can get the city to pick up the tab, the value of the Yankees can be estimated
as follows:
• FCFF = EBIT (1-t) - Reinvestment = $44.008 mil - 0 = $ 44.008 million
• Value of Yankees = 44.008*1.03/(.1226 - .03) = $ 489 million
 If on top of this, we assume that the buyer is a publicly traded firm and we use
the market beta instead of the total beta
• FCFF = $ 44.008 million
• Cost of capital = 8.95%
• Value of Yankees = 44.008 (1.03) / (.0895 - .03) = $ 761.6 million

Aswath Damodaran 207


InfoSoft: A Valuation
Current Cashflow to Firm Reinvestment Rate Return on Capital
EBIT(1-t) : 2,933 106.82% 23.67%
Expected Growth in
- Nt CpX 2,633 EBIT (1-t)
- Chg WC 500 Stable Growth
1.1217*.2367 = .2528
= FCFF <200> g = 5%; Beta = 1.20;
25.28%
Reinvestment Rate = 106.82% D/(D+E) =
6.62%;ROC=17.2%
Reinvestment Rate=29.07%

Terminal Value10 = 6743/(.1038-.05) = 125,391

Firm Value: 73,909 EBIT(1- 3675 4604 5768 7227 9054 9507
+ Cash: 500 t) 3926 4918 6161 7720 9671 2764
- Debt: 4,583 - Reinv -251 -314 -393 -493 -617 6743
=Equity 69,826 FCFF

Discount at Cost of Capital (WACC) = 11.16% (0.9338) + 4.42% (0.0662) = 10.71%

Cost of Equity Cost of Debt


11.16% (6+0.80%)(1-.35) Weights
= 4.42% E = 93.38% D = 6.62%

Riskfree Rate:
Government Bond Risk Premium
Rate = 6% Beta 4%
+ 1.29 X

Unlevered Beta for Firm’s D/E Historical US Country Risk


Sectors: 1.24 Ratio: 7.09% Premium Premium
4% 0%

Aswath Damodaran 208


Play investment banker: Price this IPO

 The value of equity that we have arrived at for Infosoft is $69.5 million. If
you plan to have 10 million shares outstanding, estimate the value per share?

 Would this also be your offering price? If not, why not?

 Would you answer be different, if the initial offering were for only 1 million
shares - the owners will retain the remaining 9 million for subsequent
offerings?

Aswath Damodaran 209


Valuation Motives and the Next Step in Private Company
Valuation: Control and Illiquidity

 If valuing a private business for sale (in whole or part) to another individual
(to stay private), it is necessary that we estimate
• a illiquidity discount associated with the fact that private businesses cannot be
easily bought and sold
• a control premium (if more than 50% of the business is being sold)
 If valuing a business for taking public, it is necessary to estimate
• the effects of creating different classes of shares in the initial public offer
• the effects of options or warrants on the issuance price per share
 If valuing a business for sale (in whole or part) to a publicly traded firm, there
should be no illiquidity discount, because stock in the parent firm will trade
but there may, however, be a premium associated with the publicly traded
firm being able to take better advantage of the private firm’s strengths

Aswath Damodaran 210


Conventional Practice on Illiquidity

 In private company valuation, illiquidity is a constant theme that analysts talk


about.
 All the talk, though, seems to lead to a rule of thumb. The illiquidity discount
for a private firm is between 20-30% and does not vary across private firms.

Aswath Damodaran 211


Determinants of the Illiquidity Discount

 Type of Assets owned by the Firm: The more liquid the assets owned by the
firm, the lower should be the illiquidity discount for the firm
 Size of the Firm: The larger the firm, the smaller should be the percentage
illiquidity discount.
 Health of the Firm: Healthier firms should sell for a smaller discount than
troubled firms.
 Cash Flow Generating Capacity: Firms which are generating large amounts
of cash from operations should sell for a smaller discounts than firms which
do not generate large cash flows.
 Size of the Block: The liquidity discount should increase with the size of the
portion of the firm being sold.

Aswath Damodaran 212


Illiquidity Discounts and Type of Business

 Rank the following assets (or private businesses) in terms of the liquidity
discount you would apply to your valuation (from biggest discount to
smallest)
 A New York City Cab Medallion
 A small privately owned five-and-dime store in your town
 A large privately owned conglomerate, with significant cash balances and real
estate holdings.
 A large privately owned ski resort that is losing money

Aswath Damodaran 213


Empirical Evidence on Illiquidity Discounts: Restricted
Stock

 Restricted securities are securities issued by a company, but not registered


with the SEC, that can be sold through private placements to investors, but
cannot be resold in the open market for a two-year holding period, and limited
amounts can be sold after that. Restricted securities trade at significant
discounts on publicly traded shares in the same company.
• Maher examined restricted stock purchases made by four mutual funds in the
period 1969-73 and concluded that they traded an average discount of 35.43% on
publicly traded stock in the same companies.
• Moroney reported a mean discount of 35% for acquisitions of 146 restricted stock
issues by 10 investment companies, using data from 1970.
• In a recent study of this phenomenon, Silber finds that the median discount for
restricted stock is 33.75%.

Aswath Damodaran 214


Cross Sectional Differences : Restricted Stock

 Silber (1991) develops the following relationship between the size of the
discount and the characteristics of the firm issuing the registered stock –
LN(RPRS) = 4.33 +0.036 LN(REV) - 0.142 LN(RBRT) + 0.174 DERN + 0.332
DCUST
where,
RPRS = Relative price of restricted stock (to publicly traded stock)
REV = Revenues of the private firm (in millions of dollars)
RBRT = Restricted Block relative to Total Common Stock in %
DERN = 1 if earnings are positive; 0 if earnings are negative;
DCUST = 1 if there is a customer relationship with the investor; 0 otherwise;
 Interestingly, Silber finds no effect of introducing a control dummy - set equal
to one if there is board representation for the investor and zero otherwise.

Aswath Damodaran 215


Adjusting the average illiquidity discount for firm
characteristics - Silber Regression

 The Silber regression does provide us with a sense of how different the
discount will be for a firm with small revenues versus one with large revenues.
 Consider, for example, two profitable firms that are equal in every respect
except for revenues. Assume that the first firm has revenues of 10 million and
the second firm has revenues of 100 million. The Silber regression predicts
illiquidity discounts of the following:
• For firm with 100 million in revenues: 44.5%
• For firm with 10 million in revenues: 48.9%
• Difference in illiquidity discounts: 4.4%
 If your base discount for a firm with 10 million in revenues is 25%, the
illiquidity discount for a firm with 100 million in revenues would be 20.6%.

Aswath Damodaran 216


Liquidity Discount and Revenues

Figure 24.1: Illiquidity Discounts: Base Discount of 25% for profitable firm with $ 10 million in revenues

40.00%

35.00%

30.00%
Discount as % of Value

25.00%

20.00%

15.00%

10.00%

5.00%

0.00%
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 100 200 300 400 500 1000
Revenues

Profitable firm Unprofitable firm

Aswath Damodaran 217


Application to the Yankees

 To estimate the illiquidity discount for the Yankees, we assume that the base discount for a firm
with $10 million in revenues would be 25%. The Yankee’s revenues of $209 million should result in
a lower discount on their value. We estimate the difference in the illiquidity discount between a firm
with $10 million in revenue and $209 million in revenue to be 5.90%. To do this, we first estimated
the illiquidity discount in the Silber equation for a firm with $10 million in revenues.
Expected illiquidity discount = 48.94%
 We then re-estimated the illiquidity discount with revenues of $ 209 million:
Expected illiquidity discount = 43.04%
 Difference in discount = 48.94% - 43.04% = 5.90%
 The estimated illiquidity discount for the Yankees would therefore be 19.10%, which is the base
discount of 25% adjusted for the illiquidty difference.

Aswath Damodaran 218


An Alternate Approach to the Illiquidity Discount: Bid Ask
Spread

 The bid ask spread is the difference between the price at which you can buy a
security and the price at which you can sell it, at the same point.
 In other words, it is the illiqudity discount on a publicly traded stock.
 Studies have tied the bid-ask spread to
• the size of the firm
• the trading volume on the stock
• the degree
 Regressing the bid-ask spread against variables that can be measured for a
private firm (such as revenues, cash flow generating capacity, type of assets,
variance in operating income) and are also available for publicly traded firms
offers promise.

Aswath Damodaran 219


A Bid-Ask Spread Regression

 Using data from the end of 2000, for instance, we regressed the bid-ask spread against
annual revenues, a dummy variable for positive earnings (DERN: 0 if negative and 1 if
positive), cash as a percent of firm value and trading volume.
Spread = 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (Annual Revenues) -0.015 (DERN) – 0.016 (Cash/Firm Value)
– 0.11 ($ Monthly trading volume/ Firm Value)
 You could plug in the values for a private firm into this regression (with zero trading
volume) and estimate the spread for the firm.
 We could substitute in the revenues of the Yankees ($209 million), the fact that it has
positive earnings and the cash as a percent of revenues held by the firm (3%):
Spread = 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (Annual Revenues) -0.015 (DERN) – 0.016 (Cash/Firm Value)
– 0.11 ($ Monthly trading volume/ Firm Value)
= 0.145 – 0.0022 ln (209) -0.015 (1) – 0.016 (.03) – 0.11 (0) = .1178 or 11.78%
 Based on this approach, we would estimate an illiquidity discount of 11.78% for the
Yankees.

Aswath Damodaran 220


What is control worth?

The Value of Control


Probability that you can change the
management of the firm X Change in firm value from changing
management

Value of the Value of the


Takeover
Restrictions
Voting Rules &
Rights
Access to
Funds
Size of
company
firm run
optimally - firm run status
quo

Aswath Damodaran 221


Where control matters…

 In publicly traded firms, control is a factor


• In the pricing of every publicly traded firm, since a portion of every stock can be
attributed to the market’s views about control.
• In acquisitions, it will determine how much you pay as a premium for a firm to
control the way it is run.
• When shares have voting and non-voting shares, the value of control will
determine the price difference.
 In private firms, control usually becomes an issue when you consider how
much to pay for a private firm.
• You may pay a premium for a badly managed private firm because you think you
could run it better.
• The value of control is directly related to the discount you would attach to a
minority holding (<50%) as opposed to a majority holding.
• The value of control also becomes a factor in how much of an ownership stake you
will demand in exchange for a private equity investment.

Aswath Damodaran 222


Status Quo and Optimal Value

 Eisner Enterprises is a poorly-managed firm that is expected to generate $ 10


million in after-tax cashflows in perpetuity (if run by existing management)
and is all-equity funded with a cost of equity of 10%. Estimate the status quo
value:

 If you believe that you can improve the after-tax cashflows to $ 12 million a
year in perpetuity and that you could lower the cost of capital to 8% by
moving to a higher debt ratio. Estimate the optimal value for Eisner
Enterprises.

Aswath Damodaran 223


Scenario 1: Valuing shares in a publicly traded firm

 Assume that, based upon your assessment of takeover defenses in the firm,
you estimate that there is a 40% probability that management in Eisner
Enterprises will change. If there are 10 million shares outstanding in the firm,
estimate the value per share?

 What do you think will happen to the value per share if another firm in the
same industry is the target of a hostile acquisition?

Aswath Damodaran 224


Scenario 2: Publicly traded firm with voting and non-voting
shares

 Assume that Eisner Enterprises has 5 million voting shares and 5 million non-
voting shares. If the probability of control changing remains 40% and non-
voting shares are completely unprotected, estimate the value per voting and
non-voting share:
• Value per non-voting share =
• Value per voting share =
 If the incumbent managers own 35% of the voting shares, will your
assessment of the value per voting share change? If so, why? If not, why not?

Aswath Damodaran 225


Value of stock in a publicly traded firm

 When a firm is badly managed, the market still assesses the probability that it
will be run better in the future and attaches a value of control to the stock
price today:
Status Quo Value + Probability of control change (Optimal - Status Quo Value)
Value per share =
Number of shares outstanding
 With voting shares and non-voting shares, a disproportionate share of the
value of control will go to the voting shares. In the extreme scenario where
non-voting shares are completely unprotected:
!
Status Quo Value
Value per non - voting share =
# Voting Shares + # Non - voting shares

Probability of control change (Optimal - Status Quo Value)


Value per voting share = Value of non - voting share +
! # Voting Shares

Aswath Damodaran 226


!
Empirical Studies on Voting versus Non-Voting Shares

 Studies that compare the prices of traded voting shares against the prices of
traded non-voting shares, to examine the value of the voting rightsconclude
that while the voting shares generally trade at a premium over the non-
voting shares, the premium is small.
• Lease, McConnell and Mikkelson (1983) find an average premium of only 5.44%
for the voting shares. (There are similar findings in DeAngelo and DeAngelo
(1985) and Megginson (1990))
• These studies have been critiqued for underestimating the value of control, because
the probability of gaining control by acquiring these voting shares is considered
low for two reasons - first, a substantial block of the voting shares is often still held
by one or two individuals in many of these cases, and second, the prices used in
these studies are based upon small block trades, which are unlikely to give the
buyer majority control.

Aswath Damodaran 227


Scenario 3: Control Value in a Private firm

 Assume now that Eisner Enterprises is a private firm. If you were bidding for
100% of Eisner Enterprises, what is the maximum you would be willing to
bid?

 What about 51% of Eisner Enterprises?

 What about 49% of Eisner Enterprises?

Aswath Damodaran 228


Minority and Majority interests

 When you get a controlling interest in a private firm (generally >51%, but
could be less…), you would be willing to pay the appropriate proportion of
the optimal value of the firm.
 When you buy a minority interest in a firm, you will be willing to pay the
appropriate fraction of the status quo value of the firm.
 For badly managed firms, there can be a significant difference in value
between 51% of a firm and 49% of the same firm. This is the minority
discount.
 If you own a private firm and you are trying to get a private equity or venture
capital investor to invest in your firm, it may be in your best interests to offer
them a share of control in the firm even though they may have well below
51%.

Aswath Damodaran 229

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi