Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 37

The Dutch Tulip Mania: The Social Politics of a Financial Bubble

A. Maurits van der Veen


Assistant Professor
Department of International Affairs
University of Georgia

March 2009

Abstract

The Dutch tulip mania of 1636-1637 is widely seen as the first recorded instance of a
financial bubble. In recent years, however, economists have argued that prices offered
and paid for tulip bulbs, while extremely high, nevertheless reflected underlying
economic fundamentals. If valid, such claims imply that the tulip mania cannot be
considered a true bubble. This paper demonstrates that attempts to rationalize the bubble
in this manner cannot be justified with the available data: the tulip mania really did
produce a bubble. Moreover, the paper presents a model based on social networks and
information cascades that explains the emergence of the bubble as well as its subsequent
collapse. The salient feature of the tulip mania was not the astronomical prices that were
paid for bulbs, but instead the remarkably dense and localized social network within
which the tulip market was embedded.

Keywords

Tulip mania, financial bubbles, speculation, investment, social networks, Holland


The Dutch Tulip Mania: The Social Politics of a Financial Bubble

I shall eliminate…
Those who ran with rabid lust after filthy profit,
And poured so much of their poisoned juice
That they nearly corrupted the real [flower-loving] people
To no longer revere my flowers as they used to
But weigh trash with pounds and bulbs by weight
— Flora [the goddess of flowers], 1637.1

The Dutch tulip mania of the 1630s has long served as the epitome of the financial

bubble. In his book Irrational Exuberance, Shiller calls it “the most famous bubble of

all.”2 No asset bubble is too small or too large or its bursting will be compared to the

Dutch tulip craze. Indeed, references to tulips have come thick and fast in discussions of

the current financial crisis. The Economist refers to “all those overpriced Dutch tulips” in

an article examining financial instability,3 while the New York Times asks: “It can’t

possibly be that in the sophisticated, computerized 21st century, we find ourselves

experiencing the same kind of financial panic — the same kind of financial insanity,

really — that has dogged mankind at least since the Dutch tulip mania of the 1630s. Can

it?”4

The tulip craze has maintained its grip on the public imagination not just as a

reference point in finance, but also as a fascinating episode in itself — witness Dumas’

1 (De Verstoorde, 1637) (The angry and not-yet-dead Flora.) All translations are by the author.

2 (Shiller, 2000, p. 177) Similarly, though Kindleberger’s standard work Manias, Panics and Crashes
offers only a very superficial discussion of the mania, he nonetheless lists it as the first of the “big 10
financial bubbles” (Kindleberger & Aliber, 2005, p. 8)
3 ("Wild-Animal Spirits," 2009)
4 (Nocera, 2008)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 2

classic novel The Black Tulip and Moggach’s more recent Tulip Fever.5 In recent years,

however, some authors have called into questions its status as an early example of a

financial bubble. There is some disagreement among economists on the proper definition

of a bubble, but Shiller’s definition — “a situation in which temporarily high prices are

sustained largely by investors’ enthusiasm rather than by consistent estimation of real

value” — appears relatively uncontroversial.6 The controversy lies in its

operationalization: how does one judge whether “consistent estimation of real value” is

taking place? Clearly, high prices do not suffice: the fact that single bulbs sold for more

than the price of a house during the tulip mania appears foolish today, but it may well

reflect the value placed on those bulbs by contemporaries.

Several authors have challenged the tulip mania’s iconic status as a financial bubble.

First, Garber has suggested that the pattern of price changes observed during the tulip

craze matches the pattern one would expect for novel luxury goods in limited but

gradually growing supply.7 His argument is widely cited but rarely examined closely.

More recently, Thompson has claimed that the dramatic increases in tulip prices during

the winter of 1636-1637 were due to a shift in market instruments from standard futures

contracts to options.8 If either author is correct, the literature on financial bubbles may be

forced to make do without this popular episode. As I show in this paper, however, both

are wrong.

5 (Moggach, 1999)
6 (Shiller, 2000, p. xii)
7 (Garber, 1989, 2000)
8 (Thompson, 2006)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 3

The Dutch tulip mania undeniably meets Shiller’s definition of a bubble, and as such

deserves to retain its place as an early illustration of “the madness of crowds.”9 More

importantly, the episode sheds a valuable light on a feature of speculative bubbles often

ignored by market fundamentalists: the impact of social networks and norms. The tulip

mania illustrates the ease with which a bubble can emerge within comparatively small

and densely connected social networks. The remainder of the paper is divided into three

parts. The first part briefly presents the key features of the tulip craze. Next I analyze the

available evidence on tulip prices during the mania, which demonstrates that a bubble did

arise, and that claims to the contrary cannot be sustained by the data. The third part,

finally, shifts the emphasis to the social context that made the bubble possible, but also

limited its scope and duration.

The Tulip Craze

Tulips arrived in Western Europe from Turkey during the sixteenth century. They

rapidly came to be prized above all other flowers, and the well-to-do were willing to pay

quite extraordinary sums to obtain the latest, most spectacularly colored variety.10

Particularly prized were tulips with darker colored stripes and “flames” on a lighter

background. Many of the most valuable striations were created, we now know, by a virus.

This was not understood at the time, however, hampering the systematic development of

new varieties. Moreover, such “flaming” tulips were always a risky investment, since it

9 (Mackay, 1932 [1852])

10 Indeed, a 1614 book of emblems displays a tulip alongside the proverb “A fool and his money are soon
parted” (Visscher, 1614)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 4

was never certain whether their patterns would be as desirable, and valuable, from one

year to the next.11 To minimize uncertainty, serious tulip collectors contracted to buy and

sell bulbs while they were in bloom, making payment and taking delivery only later, once

the bulbs were lifted from the ground.

Tulip prices were high because supplies of the most exciting new varieties were

extremely limited. The supply of the most famous tulip of the 1620s, the Semper

Augustus was in the hands of a single owner, who held on to the bulbs as prices offered

rose from 1000 gulden per bulb in 1623 to 3000 gulden per bulb in 1625.12 When a

Semper Augustus bulb was finally sold some time later, the owner attached the

stipulation that the buyer could sell neither the bulb itself, nor any of its offsets — small

bulbs that develop on the outside of the main bulb — without permission of the original

seller.13 The problematic combination of uncertainty about the quality of a bulb’s next

flower and mostly informal inevitably resulted in some failed transactions. Indeed, most

of our reliable knowledge about tulip prices during this period derives from such

transactions, since the disappointed party would often approach a notary to file an official

complaint. Records of these complaints are still kept in the city archives of many cities in

Holland, whereas almost no original transaction records remain. The first of these

complaints show up in the city archives as early as 1611.14

11 (Roman, 1637b, p. 22)


12 (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 31-33; van Wassenaer, 1625) The Dutch currency at the time was the gulden,
often translated as guilder. The annual earnings of a skilled artisan such as a carpenter around 1630
were about 300 gulden (Goldgar, 2007, p. 225) At 3000 gulden, the Semper Augustus was valued at
about 10 times the annual income of someone in the lower middle class.
13 (Roman, 1637a, pp. 18-19)
14 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 11-13)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 5

The number of different varieties of tulips increased very rapidly during the 1620s

and 1630s — far too rapidly for any consistent naming scheme to evolve.15 Some names

were descriptive, but many signaled high quality and the bulb’s original owner or town.

Thus we find many tulips whose name begins with Admirael or Generael, applying

military ranks to signify the fine quality of the bulb. Admirael van Enckhuysen was a

bulb originally grown in the town of Enkhuizen, while the tulip grower Van der Eijck

was the original owner of the first Generael van der Eijck bulb.16 Despite the large

number of varieties, supply remained quite limited, as new bulbs needed to grow for a

number of years before they bloomed for the first time. Though there were dozens of

highly prized varieties, the total supply for any given variety was frequently only a

handful of bulbs, property of an even smaller number of growers.

Until the early 1630s, the market for tulips was composed almost entirely of

aficionados trading amongst themselves. These were mostly wealthy merchants whose

financial fortunes would not be negatively affected by the occasional disappointing

purchase of a bulb that turned out to be less fine than expected. Moreover, as bulb lovers

they also had a thorough knowledge of tulip growing and of the characteristics of

different varieties. Most importantly, since transactions took place during the time when

bulbs were in bloom, the quality of the flowers could be assessed. By 1634, however,

15 By the peak of the mania in early 1637 about 500 different varieties had been developed in Holland.
Few of these same varieties still exist today, but we have contemporary pictures of about 80% of them
(Krelage, 1942a, p. 59)

16 (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 35-38; see also Roman, 1637a, p. 16) Inevitably, name inflation occurred: one of
the most famous varieties during the tulip craze was the Gouda bulb, named for the Dutch town.
However, its original name was actually Generael der Generaelen van Gouda, i.e. “general of
generals.”
The Dutch Tulip Mania 6

sales had begun to take place throughout the year.17 A futures market developed shortly

thereafter: people began to sell bulbs for which they had signed a contract but which they

did not yet have in their possession.18 This permitted traders to make a profit without ever

having to plant a bulb of their own. Not surprisingly, it took little time for speculators to

enter the market.

A number of factors served as catalysts for speculation. First, Dutch commerce in

general was flourishing during this period, creating new wealth not only at the elite levels

but also among an increasingly prominent middle class. 19 Second, the large profits

generated by the East Indian trade — as well as speculation in the shares of the Dutch

East India Company (VOC) — generated not only high incomes, but also a level of

comfort with risky futures contracts.20 Third, no guild controlled the tulip trade, so

barriers to entry were comparatively low.21 Finally, it has been suggested that the free

coinage policy of the Bank of Amsterdam may have attracted additional money to

Holland.22

One additional contributing factor deserves separate mention: the plague which

ravaged Holland in 1635-1636. Amsterdam lost about 20% of its inhabitants over two

17 (Velius, 1648)

18 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 206-207)

19 Indeed, a near-contemporary account characterizes the tulip craze as a “remarkable example”


(verwonderenswaardig exempel) of the growth in wealth and mass participation associated with
commerce (Aitzema, 1669-1672, p. 2:503)

20 Indeed, the Dutch appear to have had an appetite for risk in general. Goldgar cites numerous examples
of contracts for the purchase or sale of bulbs that include side bets on the outcome of military
campaigns, or the survival of parties to the contract (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 219-221)
21 (Schama, 1988, p. 350)
22 (French, 2006)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 7

years. Haarlem, one of the centers of the bulb trade, lost more than 20% in 1635 alone.23

In fact, several contemporary authors drew a causal link from the tulip craze to the

plague. The title of one pamphlet says it all: New Year’s Plague Mirror in which is on

display God’s Just Plague-Punishment, for the attention of the well-to-do Netherlanders

in this bold, rotten Century. The implication was that God was punishing the bulb

speculators for their limitless greed.24 Recent writers reverse the causal arrow: the ever-

present threat of a rapid death may well have inclined people towards taking greater

risks.25

As prices began to rise and new, less knowledgeable traders entered the market, three

new types of deals were introduced. First, transactions began to make explicit reference

to a bulb’s weight. The first recorded disputes to mention bulb weights concerned

contracts signed in the late summer of 1635.26 Bulb weights were expressed in “azen”,

with one “aas” equivalent to about 0.05 grams. Next, a lively trade developed in the

offsets of bulbs. For example, buyers would offer a certain price per aas for the largest

offset of a particular bulb. The total payment would be determined when the bulb was

dug up and its offsets examined and weighed.27 Finally, bulbs began to be sold in bulk,

by weight. The archives record many deals for 1000 azen of a particular variety —

23 (Noordegraaf & Valk, 1996, p. 54)

24 The title in Dutch is: Nieu-Iaers Pest-Spiegel waer in te sien is de Rechtveerdighe Pest-straffe Gods
voorghestelt tot opmerck der weeldige Neder-Landers in dese snoode bedurven Eeuwe. The pamphlet,
originally published in Haarlem, was sufficiently popular to be reprinted almost immediately in
neighbouring towns (Theuniszoon van der Lust, 1637).
25 (E.g. Garber, 2000, pp. 37-38; Goldgar, 2007, pp. 254-260)
26 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 17)
27 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 23, 29, 32)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 8

usually about 3-6 bulbs. Lesser-valued cultivars could also be traded by the pound,

roughly 30-60 bulbs.

This last innovation in particular fueled the speculative bubble. As the epigram

opening the paper indicates, contemporary observers recognized this too, and many

looked askance (partially out of envy) at those who traded primarily in so-called ‘pound

goods.’ Earlier contracts had always been linked to specific bulbs. However, a contract

for 1000 azen Gouda, for example, could be filled with any set of Gouda bulbs the seller

chose. With the link to specific bulbs severed, it became possible to engage in

transactions in which neither party had any idea about the eventual source of the bulbs.

Moreover, no real knowledge of either tulips or their bulbs was required, only a sense of

the going rate per aas for a particular tulip variety. Where prices had risen gradually but

steadily over the preceding years, the rise accelerated once these bulk contracts were

introduced into the market. Single-bulb prices appreciated faster too, but prices rose

fastest on the bulk contracts.

The elimination of the need to have one’s own bulb garden or even to be a

connoisseur of tulips, combined with the lure of quick and easy profits, drew new

entrants into the tulip market in growing numbers beginning in the fall of 1635. As new

entrants multiplied, transactions increasingly moved from the gardens and drawing rooms

of the most active collectors to regular, organized venues, usually at local inns. A system

of ‘colleges’ soon developed across the main towns of Holland. These colleges,

composed of a core of regular traders, met at a specific inn two or three times per week,

usually in the evening (most traders held on to their day jobs). Outsiders were welcome,

but needed to be introduced first. Most deals took places with the mediation of one or two
The Dutch Tulip Mania 9

“neutral” observers, and all sales were sealed with the payment of a small surcharge

called the “wijnkoop” (wine purchase/fee) of about 2.5%. These funds were spent

immediately by the members of the college in attendance, on food, drink and tobacco,

thus lubricating the deal-making. Wijnkoop monies also paid for lamps and a fire, as well

as tips for the serving girls. Even the poor were not forgotten, and some alms were set

aside.28 Prominent tulip collectors and growers regularly attended these colleges, and

some of the more successful traders in the colleges developed ties to a number of

collectors, further tightening the social networks within which all were embedded.29

The real speculative bubble did not last very long. Prices began to rise faster once the

bulbs had been planted in October 1636. Bulk contracts became increasingly common by

December 1636, giving the market a final boost. Peak prices were paid during the last

few days of January and first few days of February 1637. From the beginning of this

three-month period to the end, some individual bulbs were sold as many as 5-10 times,

and increased more than ten-fold in price, while bulk quantities of cheaper goods

increased as much as twenty-fold. A contemporary account notes that even varieties for

which there had been no demand previously because they were too common or plain now

were sold for large sums.30 Although disquiet about skyrocketing prices had been

building, the end still arrived suddenly and unexpectedly, with plummeting prices for

some of the most common pound goods in Haarlem on February 3rd. A public auction of

28 (Roman, 1637b, p. 5)
29 (Goldgar, 2007)
30 (Roman, 1637b, p. 24)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 10

choice bulbs in Alkmaar on February 5th garnered peak prices,31 but this was merely a

last hurrah.32 By February 7th, it had become clear throughout the main trading centers

that the market had crashed. I discuss the crisis and its resolution in more detail below.

First however, we need to establish that a bubble indeed took place, by taking a closer

look at the available data on bulb prices.

Data on Tulip Prices

Most tulip contracts were informal, and many were probably not even written down.

Those that were committed to paper were generally torn up once completed. Moreover,

there were no regular newspapers to cover the crisis as it unfolded: weekly newspapers

only emerged in most Holland towns in the 1660s. However, the tulip bubble fascinated

contemporary observers, who produced a wealth of — mostly critical — pamphlets,

which accordingly constitute one of the main sources of empirical data on tulip prices.33

Unfortunately, contemporary historiographers relied almost exclusively on these

pamphlets, even where access to the principals and other original documents would have

been feasible.34 Pamphlet authors were usually more interested in criticizing — or , in a

few case, defending — the bulb trade than in explaining it. As a result, most of the useful

31 (Lijste van Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637)

32 Though distances between Holland towns were not great, people did not travel frequently. As noted,
most bulb traders had other professions and traveling did take time away from their other pursuits. As a
result, the peak did not occur on the same day all across Holland (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 50-51)
33 (Krelage, 1942b; Posthumus, 1926)
34 (E.g. Aitzema, 1669-1672, p. 2313)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 11

specific information about the tulip mania we have today is drawn from a series of just

three pamphlets.

These pamphlets were published — and likely written —by Adriaen Roman in

Haarlem, between February and May 1637.35 Each is presented in the form of a dialogue

between two main characters, Gaergoedt (GreedyGoods) and Waermondt (Truemouth).

Gaergoedt is a well-to-do weaver who has been active as a bulb trader, and who

undertakes to educate Waermondt about the tulip market, in order to explain and defend

his actions. Waermondt, in response, offers moralistic tales intended to highlight the folly

of various aspects of the tulip mania. One of the most valuable features of these dialogues

is that they reproduce sample bulb sale contracts as well as data on the prices fetched for

particular bulbs near the beginning and towards the end of the bubble. There is little firm

corroboration for the data provided in these dialogues, and they can be shown to contain

some errors. Accordingly, no single price or weight can be considered entirely reliable.

Nevertheless, there is no reason to suspect any systematic distortion of the price

information, and most students of the tulip mania have accepted it as valid.36

Similar problems hamper the use of the sole other source of price data: complaints

and legal cases whose records survive in town archives. Few students of the tulip craze

have consulted these archives themselves: the only recent exceptions I am aware of are

35 (Roman, 1637a, 1637b, 1637c)


36 The dialogues are fictional, and their publisher/author does not pretend otherwise, which might lead us
to suspect all of the reported prices. Moreover, they have an agenda, which is to highlight the folly of
the tulip mania. However, no contemporary pamphlet authors challenged the data provided in these
dialogues, and some of the prices listed in the dialogues match those printed in a broadside reporting
the results of the Alkmaar auction of 5 Feb. 1637, at which some of the highest prices for any bulbs
were recorded (Lijste van Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637). Still, some of the prices in the dialogues are faulty
transcriptions from the Alkmaar auction. For example, example, a bulb of 171 azen that sold for 173
gulden is listed in the dialogue as weighing just 71 azen but selling for 175 gulden.
The Dutch Tulip Mania 12

Dash and Goldgar.37 Instead, most rely on the collection of transcriptions published

during the 1920s and 1930s by Posthumus.38 Unfortunately, Goldgar has found

Posthumus’ transcriptions to be “extremely sloppy” and riddled with errors.39 In other

words, no single piece of evidence is completely reliable here either. All in all, the

available price evidence is both thin and somewhat uncertain. We have about 400 price

points, the vast majority of which refer to peak prices only. About 65 data points provide

pre-peak prices, from before late January 1637. Of these, about 50 concern the three

month-period of the bubble from November through January. These 50 observations

reference 30 different varieties of tulips. On the far side of the peak, we have data on only

about 5 transactions for the remainder of 1637 and the first part of 1638. We do,

however, have a few general statements in the third dialogue about the drastic drop in

value after the crash.

Writers on the tulip mania have adopted different strategies to overcome the difficulty

of drawing solid conclusions based on such limited data. The simplest tactic is to rely

heavily on the hyperbole found in the pamphlets. For example, the post-script to the first

dialogue between Gaergoedt and Waermondt claims that “some goods ran so high that

one or two guldens became one hundred, sometimes more.”40 If true, this would be strong

evidence for a bubble. However, the prices listed in the dialogues — which are explicitly

intended to illustrate the dramatic nature of the price increases observed — do not

37 (Dash, 1999; Goldgar, 2007)


38 (Posthumus, 1927, 1934)
39 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 328-329, fn. 329)
40 (Roman, 1637b, p. 23)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 13

support this claim, and only the most superficial treatments of the tulip mania take it

seriously.

A more promising approach is to interpolate based on the available data, as Garber

does.41 Garber generates 16 charts showing the price evolution of different tulip varieties

by connecting observations in a straight line. However, each chart has only a few data

points: three of them have only an initial and a final price. While the charts demonstrate

that prices rose a lot, they cannot be used to draw any conclusions about the price

trajectory between the individual observations. Simply imposing a straight line

contradicts all contemporary accounts, which indicate a gradual increase at first, with a

far steeper slope near the end of the bubble.

Garber’s data on the other side of the peak suffer the same flaw. As noted earlier, we

have very little data from the period immediately following the bubble. Garber, therefore,

is forced to rely on prices from a sale in 1642/43. All one can do with such data is

calculate average annual depreciation; they say nothing about the actual shape of the

price curve. Nevertheless, Garber concludes that “the crash of February 1637 for rare

bulbs was not of extraordinary magnitude” simply by assuming a linear price decline for

the period between the end of the crash and 1642.42 However, if we trust the peak price

data offered in the dialogues — as Garber does — we must also take seriously the

evidence they provide on the values of bulbs after the crash. Gaergoedt notes that it is

hard to estimate price levels “since there is no demand for bulbs; everybody is silent.”

Nevertheless, he records that a garden filled with common varieties of tulips brought only

41 (Garber, 1989, 2000)


42 (Garber, 2000, p. 70)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 14

about one hundredth of the price it might have fetched at the peak. More importantly for

our purposes, a sale of several individual bulbs only fetched about 22 gulden each,

whereas Gaergoedt suggests they might have been worth 400 gulden at their peak.43 This

implies that prices of individual bulbs fell by as much as 95% within a few months,

invalidating Garber’s assumption of a steady, linear drop in prices over the course of the

six subsequent years. Garber does acknowledge the price surge and decline in the more

common bulbs, sold in bulk, but waves away the problem by blaming it on the lack of

regulation of contracts within the colleges.44 I address this argument in more detail

below.

Interpolating from one observation to the next would be less problematic if we had

more data points, with less time elapsing from one to the next. This might be possible if

we could generate an index of relative prices that permits comparisons across different

tulip varieties. Thompson’s argument about the price developments in the tulip market

relies on the validity of such an index.45 However, Thompson fails to address some fatal

problems with this approach. First, an index must be based on price observations taken at

the same point in time, but Thompson derives his baseline from a book of tulip paintings

for which neither the source nor the date of the prices listed are known.46 Second, not all

bulb sales are directly comparable. Transactions may involve offsets, bulbs, or bulbs in

43 (Roman, 1637a, p. 12). Among these latter bulbs was a Gheel ende Root van Leyden. At the height of
the bubble, a large bulb of this variety was sold for 550 gulden, so an estimated value of 400 gulden for
a single bulb is not unreasonable (Lijste van Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637)

44 (Garber, 2000, p. 81)


45 (Thompson, 2006)

46 A number of the prices derive from the February 5th auction, but most do not. The book has been
digitized and can be seen at http://library.wur.nl/tulips/blauw_content.html (accessed 15 February
2009).
The Dutch Tulip Mania 15

bulk; the value per aas is not the same across these three transaction types, with bulk

goods worth the least and offsets the most. Nor does the value of a bulb increase linearly

with its weight.47 The third problem, fatal all by itself, is that an index can only be used to

compare prices for different varieties at different points in time if we assume, against all

the available evidence, that the shape of the price curve over time is identical for every

tulip variety, so that relative prices remain constant.48

In sum, neither Garber’s nor Thompson’s attempts to explain away the tulip bubble

can be sustained by the available data. Arguing that price fluctuations did not exceed

those supported by market fundamentals, as Garber does, requires ignoring key points of

evidence from the post-crash period, as well as assuming that prices increased and

decreased linearly prior to and after the peak, an assumption contradicted by every

contemporary account. Making more precise claims about the timing of particular aspects

of the bubble, as Thompson does, requires ignoring the problems inherent in aggregating

price information for bulbs of different weights and varieties at different points in time,

as well as placing complete faith in the accuracy of each individual price observation.

Though the data are limited, they quite clearly indicate a rapid rise in prices, accelerating

through December 1636 and January 1637, followed by a steep and sudden decline after

the first week of February. Contemporary pamphlets unanimously support this picture.

47 The results of the February 5th auction suggest that a doubling in weight is associated with a ≈50%
increase in price. Garber ignores this problem too (Garber, 2000, p. ch. 8)

48 To give just one example, the Gouda had doubled in price before the Oudenaerde began increasing
rapidly in price, while the Switser did not really start gaining in value until three weeks later still. If we
have only one pre-peak price for a bulb, there is no way to know where on its price curve to locate it —
has it already gained most of its value, or is the steepest rise still to come? Relative prices across
different bulbs changed day by day.
The Dutch Tulip Mania 16

Social and Informational Features of the Bubble

How, then, can we explain this bubble? In this section, I argue that the key to the

explanation lies in the dense social networks and strong social norms within which

commerce in Holland was embedded at the time. Efficient market models — of the kind

proposed by both Garber and Thompson — assume that those who bought and sold rare

and bulk bulbs used their own private knowledge about the fundamental supply of and

demand for various bulbs. Prices might rise while increases in fundamental (non-

speculative) demand exceeded increases in supply, but they would be kept under control.

Bulb traders would begin selling once prices threatened to deviate from underlying

fundamentals. As we have seen, however, in the winter of 1636/37 people behaved

differently. Still, the bubble did not develop because the traders’ private knowledge about

the actual supply of particular bulbs was faulty. As we shall see, the market was quite

localized, and those active in the trade were familiar with the gardens where the tulips

were planted and with the tulips themselves.

The key factor, instead, was the social connectedness among tulip traders, who were

linked to one another by religion, by marriage, by trade, etc. As a result, market

participants assigned a greater weight to the decisions of other traders than they would

have if they had interacted only through the arms-length transactions of the market.49

Aggregated across the entire market, these decisions came to outweigh the influence of

private knowledge, setting the bubble in motion. The tulip bubble thus emerged as the

49 (Cf. Uzzi, 1999)


The Dutch Tulip Mania 17

result of an information cascade.50 The basic insight associated with such cascades is

individuals may rationally ignore their own private information and be guided by the

decisions of others. Applied to markets this means that people may rationally ignore their

own knowledge about the demand for or supply of a particular good. Crucially, this also

implies that lack of knowledge need not be an impediment to a rational actor’s entrance

into a market.

In an elegant application of an information transmission model to investment bubbles,

Hong, Scheinkman, and Xiong show how a bubble can emerge in a situation where

technological innovation has rendered the knowledge of some advisors much less

valuable.51 Those advisors who do understand the innovation have an incentive to signal

their type by inflating their forecasts so as to stand out from those whose advice is now

less valuable. If there are many naïve investors who accept any forecast at face value, a

bubble readily emerges. The mechanism I propose here is similar in many respects. The

crucial difference is that investors and advisors are not separate groups. This changes

some of the basic dynamics and makes the social connections among the actors rather

more significant.

In his earlier work on the science of social networks, Watts suggests that a densely

connected network may be resistant to information cascades, since “the more people

whose actions or opinions you take into account before making a decision, the less

influence any one of them will have.”52 The idea is that all individuals are “locally stable”

50 (Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, & Welch, 1992)


51 (Hong, Scheinkman, & Xiong, 2008; cf. Nairn, 2002)
52 (Watts, 2003, p. 240)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 18

and hence no shock, however large, to a single node in the network is likely to result in

any kind of cascade. However, that conclusion only applies if all members of the network

can be observed at once. If members of the network act in small groups, the potential

stabilizing influence of the rest of the network largely disappears. In fact, in subsequent

research, Watts has found that cascades are made possible by “the presence… of a critical

mass of easily influenced people, each of whom adopts… after being exposed to a single

adopting neighbor.”53 As we shall see, the tulip bubble contains features of both of these

scenarios. The overall connectedness of the social network actually made things less,

rather than more, stable; and a small-group setting made it unnecessary for people to be

so naïve that exposure to just a single neighbor drove their decisions.

The social logic behind the tulip bubble can be illustrated by way of analogy to the art

auction market. Art dealer X, who has bought and sold art at major auctions for years,

will know most of the other active art dealers — especially the local ones — and will

have come to trust their knowledge and judgment. Imagine that a piece of art outside X’s

area of expertise has caught her eye. She would like to acquire it, but does not wish to

pay more than the work is worth. Three possible strategies readily suggest themselves: 1)

research the value of the piece, thus acquiring sufficient private knowledge to judge

value; 2) see how much her colleagues have recently bid on comparable pieces; and 3)

simply outbid any of her colleagues whose judgment she trusts, but stop bidding if an

unknown person drives up the bid further. No strategy can eliminate all uncertainty: no

two pieces of art are exactly alike, and even art experts are not always sure how much a

work of art might fetch on the open market. Hence, strategy 1 may not be worth pursuing,

53 (Watts, 2007)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 19

since it is not guaranteed to repay the considerable costs involved in acquiring sufficient

knowledge, especially compared to the far more modest costs associated with strategies 2

or 3. This implies that the adoption of strategies 2 or 3 may be rational, even if X

recognizes that these strategies are far riskier.

The risk associated with strategy 3 is the most obvious. If art buyers X and Y each

trust the knowledge and judgment of the other, they may end up in a bidding contest well

beyond the “fundamental” value of the piece, up to a point where the price reaches a level

that even the imperfect knowledge of either X or Y tells her that it is not worth that much.

At this point, she will stop bidding, leaving the other to pay far too much. The risks with

strategy 2 are less obvious but no less severe. The strategy will work well if bids made in

the recent past on similar pieces by other dealers were based on private knowledge, i.e.

on strategy 1. However, if they were based on strategies 2 or 3, the actions of X will

simply reinforce the misvaluation, and help generate an information cascade. It is easy to

see how the social context — art dealers who know and trust one another — makes such

outcomes far more likely than if nobody trusted the knowledge and judgment of her

colleagues. After all, the less one’s confidence in one’s fellow dealers, the greater is the

incentive to acquire adequate private knowledge.

Now imagine novice art dealers X1 through Xn who, one after the other, decide to get

involved in the market, attracted by the lure of easy money, or because their disposable

incomes has risen considerably in recent times. They can begin purchasing art most easily

by adopting strategies 2 and 3 exclusively. However, doing so reduces the fraction of the

auction participants with private knowledge. As a result, for each successive

collector/dealer that enters the market in this manner, there is a smaller likelihood that a
The Dutch Tulip Mania 20

randomly chosen auction participant has valuable private knowledge. Nevertheless, it

may continue to be rational for each new entrant not to invest resources in acquiring

private knowledge. Finally, the rising prices that result from such an information cascade

will attract additional works of art to the auction house. This further reduces the

comparative value of the private information of dealers who have been active longer,

because their knowledge of the total supply will be less complete.

Translating this basic model to the Dutch tulip mania is relatively straightforward. In

what follows, I first characterize the market by discussing the supply of bulbs, the nature

of tulip sale contracts and the community of tulip traders. Next I apply the basic logic

presented in the preceding paragraphs to the case of the tulip bubble. I show that the

bubble logically emerged from a combination of two factors: an innovation in the market

— bulbs sold in bulb, by total weight — and the entry of new traders embedded

alongside existing bulb lovers in a densely connected social network. A brief discussion

of the aftermath of the bubble underscores the key role played by these two factors. As

noted earlier, a number of facilitating factors were undeniably present: the Dutch were

comfortable with speculation, the plague may have made them more risk-acceptant, tulip

trading was rarely the sole source of income for the participants, and no guild existed to

impose strict regulations and penalties. But without the tight social network

encompassing all traders and the introduction of a new type of bulb contracts, we would

not have seen a bubble.

The supply of bulbs was comparatively fixed; it increased through the growth of

offsets, but these took several years to become full-grown bulbs capable of flowering and

creating their own offsets. With the newest varieties often in greatest demand, growers in
The Dutch Tulip Mania 21

possession of such bulbs could be fairly certain of controlling the market for a few years.

The rapid expansion of the professional and merchant class within the towns of Holland

meant that demand easily kept pace with the development of new varieties. With demand

growing faster than supply, as it did starting in the early 1630s, it is no surprise that

prices rose, or that a market emerged for lower-quality bulbs too. Not surprisingly, rising

prices attracted others to the market, and made existing bulb traders more enthusiastic.

Eventually, however, supply was bound to outstrip demand: the bulb supply could

grow faster than did that of wealthy burghers, and there was a limit to the number of

recognizably different varieties that could be developed. Prices would, therefore

inevitably fall in the medium term. This, in essence, is the story told by Garber, and it

adequately explains both the rise in prices up to the summer of 1636 and the gradual

decline that appears to have set in once the crash had been sorted out by the late summer

of 1637. As we have seen, however, it cannot account for the dramatic increase in the

prices not just of the bulk goods, but also of the rarest bulbs, in the fall and winter of

1636-1637. Nor does it explain the crash that followed.

Most tulip sales followed a standard format. Transactions in the colleges were

conducted in a ritualized fashion, with separate procedures for sales and purchases, and

were confirmed with the payment of the “wijnkoop” fee.54 As Schama notes, “what is

actually striking about the popular-speculative phase of the tulip mania is how quickly it

54 The procedures are described in (Roman, 1637c, p. 23) and (Roman, 1637b, pp. 4-5), respectively.
Sales were open to multiple bidders and were done in an auction format, whereas purchases were
conducted as bilateral negotiations in which buyers and sellers tried to find a mutually acceptable
middle ground. Detailed explanations can be found in (Krelage, 1942a, pp. 70-73). In addition to
entering the sale in the college’s ledger, both sides to a transaction often wrote out a small sales note,
or enter the text in their own ledgers. The second dialogue between Gaergoedt and Waermondt gives
some examples of the latter (Roman, 1637c, p. 14).
The Dutch Tulip Mania 22

improvised highly ritualized and formal conventions in which to conduct its trade.”55 The

sales agreement provided for simultaneous payment and delivery only at the moment a

bulb was dug up, with the opportunity to verify the flower beforehand.56 Deals struck

outside the blooming period therefore always involved some features of a futures

transaction. Deals were usually recorded in a ledger, either that of a notary or that of one

of the colleges.

Even with the norms governing the manner of buying and selling, uncertainties

remained: buyers worried about the quality of the bulbs they were buying, while sellers

worried about being paid in full. As a result, contracts themselves were subject to norms

too. A standard, but implicit, feature of sales contracts was that when a bulb turned out to

be of a different variety than promised, the sale was nullified, and the seller did not have

to accept it.57 To reassure the seller, a system of “borgen” — guarantors of payment —

emerged, in which one or two friends or relatives of the buyer would guarantee payment

if the buyer could not or would not pay. In addition, buyers often explicitly pledged their

assets. A sample contract listed in the second dialogue — and described as being

representative of almost all such contracts — states: “in case of non-payment of the

aforementioned sum, I hereby pledge all my goods, movable and immovable, placing

them under the control of all the laws and courts.”58 Such language makes it hard to

sustain either Garber’s claim that these deals were the outcome of “a meaningless winter

drinking game” with insufficient “internal control over the nature of contracts” or

55 (Schama, 1988, p. 359)


56 (Cf. Goldgar, 2007, p. 241)
57 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 85)
58 (Roman, 1637c, p. 15)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 23

Thompson’s odd assertion that traders all intuited in December 1636 that the nature of

tulip contracts had suddenly but fundamentally changed.59

Though some trading in bulbs took place among towns and even across borders, there

was virtually no systematic cultivation of bulbs for trade during the tulip mania; most

growers were aficionados working in their own small gardens.60 Notarized complaints

make clear that the main participants regularly visited the various gardens around town in

which tulips were planted, and hence were quite knowledgeable about the locally

available supply of particular varieties, and even the quality of individual bulbs.61 The

picture that emerges is one of mostly local markets within individual towns. Complaints

still on file in the Dutch archives reinforce this impression: most recount disputes

between traders from the same town, who all knew one another quite well.

In addition, the total number of active participants in the tulip market appears to have

been comparatively small, ranging from several dozen in the smaller towns such as

Enkhuizen or Hoorn to several hundred in Haarlem.62 More than one merchant appears

just once in the archival record, purchasing or selling just a single bulb from or for his

garden, so the number of regular traders was smaller still. In fact, the first dialogue notes

59 (Garber, 2000, p. 81; Thompson, 2006)

60 (Krelage, 1942a, p. 69). Bulb exports only began to take off in the second half of the seventeenth
century, after the tulip mania had ended. Even then, Krelage notes, only a few growers aimed at the
export market, and quantities were small — most foreign buyers were just interested in a single bulb of
a particular variety (Krelage, 1942a, p. 102; see also Krelage, 1946, pp. 7-8,269-275)

61 (E.g. Posthumus, 1927, p. 16). A contract dispute describes how a Haarlem baker who was interested
in buying a bulb from a local merchant in one college visited another college within town and received
additional information about that same bulb. This indicates just how small and well-informed the
market was (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 27-28)

62 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 137)


The Dutch Tulip Mania 24

that new participants in the colleges attracted immediate notice.63 Significantly, most of

those active in the tulip trade in a given town were closely connected through several

different networks. Many were related by blood or by marriage, a disproportionate

number were Mennonites, and a considerable number appear to have engaged in mutual

business transactions unrelated to the tulip trade.64 These close ties further facilitated the

rapid dissemination of information among traders, but they may also have given new

traders an inflated sense of the expertise of their peers.

The fact that most of the bulb trade was localized, and that it appears not to have

spread much beyond a about a dozen Dutch towns, helps explain why the end of the tulip

mania had only a minor impact on the rest of the Dutch economy.65 In fact, though there

is some disagreement among historians about rates of growth in the Dutch economy

during this period, nobody seriously suggests that the tulip mania had a sizeable impact

on its fortunes.66 The collapse of the tulip bubble even failed to cause much local

economic dislocation. Almost all tulip traders had other careers — they were merchants,

successful artisans, or professionals — and most were comparatively wealthy. A few of

the poorer tulip speculators may have faced economic ruin, but most of the active bulb

63 (Roman, 1637b, p. 4)

64 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 146-149)


65 Claims to the contrary in the literature are largely due to uncritical copying from Mackay’s
sensationalist account, which declares that “the commerce of the country suffered a severe shock, from
which it was many years ere it recovered (Mackay, 1932 [1852], p. 97).”

66 (E.g. de Vries & van der Woude, 1997, pp. 150-151; Israel, 1995, p. 533)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 25

traders remained quite prosperous in the late 1630s, despite losing all of their paper

profits from the bubble.67

The tulip market functioned efficiently as long as two conditions were met: the

traders all knew one another as fellow tulip aficionados, and they all had ample private

information about the market, i.e. about the supply and quality of individual bulbs. As we

have seen, the first of these conditions probably applied until 1635, and the second until

1636. When novice traders entered the market, it became less stable, because this

produced a drop in the average amount of expertise. Once a number of new traders had

entered the market, it became increasingly difficult to distinguish those with solid private

knowledge from those who were simply following the crowd. The final straw was the

introduction of bulk sales. As noted earlier, these constituted a new kind of trade, no

longer linked to individual bulbs. This meant that the private knowledge of established

bulb lovers was suddenly much less relevant.

Returning to the art auction analogy, it was as though it had become possible to buy

and sell a piece of art to be named later by the seller, and even for the seller to import that

piece from elsewhere. Pamphlets and town records alike suggest that the established tulip

traders were not initially active in this new trade, implying that prices were determined

almost exclusively by traders playing strategies 2 and 3 from our art auction example,

with the latter dominant initially. The bubble which followed inevitably spread to the rare

bulb trade. After all, the two trades were linked: new traders were also interested in the

67 (Goldgar, 2007, pp. 166-167, 247-169). Though many accounts of the bubble suggest that people from
all walks of life were involved, these claims appear to derive from some hyperbole in the first dialogue
between Gaergoedt and Waermondt, where the latter claims that “daughters and maids, farmers and
noblemen, even letter carriers… [and] chimney-sweeps” had entered the speculation (Roman, 1637b,
p. 18)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 26

rare bulbs, and rare bulb buyers were not immune to the lure of profits from the faster-

rising prices of bulk sales. Moreover, a number of bulb lovers may have convinced

themselves that they understood the market better than the latest entrants — that their

private knowledge of individual bulbs had some value in this context too.

In the end, it probably did. Prices could rise considerably as long as bulb traders —

new entrants as well as established tulip lovers — continued to play strategies 2 and 3.

Traders could rationalize rising prices by assuming that all new entrants in the market

wanted bulbs to plant rather than merely for speculation — in other words, that

“fundamental” demand had increased several times over. Moreover, (paper) profits made

from trading bulk goods could be used to bid higher sums for prized individual bulbs. But

there were limits to the price increases one could rationalize for either rare bulbs or bulk

goods. For bulk goods, bulb traders who had been active for some years knew how long

these varieties had been around, and how easily additional supplies could be found, not

just in Holland, but also abroad. At some point, rising prices in Holland would inevitably

begin to attract tulips from France or Germany.

Most of the rare bulbs, in contrast, were new varieties, for which the supply was

inelastic. Moreover, all established bulb traders knew who owned those bulbs. Here, the

built-in limit was the price beyond which even the wealthiest merchants would not be

interested in acquiring a bulb. That such a limit existed was clear from the beginning:

even at the height of its desirability, for example, the famous Semper Augustus had never

fetched prices that were beyond the reach of most bulb lovers — they simply did not wish

to own it at all costs. Since private knowledge was more significant in rare bulb trades,

this bubble did not expand as far. In turn, this implied that the bursting of the bubble
The Dutch Tulip Mania 27

would lead to less of a price collapse. The limited price data we have suggest that this is

exactly what happened. Prices for pound goods could rise further because private

knowledge mattered less: there was more uncertainty both about local supplies and about

the price level that would attract imports.

In the end, the bubble reached its limit first for the so-called pound goods. By the end

of 1636 numerous outsiders were already predicting an imminent crash.68 As January

progressed, and prices rose ever faster, traders, too, began to fear that prices might be

unsustainable.69 Moreover, the dense social networks joining all tulip traders guaranteed

that such fears were common knowledge. Things went sour in Haarlem first, on February

3rd. Waermondt, in the first dialogue, recounts the episode.70 Members of a college

decided to test market confidence by putting up for sale amongst themselves bulk

quantities of common tulips — Switsers or Croonen. Just one buyer made any bids in

three successive sales, and each of the sellers accepted his offer, even though the sum he

offered was successively 15% below, 25% below, and finally 35% below recent prices

for comparable bulbs. News of this precipitous drop in prices spread like wildfire

throughout town, and the next day trading came to a complete halt, with traders simply

staring at one another in stunned silence.71

Still, the bubble had not burst completely, or at least not everywhere. Two days later,

at an auction in Alkmaar — only about 20 miles north of Haarlem — peak prices were

reached for many individual bulbs, as well as for numerous varieties sold in 1000 aas

68 (E.g. Theuniszoon van der Lust, 1637)


69 (Krelage, 1942a, p. 80)
70 (Roman, 1637b, p. 17)
71 (Roman, 1637b, p. 17)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 28

quantities. However, that the prices fetched by the pound goods on offer did not appear in

the broadside was published to advertise the auction results.72 It seems plausible that

these prices had already been affected by collapse of the market in Haarlem. By this

point, moreover, news of the latter had spread to other towns, and bulb traders

everywhere were girding for the crash. The first recorded evidence of a response on the

part of the traders was a Feb 7th meeting in Utrecht to decide which representatives to

send to a meeting to be held in Amsterdam on February 23rd of the trading colleges

throughout Holland.

That Amsterdam meeting included representatives not only from Amsterdam and

Utrecht, but also from Haarlem, Leiden, Delft, Gouda, Alkmaar, Enkhuizen, Medemblik,

Hoorn, and De Streek.73 In the event, it proved impossible to arrive at a jointly acceptable

solution. The final proposal was to honor all contracts signed through November 30,

1636. All those signed December 1st or later, however, would be canceled if the buyer

announced by March 1637 that he wished to cancel the contract, and paid a buyout fee

(“roucoop,” i.e. regret fee) of 10% of the agreed purchase price. In the latter case, the

seller would retain ownership of the bulbs.74

Local authorities did not feel bound to sign on to the solution proposed by the

colleges. On March 7, Haarlem officials announced they were inclined to annul all

contracts signed since the bulbs had been planted in September or October.75 Similarly,

72 (Lijste van Eenighe Tulpaen, 1637)

73 The tulip colleges of Rotterdam did not send delegates, but announced ahead of time that they would
abide by any solution arrived at during the meeting.
74 (Barckman, 1637)
75 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 51)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 29

the regents of Hoorn instructed their representatives in the States General of Holland to

propose annulling all contracts, to avoid bankrupting buyers who had agreed to high-

priced deals.76 The Alkmaar authorities, on the other hand, recommended on March 14

that all contracts be upheld, and encouraged their deputies the States assembly to

convince the Haarlem representatives to change their mind.77 By early April, they appear

to have succeeded, as the Haarlem authorities now suggested that contracts agreed to in

the colleges ought to be upheld.78 Overall, it is clear that local regulation, which had

played no role during the bubble, was not going to have much of an impact on its

resolution either.

Some looked to the provincial authorities for resolution instead. The States finally

agreed to address the issue on April 11th.79 A few days later the Haarlem officials had

changed their mind again, and sent a missive supporting their colleagues from Hoorn in

the effort to have all contracts nullified. They argued that the bulb trade had involved

“purely imaginary value” and hence was noting more than “empty commerce, tending to

divert people and resources from other honest and necessary trades”. Of equal

importance, they emphasized that annulling contracts “would not only preserve many

hundreds of persons of good name and reputation from ruin and scandal”, but also would

not involve anybody outside these circles, thus preserving peace and tranquility.80 The

implication that the crisis was both localized and limited is clear.

76 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 52)


77 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 236)
78 (Dash, 1999, p. 182)
79 (Posthumus, 1927, p. 53)

80 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 57-58)


The Dutch Tulip Mania 30

On April 25th the Court of Holland recommended that the States pursue further

inquiries into to the origin and starting date of the bubble, as well as of the sudden price

collapse. Pending a final decision by the States, all contracts were to remain valid, and

the town authorities were to do their best to mediate and negotiate contract disputes.

Although contracts were to remain in force, the Court recommended a moratorium on any

official enforcement of contracts. Two days later, the States of Holland adopted the

Court’s recommendation verbatim.81 Numerous towns took the moratorium to mean that

they should not allow their officers to intervene on behalf of one party or another to a

dispute by issuing writs, summons, etc., and passed decrees to this effect.82

In the absence of government involvement, bulb traders were forced to resolve

contract disputes amongst themselves, as they had been attempting to do all along. The

first record of a sales contract canceled by mutual consent dates to February 10th. The

seller accepted a buy-out payment of 160 gulden for a contract that had been worth 1800

gulden.83 Many contract disputes were, in fact, settled more or less amicably. Some

contracts already contained buyout clauses, often specifying a penalty payment of 10% of

the purchase price.84 For those that did not, traders arrived at their own figures, which

were typically lower. One notary certified that buyout rates ranged from 1-5%, with

plenty of buyers in default refusing to make any payment at all.85

81 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 58-60)


82 (Dash, 1999, p. 188; Posthumus, 1927, p. 61)
83 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 45-46)
84 (Munting, 1696, p. 911)
85 (Posthumus, 1927, pp. 70-71)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 31

Many cases appear to have turned on the principle of honoring contracts, rather than

on the sums involved, which were often quite modest compared to each party’s assets.

What appears to have disturbed those involved in complaints most was the breach of

social norms implied by the refusal to abide by a contract. Here, once again, we see the

importance of the social network within which the tulip traded had been embedded. The

bursting of the bubble was not much of an economic threat, but it did pose a threat to the

strength of the social network. Since the commercial success of the Dutch merchant class

relied heavily on social network ties, such a threat could have serious wider implications.

As Goldgar notes, “the tulip crash struck at the heart of a commercial society that by

necessity relied on reputation and mutual credit.” Moreover, reputation and trust were

particularly important in commercial interactions with high levels of uncertainty — not

just tulips, but also the highly profitable exploitation of the East and West Indies. As a

result, “It was this social anxiety, this sense of not having the measure of others, that was

most frightening for contemporaries.”86 While broken contracts were nothing new, they

had always been the exception. In the aftermath of the tulip bubble, they briefly became

the rule, and that was deeply disconcerting.87

Conclusion

The Dutch tulip mania of 1636-1637 clearly qualifies as a bubble, in the sense that

prices were not sustained by private estimations of value. Claims that market

fundamentals explain the observed price patterns cannot be sustained, despite their

86 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 267)


87 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 294; cf. Krelage, 1942a, p. 101)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 32

popularity in recent years. Nor do arguments about inadequate government regulation

offer much explanatory leverage. Authorities remained largely uninvolved in the bubble

— although the States did consider taxing tulip profits in 1636-1637 — and they mostly

refused to be drawn into the adjudication of individual cases, at least until a year later.88

However, this does not mean that there was no regulation: the market was regulated by

the rituals and norms that developed around the tulip trade, as well as by the broader

social connections within which it was embedded.

The social network that made the bubble possible also was the strongest promoter of

amicable resolutions. As we have seen, contemporary observers often blamed the

problems on a few speculators in pound goods. However, while such speculators clearly

existed, what made them influential was that socially they were almost indistinguishable

from tulip traders of long standing. Despite what the epigram at the start of this paper

suggests, they could not be neatly separated from such “true” bulb lovers. In the end, it

was the very strength of the social network that tied all bulb traders together, new and old

alike, that made the bubble possible.

All this suggests that the tulip mania deserves to retain its position as a classic

financial bubble. However, it also indicates that the lessons to be drawn from the bubble

are less about a spectacular rise in prices followed by a collapse, and more about the

social structures within which the market is embedded. The collapse of Bernard Madoff’s

investment empire has led many to highlight to the importance of the social connections

that made investors forego due diligence.89 However, similar problems also arose in the

88 (Goldgar, 2007, p. 224; Posthumus, 1927, pp. 80-81)


89 (E.g. Schweitzer & Shell, 2009)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 33

much more extensive subprime mortgage market, as Lewis shows in his analysis of the

current crisis. Much of his story centers around the degree to which the collapse of the

subprime mortgage edifice was inevitable, foreseeable, and indeed foreseen by some. The

message is that those who continued to invest in subprime mortgages and the various

derivates thereof were simply stupid.90

However, one of the key components in the argument is that Moody’s, the rating

company, misvalued collateralized debt obligations constructed from the weakest part of

the mortgage market. Many other actors in the market trusted Moody’s because they had

been working with Moody’s for a long time and had come to trust its judgment.91 Indeed,

the current crisis reinforces a central lesson from the tulip bubble: the dangers associated

with a relatively small number of key players embedded in a social network that has

developed over a longer period of time, producing network connections in which trust

and judgment have become dissociated from the specific arena in which they developed.

People trusted Moody’s not because they were experts on subprime mortgages, but

because their judgment had proven reliable in other fields. The tulip bubble continues to

be relevant, then, not because it shows that there have always been people willing to pay

many times what something is fundamentally worth, but because it demonstrates that

such people tend to be social fools rather than economic idiots.

90 (Lewis, 2008)
91 (Lewis, 2008)
The Dutch Tulip Mania 34

References

Aitzema, L. v. (1669-1672). Saken van Staet en Oorlogh. 's Gravenhage, NL: Johan
Veely, Johan Tongerloo, and Jasper Doll.
Barckman, P. (1637). Copye van een notoriael accoordt, ghemaeckt tusschen de
Gecommitteerde der Floristen van verscheyde Steden. Amsterdam, NL.
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welch, I. (1992). A Theory of Fads, Fashion,
Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades. Journal of Political
Economy, 100(5), 992-1026.
Dash, M. (1999). Tulipomania: The Story of the World's Most Coveted Flower and the
Extraordinary Passions It Aroused. New York, NY: Crown Publishers.
De verstoorde en noyt gestorven flora. (1637).
de Vries, J., & van der Woude, A. (1997). The First Modern Economy: Success, failure,
and perseverance of the Dutch economy, 1500-1815. New York, NY: Cambridge
University Press.
French, D. (2006). The Dutch Monetary Environment during Tulipmania. Quarterly
Journal of Austrian Economics, 9(1), 3-14.
Garber, P. M. (1989). Tulipmania. Journal of Political Economy, 97(3), 535-560.
Garber, P. M. (2000). Famous First bubbles: The Fundamentals of Early Manias.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Goldgar, A. (2007). Tulipmania: Money, Honor, and Knowledge in the Dutch Golden
Age. Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.
Hong, H., Scheinkman, J., & Xiong, W. (2008). Advisors and Asset Prices: A Model of
the Origins of Bubbles. Journal of Financial Economics, 89, 268-287.
Israel, J. I. (1995). The Dutch Republic: Its Rise, Greatness, and Fall. Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press.
Kindleberger, C. P., & Aliber, R. Z. (2005). Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of
Financial Crises (5th ed.). Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.
Krelage, E. H. (1942a). Bloemenspeculatie in Nederland: De Tulpomanie van 1636-'37
en de Hyacintenhandel 1720-'36. Amsterdam, NL: P.N. van Kampen & Zoon.
The Dutch Tulip Mania 35

Krelage, E. H. (1942b). De pamfletten van den tulpenwindhandel, 1636-1637. 's


Gravenhage, NL: Martinus Nijhoff.
Krelage, E. H. (1946). Drie eeuwen bloembollenexport: De geschiedenis van den
bloembollenhandel en der Hollandsche bloembollen tot 1938. 's Gravenhage, NL:
Rijksuitgeverij.
Lewis, M. (2008). The End. Condé Nast Portfolio(December).
Lijste van Eenighe Tulpaen Verkocht aende meest-biedende op den 5. Februari 1637.
(1637). Alkmaar, NL.
Mackay, C. (1932 [1852]). Memoirs of Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the
Madness of Crowds. New York, NY: L.C. Page & Company.
Moggach, D. (1999). Tulip Fever. London, UK: Heinemann.
Munting, A. (1696). Naauwkeurige Beschryving der Aardgewassen. Leyden / Utrecht,
NL: Pieter vander Aa / François Halma.
Nairn, A. G. M. (2002). Engines That Move Markets: Technology Investing from
Railroads to the Internet and Beyond. New York, NY: Wiley-Academy.
Nocera, J. (2008, October 10). Swept Up by Insanity of Markets. New York Times,
Noordegraaf, L., & Valk, G. (1996). De gave Gods: De pest in Holland vanaf de late
middeleeuwen. Amsterdam, NL: Bert Bakker.
Posthumus, N. W. (1926). De speculatie in tulpen in de jaren 1636 en 1637. Economisch-
Historisch Jaarboek, 12, 3-99.
Posthumus, N. W. (1927). De speculatie in tulpen in de jaren 1636 en 1637 (II).
Economisch-Historisch Jaarboek, 13, 1-85.
Posthumus, N. W. (1934). De speculatie in tulpen in de jaren 1636 en 1637 (III).
Economisch-Historisch Jaarboek, 18, 229-240.
Roman, A. (1637a). Register van de Prijsen der Bloemen Zijnde de Derde Samen-
spraeck Tusschen Gaergoed ende Waermond, Inhoudende het Vervolgh van den
op ende ondergangh van Flora. Haarlem, NL: Adriaen Roman.
Roman, A. (1637b). Samen-spraeck Tusschen Waermondt Ende Gaergoedt, Nopende de
Opkomste ende Ondergangh van Flora. Haarlem, NL: Adriaen Roman.
The Dutch Tulip Mania 36

Roman, A. (1637c). Tweede Samen-spraeck Tusschen Waermondt Ende Gaergoedt,


Zijnde het Vervolgh van den op ende ondergangh van Flora. Haarlem, NL:
Adriaen Roman.
Schama, S. (1988). The Embarrassment of Riches: An Interpretation of Dutch Culture in
the Golden Age. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Schweitzer, M. E., & Shell, G. R. (2009). The Bernard Madoff Case: Trust Takes
Another Blow [Electronic Version]. Knowledge@Wharton,
Shiller, R. J. (2000). Irrational Exuberance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Theuniszoon van der Lust, S. (1637). Nieu-Iaers Pest-Spiegel waer in te sien is de
Rechtveerdighe Pest-straffe Gods voorghestelt tot opmerck der weeldige Neder-
Landers in dese snoode bedurven Eeuwe. Hoorn, NL: Zacharias Cornelisz.
Thompson, E. A. (2006). The Tulipmania: Fact or Artifact. Public Choice, 130, 99-114.
Uzzi, B. (1999). Embeddedness in the Making of Financial Capital: How Social
Relations and Networks Benefit Firms Seeking Financing. American Sociological
Review, 64, 481-505.
van Wassenaer, N. (1625). Historisch verhael alder ghedenck-weerdichste
geschiedenisse. Amsterdam, NL: Jan Evertsz. Cloppenburgh & Jan Janssen.
Velius, T. (1648). Chroniick van Hoorn. Hoorn: Isaac Willemsz.
Visscher, R. (1614). Sinnepoppen. Amsterdam, NL: Willem Iansz.
Watts, D. J. (2003). Six Degrees: The Science of a Connected Age. New York, NY: W.W.
Norton.
Watts, D. J. (2007). The Accidental Influentials. Harvard Business Review, 22-23.
Wild-Animal Spirits: Why Is Finance So Unstable? (2009, 22 January). Economist.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi