Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 10

DOI: 10.

1007/s00267-004-0044-7
PROFILE
Household Demand for Waste Recycling Services
RUSLANA PALATNIK purchase of a subsidized waste disposal facility, and the
OFIRA AYALON* above (proxy) value of externalities reflects the difference
MORDECHAI SHECHTER between private and public perception regarding the neg-
Natural Resource & Environmental Research Center ative externality associated with landfilling. We believe that
University of Haifa this information is useful in determining the level of subsidi-
Haifa, 31905, Israel zation needed (if at all) to sustain any recycling program.
The study is unique in the sense that its conclusions are
based on revealed household behavior when faced with in-
creased disposal costs, as well as information on WTP re-
ABSTRACT / Municipalities everywhere are coping with sponses in hypothetical but related (and, therefore, familiar)
increasing amounts of solid waste and need urgently to scenarios. The article also explores the influence of the
formulate efficient and sustainable solutions to the problem. subsidization schemes on recycling rates. It was found that
This study examines the use of economic incentives in with low levels of effort needed to participate in a curbside
municipal waste management. Specifically, we address the recycling program, householdsÕ participation rates are
issue of recycling, if and when this waste management mainly influenced by economic variables and age, and
option is—on social welfare grounds—a preferred solution. households are willing to pay a higher price for the recycling
A number of studies have recently assessed the monetary scheme. When the required effort level is relatively high,
value of the externalities of alternative solid waste manage- however, households would pay a lower price, and the rate is
ment options. In the present context, these subsidies could influenced mainly by their environmental commitment and by
be interpreted as the implicit value of the benefits from economic considerations. We found that in both cases a
reducing environmental externalities associated with land- subsidy would be required in order to achieve an efficient
filling as perceived by local government authorities. We level of recycling. The median price that households are
surmise that the difference between mean householdsÕ willing to pay for recycling devices is found to be about NIS
willingness to pay (WTP) for recycling services, via the 370 (New Israeli Shekel, approximately $90).

Municipal solid waste (MSW) is a combined private tive, cost-saving solutions to deal with the problem of
and public bad, which generates negative externalities the mounting volume and weight of MSW, recycling
when disposed of in certain manners. In Israel, as being a politically favored option. Clearly, the higher
elsewhere, the collection, transportation, and disposal the level of the householdsÕ participation in recycling
is provided by local authorities and financed through efforts, the more cost-efficient this alternative becomes.
municipal taxes that is by-and-large unrelated to the Households, however, are not always willing to partic-
volume or weight of waste (and externalities) gener- ipate, especially if it involves large investments of time,
ated by a household or a firm. Thus, for example, a space to store recyclables, and out-of-pocket expenses.
study commissioned by Israel Ministries of the Envi- The Israeli situation is compounded because of the
ronment and the Interior (Biotech 1995) showed that composition of MSW. Forty-eight percent of the waste
each person produces on average 1.14 kg of waste, or (by weight) is comprised of organic matter, yard waste,
1.73 kg including yard and construction waste, daily, and disposable diapers (Table 1), a much higher per-
and the trend has been upward due to population and centage than typical to most Western countries. Con-
income growth as well as changes in lifestyle; conse- sequently, the separation of these organic materials
quently, greater than optimal amounts of waste are from the general MSW flow will reduce the costs of
produced. Understandably, authorities seek alterna- transportation and the need for scarce landfill space. It
will also reduce negative externalities at the landfill,
such as contamination of groundwater, release of
KEY WORDS: Municipal solid waste (MSW); Willingness to pay
(WTP); Recycling, Composting; Economic incentives greenhouse gases [according to Ayalon (1999), 12% of
total greenhouse gases in Israel are related to methane
Published online February 16, 2005. emitted from landfills] and other noxious gases into
*Author to whom correspondence should be addressed; email: the environment, and the spread of diseases by animals
agofira@techunix.technion.ac.il and birds feeding at the landfill site. Furthermore, the

Environmental Management Vol. 35, No. 2, pp. 121–129 ª 2005 Springer Science+Business Media, Inc.
122 R. Palatnik and others

Table 1. Composition of solid waste in Israel, 1995 demands on the residents in terms of separation efforts,
Percent
because they were no longer required to store the dry
Component (by weight) waste in their homes for more than a week, but directly
place the separated waste in the new containers. By
Organic fraction 38
Paper and cardboard 22
March 2000, 564 out of 1864 eligible families purchased
Plastic 14 the new separation container (SC). TivÕon can be re-
Yard waste 6 ferred as a representative of 54 similar communities in
Metals 4 Israel (by size of the population and its socioeconomic
Glass 3 parameters), which are about 7% of the whole popu-
Disposable diapers 4
Textile 3
lation (Israeli Central Bureau of Statistics, 2003).
Other (rubber, leather) 6 Misgav is a township with a population of 2600, liv-
ing in 30 separate, nonagricultural communities. It
Source: Biotech (1995).
generated 5900 tons of solid waste annually. Here,
subsidized (again, at a rate of 50% of cost) home
biodegradable materials can be turned into compost, a composters (HCs) were offered for sale to residents. In
valuable material for agriculture in semiarid areas; it order to produce high-quality compost for use in their
enriches soil quality and increases yields (Avnimelech own gardens, residents must carefully separate organic
1997). For these reasons, recycling (at least the or- material from metals, plastic, glass, and so forth. The
ganic—or ‘‘wet’’—components of MSW), in countries compost must be mixed from time to time and watered
like Israel, could serve as a highly viable, economically in order to speed up the biodegradation process. In
efficient policy option for MSW management (Artzi addition to the individual household subsidy, the re-
and Aharon 2001). gional authority has promised that each community in
The aim of this study was to examine the efficacy of which at least 80% of the homes purchased HCs, would
economic instruments in promoting waste recycling enjoy a NIS 40 rebate per household on the taxes it
schemes in Israel. To date, effectively very little use, if charges each community in Misgav for environmental
at all, has been made in Israel of this option in either services. As of May 2000, 502 HCs were purchased at
MSW management or other environmental policy prices ranging from NIS 120 to 240 (after a 50% sub-
spheres. As Ayalon and others (1999) have shown, the sidy of the full cost of HCs, which ranged between NIS
use of such an incentive program in Israel (as else- 240 and 480). The price reflected the differences in
where) can help reduce costs of source separation and size and capacity of HCs offered by the Misgav regional
recycling programs. In order to examine the potential authority. Misgav can be considered representative of
benefits of recycling programs, we have decided to fo- 39 similar townships in Israel (by size of the population
cus on two ongoing programs of source separation of and its socioeconomic parameters), which are about
waste and recycling, targeting separation of clean or- 8% of the whole population (Israeli Central Bureau of
ganic waste (including yard waste and diapers), in two Statistics, 2003).
Israeli municipalities.
TivÕon is a town of 12,700 residents generating about
Related Studies
14,000 tons of MSW annually. Most of the dwellings are
single-family homes. A voluntary policy of source sepa- Rich literature is found on the issue of environ-
ration of waste was introduced early in 2000, offering mental policy toward reducing disposal and increasing
homeowners 500-L concrete bins, priced at NIS 420 recycling of household solid waste using economic
(New Israeli Shekel equivalent to about 0.25 US$ at the incentives. Kinnaman and Fullerton (2000/2001) pro-
time of the study) each, and ideally suited for separat- vided a good summary of most of the related re-
ing organic ‘‘wet’’ material (food waste, disposable searches on the subject. However, only few works were
diapers, and light garden trimming) from ‘‘dry’’ found in which householdsÕ willing to pay (WTP) for
material—the rest of the waste stream. The price recycling was estimated using observations of actual
embodied a 50% subsidy. Under an earlier, mandatory behavior, as did the present study.
system, 90-L bins were posted outside each home. They Specifically, a couple of recent studies have em-
were designed to accommodate ‘‘nonrecyclable’’ waste. ployed a somewhat similar approach to the one em-
In addition, residents were required to store certain ployed in this study to analyze the issue of recycling in
recyclables (paper, cardboard, plastic containers, etc.) MSW management. Sterner and Bartelings (1999)
in their homes and put them out once a week at the analyzed the cost of waste disposal, recycling, and
curbside for collection. The new system made easier composting in municipalities in southern Sweden,
Household Demand for Waste Recycling Services 123

Table 2. Comparison of relevant studies


Present study Swedish study US study
1. Subsidy on waste collection device; 1. Tax on waste removal; source separation 1. Unit pricing on waste removed;
curbside recycling and composting and composting curbside recycling
2. Based on actual WTP and survey data 2. Based on actual composition and quantity 2. Based on actual percentage
of waste and survey data waste recycled and survey data
3. Jenkins ‘‘Household Production Model’’ 3. Jenkins ‘‘Household Production Model’’ 3. Jenkins ‘‘Household Production
(1993) framework (1993) framework Model’’ (1993) framework
4. Analysis of waste removal, recycling, and 4. Analysis of waste removal, recycling and 4. Comparison between unit
composting composting pricing and curbside collection
as incentive to waste recycling
5. Estimation of WTP also through CVM 5. Estimation of WTP

where a unit tax system based on the weight of waste all five categories of waste, although the scale of the
generated by each household was introduced in 1994. influence varied from material to material. The unit
At the same time, the municipalities initiated an pricing option influenced only the effort to separate
advertising campaign on the environmental merits of and recycle newspapers. Household income had a po-
the program. This policy caused a significant decrease sitive, statistically significant influence on the recycling
in the amount of waste collected and an increase in effort for newspaper and plastic bottles. Generally, the
recycling. The researchers had access to data measur- higher the householdsÕ income, the larger the amount
ing the actual amount of waste disposed of, in addition of these materials recycled.
to household characteristics from a Contingent Valu- From the above comparison, it is clear that the
ation Method (CVM) survey. They found that the Swedish and American studies complement each other
important determinants of the householdsÕ behavior with regard to the type of incentives analyzed by them.
and waste composition are the relative difficulty of Both of them, as well as the study presented below,
composting different materials, living space, and age. were based on a combination of observed data and
WTP was measured and compared for three different observed behavior. However, only the present work
municipalities. It was found that composting had a specifically employs data on WTP obtained from a
statistically significant negative correlation with waste householdÕs stated preferences (CVM) survey and ac-
generation: Composting reduced the flow of waste for tual behavior (purchasing SC/HC at the authority
general disposal. Age also was a significant factor in proposed price). Table 2 presents and compares the
explaining the volume of waste generated; elderly three studies.
people were willing to invest more time in recycling
and composting. Economic incentives were also found
Data Description
to be important in promoting recycling.
A study by Jenkins and others (1999, 2003) falls The present study is unique in the sense that the
between our study of curbside recycling, as detailed analysis is based on combining responses from a CVM
below, and the Swedish study on composting and unit survey with observed household behavior when faced
pricing of waste. It analyzed two options for reducing with actual choice of payment for recycling services.
MSW: (1) unit pricing and (2) curbside recycling of The database included information obtained from the
five types of waste: glass bottles, plastic bottles, alumi- municipalities on the purchases of separation or
num, newspaper, and yard waste. The data analyzed composting container (depending on the municipal-
were unique in terms of the information level on US ity) and on levels of waste removal and composting in
households and included information on (1) the per- the two municipalities. A CVM telephone survey of
centage of the five types of waste recycled, (2) charac- samples of residents in the two municipalities gath-
teristics of the recycling program (curbside recycling ered data on several aspects of the extent of the
versus removal on a voluntary or mandatory basis), (3) householdsÕ awareness regarding recycling, familiarity
socioeconomic characteristics of households, and (4) with a variety of characteristics of the relevant waste
fees collected for removal in municipalities with a unit separation system, and socioeconomic background.
pricing. It was found that the access to curbside recy- Respondents who stated that they owned or definitely
cling and the time that passed from the introduction of intended to buy the relevant container were queried
the program were the two main positive and statistically whether they would be willing to pay a higher price,
significant influences on the percentage of recycling in which was randomly chosen out of five (TivÕon) and
124 R. Palatnik and others

three levels (Misgav) bid levels. In each case, the


maximum bid was equal to the actual cost of the
container (i.e., without any subsidy). Subjects who
indicated that they would not buy the container at the
actual price were asked for the reason. If it was in-
come related, they were queried whether they would
be willing to pay a lower price (randomly selected
from among the options). However, in both munici-
palities, relatively few respondents indicated that the
reason for nonacquisition was economic (e.g., in Ti-
vÕon 18 out of 131 respondents).

TivÕon
Figure 1. Cumulative distribution function of probability to
The sample consisted of 445 households, out of buy at price A.
which 271 households owned SCs and 43 indicated that
they intend to acquire one. Thus, the data from the
445 households were used to estimate the WTP of the The estimated regressions for the WTP for recy-
total relevant population in TivÕon (denoted WTPt) cling services in TivÕon and Misgav served two
and data from 314 (271 + 43) households were used to objectives. The first was to identify key parameters in
estimate the WTP of those who actually bought the the characterization of communities that affect the
container (WTPb). demand for waste separation services under the two
recycling programs. The second objective was to
Misgav calculate the median WTP in each case [i.e., the
price at which households are indifferent between
The sample consisted of 575 homeowners, of whom
purchasing a SC/HC (and thereby ensure their par-
296 purchased HCs and 19 declared their intention to
ticipation in the recycling program), and not pur-
buy one. Data from the 575 homeowners served to
chasing].
estimate the appropriate WTPt and from 315 (296 +
To carry out the first objective, a regression for
19) to estimate WTPb.
theentire population of homeowners (WTPt) was esti-
mated; therefore, it was necessary to weigh differently
Methods for Estimating WTP for Recycling purchasers and nonpurchasers in the sample accord-
ing to their actual representation in the entire popu-
Services
lation. For example, 564 households in TivÕon owned
The Random Utility Model (RUM) (Hanemann SCc out of 1864 private homeowners at the time of the
1984) underlies the estimation of the WTP for recy- survey. Out of 445 private homeowners participating in
cling services function. The model posits the point at the survey, 314 owned SCs. In order to obtain results
which a household is indifferent between paying to that reflected the actual situation, in each run of the
participate in the new recycling program, and not regression we used a weighted regression that matched
paying. This point is indicated by E in Figure 1 on the responses of owners of SC/HC with their real
the function, GE(A), depicting the cumulative dis- weight in the population. The dependent variable in
tribution function (CDF) of the buying decision for the estimated regression equation is BUY, the proba-
any given price A (of a HC or SC). The indifference bility that WTP is greater than zero for a household
point is derived from data on individuals who did with given characteristics (i.e., the probability that the
purchase the SC/HC, supplemented by information household would purchase a SC/HC at a stipulated
from the CVM survey of households that declined to price). In the case of TivÕon, BUY stands for the
buy at the stipulated price A. Essentially, the CDF of probability that a SC would be purchased at a price of
the purchase decision represents the household de- NIS 420. In the case of Misgav, BUY stands for the
mand function for SC or HC, and, by association, the probability that a HC would be purchased at a price
demand for recycling services. Given the high pro- ranging from NIS 120 to NIS 240.
portion of nonbuyers, we supplemented the analysis To deal with the second objective, an additional
by employing Reiser and ShechterÕs (1999) spike regression was estimated using responses of only those
model method for incorporating zero CVM re- households that actually bought or intended to buy the
sponses. SC/HC (regression of WTPb). In this case, the
Household Demand for Waste Recycling Services 125

dependent variable BUY is the probability of purcha- household. All socioeconomic variables had a positive
sing the SC/HC at a higher price than the actual stated effect on the likelihood of purchasing a SC. The like-
in the explanatory variable ln(bid). For TivÕon, ln(bid) lihood increases if the respondent or his/her spouse is
was randomly selected from five bids: NIS 500, 600, self-employed. The same also holds true for retirees. A
700, 800, and 920 (equal to the full cost of the con- possible explanation is that the shadow value of time of
tainer). For Misgav, ln(bid) applied to respondents pensioners is relatively low. Our findings with respect
who had paid NIS 120 for the HC, selected randomly to the age variable conform to other studies (Jenkins
from the following four bids: NIS 150, 170, 200, and and others 2003; Sterner and Bartelings 1999; Ayalon
240 (the full cost of the smallest HCs). As we noted and others 1999; Fullerton and Kinnaman 1995). In
earlier, the price of HCs in Misgav jumped from NIS general, our findings regarding the positive effect of
120 to 240, so for those who paid the higher price, the economic status variables correspond to those of other
following three bids were used: NIS 300, 400, and 480 works dealing with recycling effort (Jenkins and others
(the full price of the largest HC). The regression 2003; Ayalon and others 1999; Callan and Thomas
equations were estimated using the forward estimation 1999).
procedure. According to Reiser and ShechterÕs (1999) In the regression of the WTP for HCs in Misgav,
spike model method, estimations of the dependent none of the socioeconomic variables was found statis-
variable BUY from WTPt regression and estimated tically significant (Table 3). All of the explanatory
parameters of independent variables from WTPb variables found significant in the regression were re-
regression were employed to derive the household lated to the awareness of the economic and environ-
demand function for SCs or HCs. mental benefits of recycling. As the level of awareness
about recycling and composting rose, the willingness of
Misgav households to participate in the recycling pro-
Results and Discussion gram grew. The difference of found influences on
Table 3 summarizes the results of the four regres- decision of Misgav households compared to TivÕon
sions (WTPt and WTPb for TivÕon and Misgav, households might be explained by the following fac-
respectively). All information gathered in the surveys tors:
was used in the form of explanatory variables. Maxi-
mum likelihood estimation (MLE) using the forward 1. The diverse nature of communities and house-
logistic procedure estimated the vector of coefficients. holds represented in our dataset: Socioeconomic
The value of each of the statistically significant vari- status of households in Misgav varied much less
ables, as they appeared in each regression, is shown in than it did in TivÕon (most of the family heads are
Table 3. The level of confidence of all significant about 40 years old, employed, have three children,
variables was 95% or greater. The variables that were whereas TivÕonÕs population were much more di-
highly insignificant (probability lower than 0.9) were verse).
omitted from the analysis. The variable ln(bid) was 2. Differences in the price of the relevant commodi-
used only in the regression for the WTPb; it is not ties: The SC in TivÕon costs almost twice as much as
relevant for the WTPt regression. the most expensive HC available in Misgav (NIS
420 compared to NIS 240 and almost four times the
price of the least expensive—NIS 120).
WTP Regressions 3. Differences in the amount of time and effort re-
quired under the two systems: In TivÕon, the citi-
WTPt zens are just required to separate the waste,
The econometric results reported in Table 3 indi- whereas in Misgav, residents need to invest time
cate that two categories of variables influenced the and effort in periodically watering and turning the
decision of TivÕon households to purchase SCs at a compost; only after a year could they use the
price of NIS 420. One involves household socioeco- resulting compost on their gardens. Therefore, the
nomic and demographic characteristics and the other purchase of an HC might be interpreted as a de-
is associated with attitude, such as environmental mand for additional effort.
awareness and a positive impression regarding the de- 4. Differences in the ‘‘lifetime’’ of the commodity:
sign of the SC. Statistically significant socioeconomic Misgav HCs are made of plastic and, as such, have
variables in the model were type of employment of the an estimated life of 5 years. In contrast, the con-
respondent, type of employment of the respondentÕs crete SC proposed for TivÕon has an estimated life
spouse, age, and the number of cars owned by the of 15 years or more.
126 R. Palatnik and others

Table 3. Regression estimates, logit model


TivÕon Misgav

WTPt WTPb WTPt WTPb


Sample size (N) of 445 314 575 315
private homeowners
Explanatory variable
Constant )6.498** (0.85)*** 12.756** (3.66) )3.495** (0.282) 12.87** (2.313)
Employee 0.057 (0.405) — — —
Self-employed 0.006 (0.471) — — —
Pensioner 1.2** (0.46) — — —
Age (in years) 0.029** (0.29) — — —
Number of cars 0.417** (0.161) 0.446* (0.207) — —
Participate frequently 3.034* (0.5) — — —
in the scheme
Finds the 1.191* (0.247) — — —
container practical
Reason for recycling — — 4.645 (0.84) —
is environmental
Reason for recycling — 0.493** (0.244) 3.096** (0.7) 0.736** (0.313)
is economic
Reason for recycling — — 9.501** (15.8) —
is local
Babies in the family — — — 0.859** (0.342)
Municipal information — — 2.178** (0.384) —
actions are clear
Separate organic fraction — — — 1.13* (0.445)
to save costs
Separate organic fraction — — — —
to recycle more
Separate organic fraction — — — —
to get compost
Spouse is employed 0.734** (0.376) 0.945** (0.311) — —
Spouse is self-employed 0.277 (0.443) 0.724* (0.441) — —
Partner is a pensioner 0.18 (0.467) 0.708* (0.372) — —
Natural log of the Not used )2.19** (0.562) Not used )2.415** (0.429)
proposed price
Number of rooms — — — —
in house
Income above average — — — —
Received information — — — —
from municipality
Education (in years) — — — —
Number of — — — —
family members
Thinks neighbors — — — —
participate frequently
Knows the separation rule — — — —
Heard about the program — — — —
Score for the municipality — — — —
waste treatment (1–10)
Participates for — — — —
local reasons
Participates to get compost — — — —
Participates for — — — —
ecological reason
Knows that organic — — — —
fraction has to be clean
R2 = 36% R2 = 16% R2 = 72% R2 = 24%
Note. Values in parentheses are standard deviations of the variables.
*a = 0.05
**a = 0.01
Household Demand for Waste Recycling Services 127

WTPb
The WTPb analysis refers to 314 TivÕon households
that had already purchased a SC or indicated a definite
intention to do so at the time of the survey. Consistent
with expectations, as the suggested price of a container
rises, the probability to buy one falls (Table 3). The
analysis also indicates that a higher economic status of
the household increases the probability of purchasing
the container at the suggested price. In addition, those
households show more awareness of recycling and,
especially, that source separation might help decrease
costs and, therefore, increase the efficacy of waste
management.
Willingness to pay analysis for Misgav concerned
Figure 2. Cumulative distribution function of the probabil-
only 315 households in the sample that had already
ity of purchasing a container at price A: TivÕon.
purchased a HC or had indicated the definite inten-
tion to do so. As indicated earlier, some of the HCs in
Misgav were purchased for NIS 240 and some for NIS ceived from not buying the container. In other words,
120. This fact might have influenced the willingness the median price is the point at which 50% of home-
of households to participate in the recycling program owners were willing to pay a positive amount for the SC.
and the price that they were willing to pay. Therefore, Figure 2 depicts the cumulative distribution function of
a dummy variable, LowPrice, was added to the analy- purchasing at a given price A for TivÕon residents,
sis. It had value 1 if the household had purchased a including standard errors. The indicated price of NIS
HC for NIS 120 and 0 otherwise. The effect of this 369 is a relatively high one; yet, it is lower than the NIS
variable on the WTP was not found to be statistically 420, which TivÕon residents had to pay, and much lower
significant. As hypothesized, an inverse relationship than the full cost of the container (NIS 920).
was found between the price of the HC and the WTP As Figure 2 indicates, 38% of homeowners in Ti-
for it: The higher the proposed price, the lower the vÕon would purchase a SC for NIS 420. In fact, by
WTP [negative coefficient on log(Bid)]. Additional October 2002, more than half of TivÕonÕs homeowners
variables influencing the actual buyersÕ WTP, as in the had bought a SC. It should be noted that during the
general population of Misgav, were awareness of time the survey was carried out, the project was based
recycling and its economic and environmental on the voluntary will of the residents to buy the SC.
advantages. Positive coefficients on the variables However, in 2002, the municipality required those
indicate that higher levels of awareness generally, and who needed to replace the old containers to purchase
of the economic advantages in particular, led to a the new SC. We note that the estimated median price
higher WTP. A new variable, appearing for the first is very close to the subsidized price that was actually
time as significant in the analysis, was the presence of charged. Although households that purchased the
a baby in the household. The effect on WTP in this container were prepared to pay a higher price than
case was negative, indicating that individuals taking the median, our findings indicate that the new recy-
care of a baby were less inclined to acquire a HC and cling program in TivÕon could not have succeeded
shoulder its corresponding requirements in invest- without the subsidy.
ment of time and effort. This variable can be inter- The demand schedule for SC can be derived from
preted as a proxy for free time. the cumulative distribution function, because the
independent variable is the price and the dependent
variable is the probability of buying the SC. Upon
The Demand for Recycling Services inversion of the axes of the CDF of the probability of
After accounting for zero responses using the pro- purchasing a SC at price A, found earlier, the demand
cedure suggested by Reiser and Shechter (1999), we function for SC for private homeowners in TivÕon was
applied the Hanneman RUM to derive the median derived (see Figure 3).
price on the demand schedule. It was found that NIS We can now estimate the amount of additional recy-
369 is the price at which the TivÕon householdsÕ utility cling at the TivÕon municipality after the introduction of
from purchasing the container and participation in the a subsidized SC program. The demand function for SC
new program was equal to the utility that would be re- indicates the extent of waste recycling in response to a
128 R. Palatnik and others

This amounts to a marginal cost of zero on waste dis-


posal and creates an incentive to dispose of more waste
than is socially efficient. Municipalities are striving to
make households aware of the cost related to waste,
namely the cost of treatment and related external
costs. This article analyzed the experience of a local
authority in carrying out a program of source separa-
tion and recycling combined with financial participa-
tion and investment of time by residents.
We found the following: (1) As the price that the
household is asked to pay for waste disposal services
rises, the impact of the householdÕs socioeconomic
Figure 3. Demand curve for private homeowners in TivÕon. characteristics on the decision to purchase a separation
container increases. (2) As the amount of effort re-
quired for participation rises, the willingness to par-
change in the subsidized price. The external costs of ticipate falls, as well as the price that the household is
landfilled waste in Israel had been estimated to approx- willing to pay. (3) As the effort required for participa-
imate NIS 23 per ton (Goren 1997; Enosh 1996), imply- tion rises, environmental awareness exerts a much
ing that the capitalized external cost of landfilled waste greater impact upon the decision to participate in the
produced by a typical TivÕon household over a 15-year recycling program.
period (the life of a SC) amounts to NIS 549. According Although it seems that households tend to state that
to the estimated demand function, 25% of homeowners economic reasons did not influence their decision not
in TivÕon (455 out of 1864 homes) would acquire the SC to take part in the program, there is definitely a sig-
at that price (NIS 549). Hence, a subsidy of NIS 180 that nificant correlation between the price of the SC/HC
would lower the cost to NIS 369 (549-180) would raise and the willingness to purchase the device. Households
participation so that 50% of homeowners would buy one are willing to pay for a weight-base waste recycling
(932 homes in the case of TivÕon). Because the average program. Thus, TivÕon residents are willing to pay a
household in TivÕon produces 4.56 kg of solid waste daily, 10% premium for waste separation. However, we found
acquiring a SC would increase the amount of waste that the median WTP was significantly lower than the
recycled from 20% to 70% (i.e., from 0.91 to 3.19 kg. per full price of the SC/HC. It thus seems fair to conclude
day per household). A NIS 180 subsidy would therefore that without the subsidy, the recycling programs (in
raise the amount of recycled waste in TivÕon by about 1 both TivÕon and Misgav communities) would not have
ton per day or 378 tons annually over a 15-year period. succeeded to the extent that they did.
In a similar vein, one can derive the WTP per kilo-
gram waste recycled. Given the TivÕon projectÕs price of
NIS 369 per SC, the corresponding annualized sum is Acknowledgment
NIS 31 (for a device life of 15 years and at 3% interest). We wish to acknowledge the generous support of
This sum can be interpreted as the annual payment Life-3rd Countries project no. LIFETCY 97/IL/ 048.
that a representative household would be willing to pay
for waste collection and recycling in TivÕon. Because
Israeli households, on average, produce 2 tons of solid
waste annually (Biotech 1995), TivÕon households Literature Cited
would, accordingly, be willing to pay NIS 0.015 for Artzi, A., and Aharon. 2001. Waste recycling in Israel—Find-
recycling 1 kg of waste, over and above the charge set ings and targets. Israel Union for Environmental Defense.
by the municipality for waste disposal (i.e., 10% above Available at http://www.iued.org.il (in Hebrew).
the current flat tax). The above analysis refers to Ti- Avnimelech, Y. 1997. Land application of composted muni-
vÕonsÕ data only; similar analysis for Misgav can be cipal wastes. Pages 551–570 in P. N. Chremisinoff (ed.),
found in Palatnik (2002). Ecological issues & environmental impact assessment. Ad-
vances in environmental control technology. Gulf Pub-
lishing, Houston, Texas.
Concluding Remarks Ayalon, O. 1999. Priorities in municipal solid waste treatment.
Pages 8/1–8/17 in Y. Avnimelech (ed.), National priorities
Waste is a nonmarket commodity. Households pay a in environmental quality in Israel. The Neaman Institute
flat fee unrelated to the amount of waste they produce. Publishing, Haifa, Israel (in Hebrew).
Household Demand for Waste Recycling Services 129

Ayalon, O., Y. Avnimelech, and M. Shechter. 1999. Issues in Jenkins, R. J., S. A. Martinez, K. Palmer, and M. J.Podolsky,
designing an effective solid waste policy: The Israeli experi- 1999. The determinants of household recycling: A material-
ence. Pages 389–406 in T. Sterner (ed.), The market and the specific analysis of recycling program features and unit
environment: The effectiveness of market based in reply to pricing. Draft presented in 9th Annual Meeting of the Euro-
instruments for environmental reform. Edward Elgar, Chel- pean Association of Environmental and Resource Econo-
tenham, Cheltenham, UK. mists, Oslo.
Biotec. 1995. Composition of solid waste in Israel. Survey for Jenkins, R. J., S. A. Martinez, K. Palmer, and M. J. Podolsky.
the Ministries of the Environment and Interior (in Hebrew). 2003. The determinants of household recycling: A material-
specific analysis of recycling program features and unit
Callan, S. J., and J. M. Thomas. 1999. Adopting a unit pricing
pricing. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
system for municipal solid waste: Policy and socioeconomic
45:294–318.
determinants. Environmental and Resource Economics 14:503–
518. Kinnaman, T. C., and D. Fullerton (2000/2001). The
economics of residential solid waste management. In
Central Bureau of Statistics, 2003. Real interest rate of gover-
H. Folmer and T. Tietenberg, The international year
mental bonds, Israel. (Available at http://www.cbs.gov.il/).
book of environmental and resource economics
Enosh Consultants Ltd. 1996. Examination of external costs 2001/2002, Edward Elger, Cheltenham, UK, pp.
of waste disposal. Ministry of the Environment, the Waste 100–147.
Department (in Hebrew).
Palatnik, R. 2002. Assessment of demand for recycling ser-
Fullerton, D., and T. Kinnaman. 1995. Garbage, recycling, vices of household solid waste. Masters thesis, Haifa Uni-
and illicit burning or dumping. Journal of Environmental versity, The Faculty of Economics (in Hebrew).
Economics and Management 29(1):78–91, July.
Reiser, B., and M. Shechter. 1999. Incorporating zero values
Goren, T. 1997. Assessment of external costs in waste disposal in the economic valuation of environmental program
sites. Final paper for the degree of Master of Agriculture benefits. Environmetrics 10:87–101.
Sciences, Hebrew University of Jerusalem (in Hebrew). Sterner, T., and H. Bartelings. 1999. Household waste man-
Hanemann, M. 1984. Welfare evaluations in contingent val- agement in a Swedish municipality: Determinants of dis-
uation experiments with discrete responses. American Jour- posal, recycling and composting. Environmental and Resource
nal of Agricultural Economics 66:332–342. Economics 13:473–491.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi