Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 9

The Incoherence of Massachusetts that functioned as a sanction

against both sexual relations and procreation


outside of marriage—should not impose so-
Federal Sex Policy: Title X, called “middle-class morality” on the lower
classes. The government at all levels, it is
Medicaid, and the claimed, must remain absolutely neutral on
“matters so fundamentally affecting a
Eisenstadt Decision person,” including sexual behavior,
marriage, and childbearing decisions. By
by Jennifer Roback Morse, Ph.D. creating an unrestricted right for all citizens
to use contraception regardless of marital
In a 1972 decision widely hailed by the status, Eisenstadt is usually praised as an
political classes, the Supreme Court opined advance for individual liberty against the
in Eisenstadt v. Baird, “If the right to intrusion and meddling of the state.
privacy means anything, it is the right to be
free from unwarranted government Yet what one hand of the law appears to
intrusions into matters so fundamentally give, the other takes away. The same year
affecting a person as the decision whether to the Court was demanding that the
bear or beget a child.”1 Imagining that the government be neutral on sexual matters,
Commonwealth of Massachusetts was Congress was authorizing Medicaid to add
coercing her citizens to have children contraceptives to its covered services to the
against their wishes, the Eisenstadt decision low-income population. Not as innocent as it
struck down a statute that had been amended appears, this expansion of Medicaid cannot
to comply with the requirements of be understood apart from President Richard
Griswold v. Connecticut (1965). That earlier M. Nixon’s signing of the Family Planning
decision had demanded that states allow the Services and Population Research Act of
sale of contraceptives to married couples, as 1970, or Title X of the Public Health
the Court held that prohibiting the use of Services Act, described by social historian
contraceptive devices in marriage would be Allan C. Carlson as “the first federal
an unacceptable invasion of marital program openly focused on the promotion of
privacy.2 In Eisenstadt, however, the Court birth control with the aim of sharply
moved to claim that “whatever the rights the reducing American fertility.”4 In a very real
individual to access contraceptives may be, sense, the new coverage made Medicaid, an
the rights must be the same for married and entitlement program, subservient to the
unmarried alike.”3 goals of Title X. Within time, Medicaid
would become the largest federal supplier of
The Eisenstadt rendering of a “right to contraception. In 2006, for example,
privacy” seems to stand for the position that Medicaid was responsible for more than 70
the nation’s laws—like the one in
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
percent of public birth-control expenditures, Birth control is a mandatory part of

or $1.3 billion.5 state Medicaid programs. Any state
that does not want to offer family-
The goals, methods, and results of these two planning services will face a penalty
federal birth-control initiatives, however, fly and lose other Medicaid funds. When
directly in the face of the Supreme Court’s dealing with most other services,
demand that the government remain neutral including life-saving services such as
with respect to private reproductive chemotherapy, the states have a
decisions. There is a fundamental choice about whether to offer them.
incoherence in federal policy, which limits This conveys the unmistakable
the rights of the states to regulate or even message that preventing births is
influence norms of sexual behavior while at more important than preserving life.
the same time assigns to itself the right to  Contraception is the most favored
spend billions of taxpayer dollars to service in Medicaid. The federal
influence those norms at the state, local, and government will pay up to 90 percent
individual level. The fact that the American of a state’s birth-control related
public has grown accustomed to the idea of expenses, a treatment accorded to no
the federal government financing and other category of mandatory
promoting contraception does not eliminate services, nor to other preventive
the fact that Title X and its Medicaid version medicines, both categories of which
directly contradict the intellectual are normally reimbursed to the states
underpinnings of the “right to privacy,” at a little more than 50 percent of
which the Court has found to be costs. This extraordinarily favorable
“fundamental.” coverage of birth-control costs is not
a morally neutral posture.
The Medicaid Birth-Control Agenda  Birth control must be available to
minors over the age of puberty. The
The regulations that control Medicaid states cannot adopt their own
treatment of contraceptives illustrate that policies about how and whether to
fundamental incoherence. They demonstrate promote sexual relations among
that Congress was not simply making family unmarried teens. This policy has
planning available to the states and to low- embedded within it the highly
income individuals on a neutral basis. No, dubious empirical claim that making
through Medicaid rules, the federal artificial birth control available
government has been implicitly imposing a promotes health and prevents unwed
morality of its own. Medicaid’s policies teen pregnancy more effectively than
actively promoting contraception have other policies which are less favored
empirical claims and moral arguments by the government. Such policies
embedded within them. For example: might include promoting the
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
confinement of sexual activity to freedom in making their own fertility and
marriage, teaching the natural contraceptive decisions. The federal
rhythms of the body, or providing government has imposed its own values and
teens with non-sexual activities to choices on the population, particularly the
fill their time. poorest and most vulnerable portions of the
 Parents are prohibited from knowing population. These rules weaken the ability
whether their dependent children of state and local communities to counter
receive birth control. Medicaid this federal thumb on the scale of people’s
extends to children the same right to decision-making. For all practical purposes,
doctor-patient confidentiality that the federal government has nationalized a
adults have. States cannot protect policy that tacitly encourages sexual activity
parents’ rights to be informed of or among the unmarried while conducting a
involved with the health-care rear-guard action to prevent the natural
decisions of their children. In effect, outcome of that sexual activity.
the federal government requires the
states to undermine parental Is This Really Uncle Sam’s Business?
supervision and authority over their
children. Evaluating that nationalized policy requires
 Contraception must be free to not simply noting its incongruence with
welfare recipients. The states cannot Eisenstadt’s apparent demand for
even require a nominal fee or co-pay. government neutrality. It also requires
The tacit moral message is that all raising two questions: 1) whether Uncle Sam
the problems associated with non- ought to be in the family-planning business,
marital sexual relations can all be and 2) whether the federal financing and
contracepted away. promotion of contraception has met its
 State governments must actively stated objective or has improved the quality
promote family-planning services, of life of the urban poor. As to the first
especially to minors. The state question: Are the private choices concerning
Medicaid costs associated with family size and spacing of millions of
outreach, advertising, and sex private American citizens really proper
education are reimbursed to the concerns of Congress? What justification is
states at the same favorable 90 there for the federal government to actively
percent rate.6 promote contraception to minors without
parental knowledge or consent?
Under these circumstances, the claim that
the federal government pursues a policy of The obvious answer to the first set of
“neutrality” toward sexual activity and questions is No. Whether Mr. and Mrs.
fertility is hardly credible. The government Morse have two children or no children or
is not simply giving citizens complete ten children is none of the government’s
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
business. In the interests of individual wards of the state or net drains on state
choice, personal autonomy, and human expenditures. For all practical purposes, this
freedom, the government really should mind means the government has an interest in the
its own business about reproductive procreation decisions of the poor. Using this
decisions of private citizens. After all, the rule of thumb, however, assumes that the
vast majority of parents shoulder the vast children of the poor will remain poor, and
majority of financial responsibilities for the never become net tax-contributing citizens.
vast majority of babies. If the parents It assumes further that the proper policy of
believe the babies are worth the costs, the the government is to limit the births of the
state has no right to contradict them or to try poor, rather than to try to help them become
to direct their choices one way or the other. self-supporting tax-paying citizens.

Advocates of federal family-planning Note the incoherence in this argument. The


policies, however, might argue that there are government decides to direct tax funds to
externalities associated with childbearing assist the children of the poor, and then uses
decisions. That is, maybe there are fiscal or its own decision as a rationale for taking an
social costs not borne by the parents. Under interest in the private reproductive behavior
some circumstances, a private decision to of the poor. The behavior of the government
have a baby could have the public becomes an entrée into regulating the
consequence of having a child who will be behavior of the least well-off citizens. Put
dependent on government assistance in another way: To the extent the government
some form or fashion. One more baby born awards generous support for the children of
could mean increased tax expenditures the poor, the government creates its own
through education, welfare costs, and social interest in limiting the number of poor
infrastructure. Yet this consideration applies people. But acting on that interest violates
only to the limited number of cases of babies the autonomy rights of the poor, rights that
who are likely to become net tax consumers the Supreme Court has described as being
over the course of their entire lifetimes. fundamental.
After all, most babies eventually grow up,
earn a living, contribute to society, and pay Concern for the environment is another
taxes. The crass financial assumption that externality that might generate a public
additional babies mean additional public interest in private decisions about family
burdens is simply not plausible for the vast size. Every new human being consumes
majority of births. resources and generates pollution. Some
environmentalists argue that this “carbon
Still, defenders of current federal family- footprint” amounts to a cost that each person
planning policy may argue that the imposes on the environment and on the rest
government has an interest in limiting the of the world. Hence, no decision to bear a
number of babies who are likely to become child is truly a private decision. This is an
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
argument for reducing family size, choose. But it is quite another thing to say
regardless of the wealth of the family or the that the government ought to pursue a policy
wishes of the parents. If anything, the rich of actively promoting some kinds of
should be especially discouraged from reproductive decisions and tacitly
reproducing, since their children are likely discouraging others.
to be bigger consumers, hence bigger
polluters. Has Federal Family Planning Worked?

Finally, the government might adopt a The second question for evaluating federal
population policy for explicitly eugenic sex policy is whether it has achieved its
reasons. That is, the government might goals. The answer to this question depends
claim for itself the responsibility to monitor on the policy goals of family planning. Keep
the health of the gene pool. If it takes up this in mind that some of the possible goals are
responsibility, then funding and promoting mutually contradictory. The birth rate is
contraception per se does not make sense. lower now than in 1970, so one might argue
The government really ought to encourage that the policy has met its “environmental”
people with desirable genes to reproduce, goal. But it is difficult to argue that the
while encouraging contraception for those government has achieved any eugenic goals
with genes deemed to be undesirable. Most or reduced any fiscal externalities. A larger
definitions of “desirable” genes include percentage of births are now to unmarried
some combination of intelligence, high women than ever before. Moreover, the
income-earning capacity, and social taxpayer cost of out-of-wedlock
productivity. In other words, the genes childbearing is conservatively estimated at
labeled “desirable” are the genes of the $112 billion per year in federal state and
relatively well-off. These are the very local expenditures.7 This is the equivalent of
people most likely to have the heaviest the GDP of New Zealand.
“carbon footprint,” since they will be able to
consume more resources. This eugenic In fact, one can make an even stronger
motive, therefore, contradicts the argument for policy failure. Without
environmental motive for the government’s question, anyone wanting to know why
taking an interest in citizens’ private unmarried women are now bearing an
reproductive decisions. unprecedented number of babies must
acknowledge the impact of Title X and
It should be obvious that these possible Medicaid funding for contraception—along
motivations are some combination of with the Supreme Court’s decision in 1973
perverse, implausible, or repulsive. It is one to give women an unrestricted right to
thing to argue that the government should abortion. The linkage between government
permit private citizens to use contraception funding for contraception and out-of-
in any way and in any context that they wedlock births is not merely some fantasy of
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
right-wing social conservatives. That But when low-cost, highly effective
widespread contraception and unwed contraception is introduced, distributed, and
childbearing are causally related is the paid for by the federal government, these
conclusion of a Nobel Prize winning cultural norms no longer serve the same
economist, George A. Akerlof, and his purpose and are likely to fade. A woman
colleagues. They set for themselves the task cannot so easily resist a man’s sexual
of answering the question of why unmarried advances on the grounds that she might get
childbearing increased at exactly the period pregnant: the probability of pregnancy is
of time that contraception and abortion lower. The man can make birth control and
became widely available. Their conclusion: sex the price of being in a relationship with
widespread use of contraception and the him. In many ways, the man has the upper
availability of abortion changes relationships hand; he can more easily find an alternative
between men and women in significant lover if she refuses. Even a woman who
ways. These changes do not just affect the would be inclined to abstain from premarital
individuals who choose to use the relations will face increased pressure to be
technology. Contraceptive technology, sexually permissive. The pressure comes not
imposed on the states by the Court and only from men but also indirectly from
subsidized by Title X and Medicaid, competition with other women.
changes the terms on which everyone
participates in the dating and mating game, If sexual relations commonly result in
even if they decline to use the technology.8 pregnancy, a woman can refuse sex unless
she receives an implicit or explicit promise
When sexual activity entails a high of marriage in the event of pregnancy. As
probability of pregnancy, society develops a the connection between each sexual act and
set of cultural norms for inducing men to pregnancy weakens, a woman is less able to
commit to women they impregnate. These extract a promise of marriage in the event of
norms, largely if informally enforced by pregnancy. If she asks for a promise, she
women, include a strong social expectation may simply cause the man to leave the
that women will refuse sex outside of relationship and find someone who does not
marriage. Women develop a set of socially ask for a marriage promise. The “social
acceptable ways to refuse sex, even with compact” among women therefore breaks
men they genuinely like. The norms also down because of the broader social impact
include the expectation that the man will of even a small number of women who are
marry a woman he impregnates. All these willing to abort their children rather than
norms are designed to discourage casual carry a non-marital pregnancy to term.
encounters and encourage fathers to commit
to mothers. Look at it this way: A single woman who is
willing to terminate a pregnancy will not ask
the man for a promise to marry in the event
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
of pregnancy; she considers abortion a married has declined, and the proportion of
simpler solution to her “problem” of an babies born outside of wedlock has
unwed pregnancy. A woman who really increased. As Akerlof notes, between 1965
wants motherhood will keep the baby, even and 1989, the birth rate per 1,000 married
if the father refuses to marry her. The typical white women declined from 119 to 90, while
man presumably knows this, so her attempts the birth rate per 1,000 unmarried white
to persuade him to marry her are not women doubled from 12 to 24 births over
credible. Therefore, in the presence of the same time period. At the same time, the
unrestricted abortion as a back up to percentage of white women who married
contraceptive failure, women will not insist declined from 68 percent to 58 percent. The
on a promise of marriage in the event of a percentage of “shotgun marriages” declined
premarital pregnancy. To put it even more from 60 percent to 42 percent for whites,
starkly, no woman will be in a position to while the ratio of adoptions to out-of-
demand such a promise, since there is no wedlock births declined from 49 percent to
credible threat of social stigma or sanction 20 percent.9
that she can impose on him. The social norm
that insists that men marry women they In short, more of the women who conceived
impregnate erodes very quickly. out of wedlock ended up raising the child as
a single parent. Fewer mothers married the
This is the answer to the puzzle of federal father of the child or placed the child for
family planning: Why should low-cost and adoption. The overall result is that fewer
free contraception for the unmarried lead to children are raised in married couple, two-
more children being born in less desirable, parent households. Yet, this is the family
more difficult circumstances—namely out- form most conducive to the welfare of
of-wedlock—when the ability to prevent and children.10
terminate pregnancy increases? This occurs
precisely because so many women actually The Moral of the Story
want babies, more so than the estimates of
so-called “unintended” pregnancies and The lesson should be clear: A nation cannot
birth suggest. These women want their avoid legislating morality.11 The attempt to
babies; they don’t want to have abortions. remain neutral is itself, not neutral. The
Not very long ago, these women would have federal government’s policies have eroded
had the support of the entire society in the social norms around sexual activity,
pressuring the father to marry them. But marriage, and childbearing. Far from
since having a baby is a “woman’s choice,” occupying some Olympian perspective of
that pressure is greatly attenuated. neutrality, the largest and most powerful
government in the world has created an
Consequently, the overall birth rate has alternative moral universe, based upon
declined, the proportion of women that are highly debatable moral premises and
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
empirical claims. States and localities, policy idea whose time has come, and not
churches, and individuals have very limited just for the “religious right,” whoever that
room to maneuver in trying to establish might be. This is good policy for fiscal
more reasonable standards of sexual conservatives and civil libertarians, for
behavior. Citizens who see the anyone who wants to limit the expenditures
destructiveness of the current federal sex of the government and the intrusiveness of
policy are reduced to arguing for parental the state.
notification or waiting periods for abortion,
or for marriage and abstinence promotion to Dr. Morse, a frequent contributor to The
counter the federal government’s active Family in America, taught economics at
promotion of sex outside of marriage. The Yale and George Mason University. She is
federal government has morally disarmed the foundress of the Ruth Institute, a project
our culture. Ordinary Americans have been of the National Organization for Marriage.
reduced to bringing knives to a gunfight.

The federal government has no business


trying to persuade women to have fewer
children. Nor does the federal government
have any business undermining the authority
of parents to supervise their children’s
behavior by mandating that minors receive 1. Eisenstadt v. Baird, 405 U.S. 438,
contraception and abortion without parental 453 (1972).
notification. Nor does the federal 2. Griswold v. Connecticut, 381 U.S.
government have any business regulating 479 (1965). See the analysis of this
the sexual policies of the states. This area is case in Gerard V. Bradley, “Same-
ripe for policy experimentation among state Sex Marriage: Our Final Answer?”
and local governments and for the creation Notre Dame Journal of Law, Ethics
of distinctive local cultures. Finally, in this and Public Policy, 14.2 (2000): 729–
era of bankrupt governments, it is the height 52, and Jennifer Roback Morse,
of fiscal foolishness and irresponsibility for Smart Sex: Finding Life-Long Love
the taxpayers to subsidize family-planning in a Hookup World (Dallas: Spence,
programs that are aggravating the very 2005), pp. 75–78.
problems they were implemented to solve. 3. Eisenstadt v. Baird, 405 U.S. 438,
453 (1972).
In short, it is time for the federal 4. Alan C. Carlson, “The Bipartisan
government to cease and desist from trying Blunder of Title X: How Uncle Sam
to shape the reproductive choices of Embraced Thirty Years of “Family
American citizens. Ending Title X and Planning,” Family Policy,
Medicaid funding for contraception is a September-October 2000, p. 1.
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.
5. A. Sonfield, C. Alrich, and R. B. 11. Micah Watson, “Why We Can’t
Gold, “Public Funding for Family Help But Legislate Morality,” Public
Planning, Sterilization, and Abortion Discourse: Ethics, Law and the
Services, FY 1980–2006,” Common Good, The Witherspoon
Occasional Report No. 38 (New Institute, November 4, 2010,
York: Guttmacher Institute, 2008). http://www.thepublicdiscourse.com/
6. Daniel Patrick Moloney, “Forcing 2010/11/1792.
the Poor to Stop Having Children,”
Public Discourse: Ethics, Law and
the Common Good, The
Witherspoon Institute, May 1, 2009,
http://www.thepublicdiscourse.com/
2009/05/230.
7. Benjamin Scafidi, “The Taxpayer
Costs of Divorce and Unwed
Childbearing: First-Ever Estimates
for the Nation and All Fifty States”
(New York: Institute for American
Values and the Georgia Family
Council, 2008),
http://www.marriagedebate.com/pdf/
ec_div.pdf.
8. See George A. Akerlof, Janet L.
Yellen, and Michael L. Katz, “An
Analysis of Out-of-Wedlock
Childbearing in the United States,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
111.2 (May 1996): 277–317.
9. Ibid., Tables I and II.
10. See Morse, Smart Sex, chapter 1, for
some of the many references on this
point. See also the essays by Don
Browning and Elizabeth Marquardt,
Maggie Gallagher, and W. Bradford
Wilcox in The Meaning of Marriage:
Family, State, Market and Morals,
eds. Robert P. George and Jean
Bethke Elshtain (Dallas: Spence,
2006).
Dr. Jennifer Roback Morse • 663 S. Rancho Santa Fe Road Suite 222 San Marcos CA 92078
www.jennifer-roback-morse.com • email: drj@jennifer-roback-morse.com • 760/295-9278
©2007 No part of this document may be reproduced or disseminated in any way without the expressed written consent of the
Ruth Institute.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi