Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 28

FARMERS PARTICIPATION IN INDIAN AGRICULTURAL COMMODITY MARKETS

-FEW AVENUES FOR A BETTER PRICE! 1. INTRODUCTION


Recent years have witnessed significant growth in Indian agricultural commodity markets. This market, in effect, has notched up phenomenal growth in terms of number of products on offer, participation, spatial distribution, and volume of trade (Sen et al., 2008). Despite this Indian farmers have been occupied with a little share in this market. Undeniably, farmers participation is a central theme to discussion in this article. An attempt has been made to explore a few avenues to encourage the farmers engagement in Indian commodity markets. Thin literature base with respect to this has so far been available and there is hardly any comprehensive framework depicting the modalities and possibilities of participation of Indian farmers, especially, for a large pool of small and marginal farmers having less than a hectare or two of operational landholdings. Hence, this article will provide a roadmap to explore the nuances involved in farmers participation in Indian agricultural commodity markets. In India, futures market was, albeit, present in some crude form until 19 th century. Bombay Cotton Trade Association (BCTA) had received paramount importance by virtue of being a regional exchange in Indian soil in the year 1875. Off and on, many regional commodity exchanges had established like India Pepper and Spice Trade Association (IPSTA), Kochi, Vijay Beopar Chambers Ltd.(VBCL), Muzaffaranagar, Kanpur Commodity Exchange (KCE), East India Jute Association Ltd.(EIJAL), Kolkata to name a few in between 1900s to 1950s. A study by Naik and Jain in early 21st century seems to be a good attempt as their study meticulously tried to gauge the performance of regional level commodity exchanges until 2002. In late 2002, commodity futures market underwent a rebirth following the establishment of countrys first national level demutualised commodity exchange, the National Multi Commodity Exchange (NMCE, 26th November, 2002). It is noteworthy to mention that recent years have witnessed significant growth despite the fact that intermittent ban on a few commodities led to arrest the pace of growth, in essence, trade volume and participation of agents on electronic futures

Page 1 of 28

platform. Nair (2004) pointed out that the major stumbling block for the development of futures market is due to the fragmented and unorganised physical or cash markets. Since 2006, efforts have been channelised to achieve integration between futures and spot commodity markets to a greater extent. Three national level spot exchanges, the National Spot Exchange (NSPOT) promoted by the National Commodity and Derivative Exchange (NCDEX), the National Spot Exchange of India (NSEIL) overseen by the Financial Technology Group (FTG), National Agricultural Co-operative Marketing Federation (NAFED), and National Agricultural Produce Marketing Company (NAPMCL) and innovations at futures platform through Exchange of Futures for Physicals (EFP) and Alternate Settlement Mechanism for Futures (ASMF) are some of the good precedence perceived to be outcomes of man-made innovations at several occasions in the country, which augurs well for better price discovery and risk management mechanisms. Up until now commodity futures market has augmented with significant growth in terms of product on offer, trade volume which is about Rs. 112 lakh crore, spatial distribution covering more than 800-900 sub-urban or metros via more than 20,000 terminals, and participation of members including professional clearing or/and professional clearing-cum-trading members and institutional clearing members (more than 3000) reported by a study under the chairmanship of Dr. Abhijit Sen Committee in the year 2008. In India, significant and relevant literature base on commodity futures have been delimited the depth of research in commodity futures markets, in general and agricultural commodity futures markets in particular (Kolamkar, 2003; Kumar and Pandey, 2009; Ramaswami and Singh, 2007; Raipuria, 2002; Roy, 2008; Thomas, 2003). Several committees had constituted to monitor, control, and regulate this market at several occasions at the behest of Government of India, namely, A.D. Shroff Committee (1950), M. L. Dantwala Committee (1966), A.M. Khusro Committee (1979), K.N. Kabra Committee (1993), Shankarlal Guru Committee (2001), Habibullah Committee (2003), and lastly Sen Committee (2008). More or less, those committees recommendations, inevitably, stand out few indicatives with respect to measuring the efficacy of Indian commodity futures markets, assertions behind low degree of participation or on contrary, excessive speculation, and implications behind impositions of ban on several commodities relating to economic fundamentals driven by those commodities and their underlying policy issues (FTGKMC, 2011).

Page 2 of 28

Newbery and Stiglitz (1981) argue that futures market provides a partial insurance mechanism to the farmers' produces as this market is considered to mitigate risk of price of output only rather than that of value of total produces. Producers are not homogenous in nature and their expectations are largely varied with respect to nature of produces, floated futures contract specifications, delivery month, margin money, and over and above, efficiency of the market. Intuitively, it can be inferred that market integration has improved the process of price formation and transmission following the establishment of national level commodity exchanges in the post 2003 and until 2010. However, the progress is on anvil to curtail the magnitude of information asymmetry. Price stabilisation is a matter of concern in this regard, which warrants a critical review and appraisal with respect to various forms of their merits, say, nonlinearities, disturbance form, risk response, surplus, partial stabilisation, export earnings, optimization, simulation, and others (Labys, 1980). At microstructure level, moral hazard and adverse selection have been mitigated to some extent because of the prudent governance mechanisms, risk compliances, and transparent reporting systems (Ghosh, 2009). These are, probably, few accepted elucidations of technology mediated innovations in Indian commodity markets (Bhattacharjee, 2007). The major issue, yet challenging and persisting, has not been addressed in full-fledged manner. Few exchanges, namely, the MCX and the NCDEX have showcased few successful cases which have implemented aggregation models to encourage the farmers participation on futures as well as on electronic spot platforms (Berg, 2007; Fernandes and Mor, 2009). Still, these initiatives are in nascent stages. Quite logically, benefits of these innovations have not fully permeated at the producers or the growers level, who are directly or actively engaged in agriculture. Why, what, and how-these can be subject to further discussions with special emphasis on producers participation in electronic-commodity or e-commodity markets. Models will try to narrate the probable avenues that how these can help to rendering services at producers or farmers level and to what extent models will be scalable. The remainder of this article proceeds as follows. Section one illustrates few concepts which are useful to operationalise the proposed avenues. Section two discusses the model as a case of triangle by incorporating the principal as the farmer, the exchange, and other agencies including private players, co-operatives, collateral management agencies (CMAs). Last section concludes.

Page 3 of 28

SECTION-I 2. FUTURES MARKET: ITS MECHANICS AND INSTRUMENTS


Mechanics of commodity trading has largely been adopted by almost all national level exchanges, which has been at par with the best practices being reflected on the platform of global commodity exchanges up until now. Trading, settlement, and delivery-these three integral processes have hitherto largely been performed by any national level commodity exchange at the behest of the regulator in India. Novation comes to play here. Contract design, margin money, mark-to-market, settlement pattern, etc. are parameters underlying principles of market microstructure which usually provide a performance guarantee being monitored by the exchange for both the buyer and the seller (Dey and Maitra, 2011). These are put in place for ensuring liquidity, leverage, and transparency (Kaul, 2007). Few arguments have also illustrated empirically against the benefits of electronic markets over open outcry practices (Pavaskar, 2008). Market microstructure issues have also being discussed in the realm of Indian commodity futures markets in particular by Ghosh (2009) and Pavaskar (2009).

2.1. MARGIN MONEY AND PAYOFF


Margin money is an important pre-requisite by providing a gate pass to enter into this market. For a poor farmer, arrangement of atleast initial margin is difficult, which constitutes about 4% to 5% of total value of the contract traded on exchange platform. Additional, special, incremental-these are being charged by the exchange based on trading frequency, contract size, maintenance of spread (bid-ask) gap, volatility in the market etc. By considering all these requisites, this is quite impossible for a farmer to reap the benefits by leveraging on futures markets. Arbitraging or short selling can be an alternative. Aggregators (who aggregate produce by pooling) can make it possible by participating on behalf of a group of farmers on exchange platform. From financial angle, margin money raised through collateral has a direct impact on the number of contracts being purchased. On contrary, margin raised via debt or loan is inversely proportional to purchased contracts (Bailey, 2005: p.13-15).

Page 4 of 28

The following equations are written below to show the two probable conditions with their different likelihoods. m = (c pn / pn), i, j ,... 0 m = [(c / pn) 1] m k 1 m = ( pn l / pn), i, j ,... 0 m = [1 (l / pn)] m 1 s obj. 0

(1), (2), (3)

max(k 1, 0)

min(1 s, 0)

Where m is amount of margin, c and l are collateral and loan respectively. p is price per contract and n is the number of contract purchased. (c/pn) is considered as k whereas (l/pn) taken ass. Objective is to maximize either collateral or minimise loan amount to increase pn amount and increase the gap between collateral and loan relative to loan amount to calculate actual margin requirement (expressed in percentage). Similarly, rate of return (%) is calculated on the difference between payoff and price paid relative to price, which is considered as an opportunity cost. Maxima and minima functions are presented with respect to the objective function parameter (3). More formally, as p varies, so does m. If p falls, m may fall so low that the member/broker demands funds from the investor (aggregator in this case) to reduce l and raise m. It is common to require that the actual margin be restored to its initial value (a common practice in short-selling); although it is possible that investor may be obliged to restore it only to the maintenance margin threshold. The precise requirement depends on the terms of agreement between the parties to the transaction and the exchange authorities. Through equation (2), it can be derived that m varies with p. If p increases, m may fall so low that the broker demands funds from the investor to increase the collateral, c, and thus raise m. Margin money has an implication on daily settlement mechanism or mark-to-market process. In case of long futures, margin call indicates a low or less than the previous settled/close price whereas margin call for short futures indicates an opposite direction, i.e., high or more than the previous close price (through tick-by-tick basis).

Page 5 of 28

Telser (1981) argued that initial margin requirements do have a cost attached which is liquidity cost. Once the margin money is deposited it is no more available to the hedger for any further purposes and now it renders participant less liquid than before he/she bought or sold futures contracts. Kalavathi and Shanker (1991) also examined that there is negative impact of initial margin requirements upon the demand for futures contracts by hedger. The cost of initial margin is the spread between hedgers borrowing and lending rates. Since a substantial portion of liquid cash has been deposited for investing any other high yielding assets or purposes, the person has to borrow again. Thus, the cost of margin is an opportunity cost here. In order to meet liquidity needs and also to make the opportunity of investing being happened in the presence of margin money, the hedger has to borrow. This has also been mathematically expressed by Kalavathi and Shanker (1991). It is assumed that a hedger holds C unit of spot commodity (long at spot) and he/she wants to maximise the excess return per unit of risk of the hedged portfolio and accordingly chooses N, the number of futures contracts to be hedged at the futures by selling N futures contracts in the commodity exchange (short futures). Now,
Rh = C ( P 'P ) + NS ( F F ' CP M .C m ) S
(4)

Where Rh= return from the hedged portfolio over the hedge period; C=number of units of the spot commodity held; P=price of commodity at spot after the hedge period; P=price of commodity at spot at the beginning of hedge period; N=number of futures contracts in the hedged portfolio; S=size of each futures contract F= futures price of futures contracts at the beginning hedge period; M=initial margin requirement per futures contract and Cm=cost per rupee of margin money requirement, this could be liquidity or opportunity cost. F=futures price of futures contracts at the end hedged- period; the cost per rupee of margin requirement is critical for determining the return from the hedged portfolio of the spot and futures instrument. As Cm is critically important, it becomes obvious that an increase in margin requirement or high margin requirements would adversely affect the demand of futures contracts.

Page 6 of 28

TABLE 1: Contract-wise margin requirement


MCX
Symbol ALMOND BARLEY BARLEY GUARSEED GUARSEED MAIZE MAIZE MAIZE MENTHAOIL MENTHAOIL POTATO POTATO POTATO RUBBER RUBBER SOYABEAN SOYABEAN SUGARMKO L SUGARMKO L SUGARMKO L WHEAT WHEAT WHEAT WHEAT Expiry Date 30-Jun 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jul 20-Jun 20-May 30-Jun 31-May 15-Jul 15-Jun 14-May 15-Jun 14-May 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jul 20-Jun 20-May 19-Aug 20-Jul 20-Jun 20-May Initial Margin 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5.83 6.53 6.73 5.11 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 Tender Margin 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 5 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total Margi n 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5.83 6.53 6.73 10.11 5 8 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 Symbol BADAM BARLEYJPR BARLEYJPR GARSEDJDR GARSEDJDR MAIZE MAIZE MAIZE MENTHAOIL MENTHAOIL POTATO POTATO POTATO RBRRS4KOC RBRRS4KOC SYBEANIDR SYBEANIDR SUGARS150 SUGARS150 SUGARS150 WHTSMQDE LI WHTSMQDE LI WHTSMQDE LI WHTSMQDE LI Expiry Date 20-Jun 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jul 20-Jun 20-May 30-Jun 31-May 20-Jul 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jun 20-May 20-Jul 20-Jun 20-May 19-Aug 20-Jul 20-Jun 20-May

NCDEX
Initial Margin 3.5 5.96 6.06 5.41 5.46 3.9 3.96 3.99 9.78 9.23 9.51 8.39 7.31 4.98 5.08 2.78 2.81 3.5 3.5 3.5 3.57 3.61 3.64 3.68 Exposure Margin 1.5 3.25 3.25 2.5 2.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 2.75 2.75 1 1 1 1.5 1.5 2.25 2.25 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 Total Margin 5 9.21 9.31 7.91 7.96 5.4 5.46 5.49 12.53 11.98 10.51 9.39 8.31 6.48 6.58 5.03 5.06 5 5 5 5.07 5.11 5.14 5.18

Source: compiled from the MCX and the NCDEX as on 10 May 2011, data with respect to margin money are expressed in percentage (%). Bold figures indicate total margin money in %, which shows a sharp contract in terms of margin imposition between two exchanges.

Page 7 of 28

2.2. MECHANICS OF HEDGING USING FUTURES INSTRUMENT


The exchanges trading futures in any given commodity are indicated followed by a mention of the contracts that have matured during the period. The predominant pattern of the hedge market, namely, contango or backwardation, is indicated. The hedge is said to be in backwardation when current supplies are scarce leading to exhaustion of producers inventories (stock out condition) and opposite phenomenon holds in case of contango. We can describe these two commonly used terminologies in hedging strategy using futures. A situation called contango is said to arise when the futures prices rise over the life of the contract following hedgers and speculators desire to be net long and net short, respectively. Conversely, a falling price where spot price of asset is greater than the futures price of the underlying asset is referred to as backwardation. In case of normal contango and normal backwardation, futures price will be above the expected future spot price and expected spot price will be above the futures price, respectively. Future trade receives impetus from increased volatility in the spot market of the underlying commodity. Thus, precisely, both the markets need to be watched and in this context, basis assumes significance. Basis reflects cost of marketing the commodity, which is storage costs (cost of carry model) forming an important component; and thus, ought to be less variable than the spot. Basis variation or basis risk also implies operational risk, credit risk, and market risk. Economic fundamentals (production, import, export, carryover stock, and consumption) of the asset, liquidity, and return on assets (Roll, 1984) largely affect basis variation either in a positive or negative manner. Basis variation, in turn, decides the magnitude of hedge-effectiveness or degree of variance minimising hedge-ratio (Roy, 2008). Let s1, s2 be spot prices and f1, f2 be futures prices with time variable t1, t2 and the basis (b1, b2) are denoted by b1 = s1-f1; b2 = s2-f2 f1 +b2 or s2 (f2-f1), (5) (6)

Hence, we can get payoff equation after considering effective realization on financial asset or commodity, i.e., payoff through hedging mechanism,

Page 8 of 28

= [f1 + (s2-f2) + (s2-s1)]n or [s2 + (s2-s1) - (f2-f1)]n where n is contract size

(7)

Where h = nf/nA, nf is the number of contracts for futures and nA is the number of contracts of underlying assets or commodities at spot. Basis occasionally remains constant because local supply and demand conditions continually change through time. Changes in basis are known as basis patterns or basis variations. In order to use basis to select among marketing alternatives, basis theory and associated concepts must be understood, and basis patterns are one of the important concepts. An improving basis changes from weak to strong. Logically, if basis strengthens unexpectedly then this improves a short hedger position. On contrary, if basis weakens unexpectedly, the situation worsens a long hedger position (Hull, 2007). If we know the value of s2 and nA then we can calculate mimimum variance hedge ratio. The equations are written below. = snA - fnf = snA - fhnf Now, variance (2v) of the hedged-position can be calculated
(s hf)2 (2s - 2hsf + h22f), taking the first-order differentiation of variance with respect to h

(8)

(dv/dh) and equating with 0, we get


dv/dh = d/dh (2s - 2hsf + h22f) = 0 dv/dh = 0 - 2sf + 2h2f = 0 h = s/f d2v/dh2 = 22f 0

(9)

Second-order derivative satisfies the minima condition and first-order derivative holds the condition of minimum-variance hedge ratio. In alternative way, we can calculate minimumvariance hedge ratio (h) by considering covariance of change in spot and futures price relative to variance of change in futures price [s,f/2f] or [* s/f] where s, f, are standard deviation of change in spot price, standard deviation of change in futures price, and correlation coefficient between change in spot and futures price, respectively. Some literature show that simple ordinary least square (OLS) technique is inferior over the GARCH (Generalized Autoregressive

Page 9 of 28

Conditional Heteroscedasticity) estimated dynamic hedge-ratio (Gupta and Singh 2009). Still, OLS (static hedge ratio) outperforms GARCH models in most of the cases for calculating variance minimising hedge-ratio. Formally, the basis is defined here as the difference between the spot and futures market price for a commodity, which is negative in contango market or vice versa. It is a signal of market forces at work and will change over time as the cash market price and futures market price converge. The simple efficiency hypothesis of futures market postulates that the future price is simply the expected and technically called the unbiased predictor of the future spot price implying that spot and futures prices share a one to one long-run equilibrium. The expectations hypothesis treats the future prices as the consensus (indicative) forecast of the future spot price. To a great extent, this is dependent upon the method of collection of spot quotes by the exchanges. Biased collection procedures present distorted patterns in the spot quotes and, for this reason, the two do not seem to converge at the expiration of contract. To solve the issue of settlement, a due date rate (DDR) is fixed by exchanges which is simple average of spot prices during delivery period, which should take place within 11 days after settlement at the exchangenotified warehouses (FMC, 2002). Key factors affecting the basis are, inter alia, distortions/opacities in the underlying spot market, weather, imports/exports, government aid packages, trade disputes, disease outbreaks, anticipated short term supply and/or demand, work holidays etc. As agents face more basis risk, they reduce their exposure by reducing inventory level. Hence, the storage level is adversely affected. A fairly good and necessarily positive correlation (>0.5 or 0.5-0.80) and relatively low deviation between the spot and future prices would posit certain degree of integration of two markets. The movement of futures and spots prices in tandem is a necessary condition for manageably low basis risk. Wherever the basis is not zero, the local supply and demand factors are different from those prevailing in the futures market. A negative basis indicates the local spot price is less than futures price implying the local supply is greater than local demand, a situation called contango. Conversely, related concepts are that of a normal market where the futures trade at a premium over the nearer one and the opposite in the case of an inverted market. When the basis is positive,

Page 10 of 28

i.e., the cash price greater than the futures price and the cash market is trading at a premium over the futures indicating that the local demand is greater than local supply, a situation called backwardation. In India, a study conducted under the chairmanship of Abhijit Sen (2008) illustrates comprehensively that the magnitude of basis pattern for wheat varies from high to low followed by moderate to weak for chana and for others, variation seems to be moderate. Hedgeeffectiveness (HE) is found relatively high in case of pulses, namely, chana, 36%), tur, 44%, and urad, 43%. In case of guar seed, sugar and wheat, this is 58%, 32%, and 15% respectively. These numbers implicitly throw some lights on suspension of trading of commodities, namely, sugar, tur, urad (although ban on sugar had lifted few months before).

SECTION-II

3. EXCHANGE, FARMER, AND OTHER AGENCIES: A CASE OF TRIANGLE


Exchange usually provides fairly an improved and sophisticated platform for price discovery processes and price risk management. But nuances involved in trading are complex ones, if not, being understood by agents or investors properly. Same is also applicable to Indian farmers. Tiny land holdings, poor productivity, exorbitant interest rates on informal credit, lack of access to formal credit, and lack of marketing acumen are few impediments which impound them from realising better price rather than experiencing good yield. This is true for almost 80 % of Indian peasants. Other obstacles could be market driven. Poor infrastructure relating to market yards, (Agriculture Produce Market Committee Act, 2003), poor trade practices (auctioning), limited initiatives for increasing awareness about commodity futures markets, spot markets across regional centers and so on have been delimited the growth of commodity markets. Thanks to the mediation of few private agencies or a sort of private-public-partnership projects, which have been initiated in the recent past to augment the liquidity in this trade like Institute for Financial Management and Research (IFMR), Adani facilitated aggregation model to encourage the farmers participation in Reliance e-Mandi trade, NCDEX-Haryana State Cooperative Supply and Marketing Federation (HAFED) collaboration for hedging of wheat on behalf of farmers,

Page 11 of 28

and MCX- Aga Khan Rural Support Programme (AKRSP-I)-Cardinal Edge (CE)-a case of triangle to name a few. Case-I: Guetemalan Coffee Growers Association (ANACAFE), a non-government organisation had set precedence by introducing a credit system for small coffee growers in 1980s. By linking the farmers with banks for credit, ANACAFE made it prerequisite to use risk management instrument in order to hedge the risk. So, farmers received only loan amount after assuring banks that they had proper risk management tools like forward price agreement, hedging through futures markets, etc. In this process banks also sanctioned loan amount with lower interest rate which eventually brought about savings for farmers of more than 10% of loanto- value. Both banks and farmers had become successful to minimise the risk. Case-II: In 1994, Agricultural Products Option Programme (APOP) was introduced in Mxico in cotton which was further extended to wheat, corn etc. Here, Support and Services for Agricultural Trading, (ASERCA), a decentralized administrative part of the Ministry of Agriculture, Livestock, Rural Development, Fisheries and Alimentary, acted as an intermediary between producers and exchange, e.g. Chicago Board of Trade and New York Cotton Exchange. ASERCA helped the farmers to participate in the exchanges by buying put option through grouping their production to meet minimum size requirement for which ASERCA contributed 50 % of total option premium. But farmers ought to deposit the same amount in one fund called FINCA. The cost appeared to the farmers was 5-8 % of the strike price of the option. As a result of which APOP covered 11 % of the total wheat production of Mexico. Case-III: In Surendranagar of Gujarat state, the MCX in collaboration with Cardinal Edge for administrative support and Aga Khan Rural Support Programme (AKRSP-I) initiated one programme to make cotton growers aware of the futures markets and its complex operational nuances during 2007. For funding purposes, they sought the help of NABARD and opening of trading accounts was accomplished by Kotak Securities. Case-IV: Centre for Micro Finance (CMF), Self-Employed Womens Association (SEWA) and the NCDEX partnered in 2007. A randomised controlled trial (RCT) had been conducted to examine the impact of providing commodity futures prices to farmers at 108 villages in four districts in Gujarat and its impact on price expectation and sowing decision. The programme

Page 12 of 28

seemed to be found with significant impact on formation of price expectation but at the same time, it had not been found with any significant effect on selecting crops or areas cultivated.
Source: OECD (2000) report on Income Risk Management in Agriculture (case-I to Case-III) and Cole, S (2009), Futures Price Information for Farmers paper presented at the conference on Risk Mitigation in

Agriculture organised by IFMR, Chennai, SEWA Bank Ahmedabad, Gujarat, 2009, August (case-IV).

In 1999, International Task Force on Commodity Risk Management of World Bank (WB) recommended the establishment of one international intermediary which would fill the gap between price insurance providers like banks, brokers or traders, etc. and the service seekers like producers organisations, agribusiness organisations, co-operatives, etc. It would perform three types of functions, (a) facilitation by providing partial guarantees to mitigate risk involved in the transaction, (b) intermediation between service providers and users, and (c) provision of core services and technical assistance-in particular, market information and support to local transmission mechanisms (WB, 1999). Agriculture and agribusiness both are highly influenced by the vagaries of nature. Hence, the risks attendant cannot be avoided or wished away. Financing in agriculture requires a long-range planning. At the same time, relatively stable cashflows would ease out the financing process. Seasonality is a major bottleneck which results in a conservative outlook towards credit rationing in agriculture. Pledge financing is an age-old financing technique adopted by most nationalized banks, a few private sector banks and non banking finance companies (NBFCs). This is usually accomplished on the basis of collateral being produced by the borrower to/before the lender. Technically, collateral is an asset, say, a marketable property, either in the form of physical or financial, which can be pledged or physically transferred by a borrower to a lender; the borrower retains the right to any earnings from the asset, and the lender can only dispose of the asset when the borrower defaults on his payment obligations (UNCTAD, 1996). So, the loan amount is being obtained through collateral, which should bring rights ascribed to the title of ownership. Warehouse receipt (WR) is such example that can be considered as a negotiable instrument under the directives prescribed by the Warehouse Development (Regulation) Act, 2007. Of late, this kind of financing has been changed to a different nomenclature, which is, collateral (commodity) based structured financing (CBSF).This type of financing, typically, helps to assure predictable cashflows that can be isolated from its originator in order to secure credit on part of the borrower and to mitigate risks on part of the lender. Collateral management
Page 13 of 28

agency (CMA) is a third party to ensure a guarantee for both parties with respect to physical risk, market risk, and operational risk like National Collateral Management Services Limited, National Bulk Handling Corporation limited, Arya collateral, Star Agri, India Commodities to name a few . In turn, the agency usually charges a commission or service fee, which is linked with performance guarantee for the collateral overseen by the CMA under its lock-and-key arrangement. Role of CMAs is well described. Since collateral management is still being in nascent stage, there is hardly any data or information on the exact quantum of agricultural produces and industrial assets financed under collateral management structures. Avanthakrishnan (2011) puts forward
It would be of interest to note that against a gross bank credit of Rs. 3,38,656 crore as at the end of March, 2009, to the agriculture sector, the extent of finance secured by collateral management structures is only 10,000 crore, clearly indicating that there is tremendous scope for such financing in the days to come (Avanthakrishnan, 2009: p. 135).

On contrary, commodity futures or derivative markets have witnessed exponential growth in recent times. Evidently, total turnover and value of futures trading of agro commodities were approximately 291.0 million tonnes and Rs.9.02 lakh crores in the year 2009-10 respectively (Economic Survey of India, 2009-10) despite the invocations of ban at several occasions on many commodities. Research with the help of exchange-level proprietary data helps to uncover many issues behind those decisions, which could be pertinent to practitioners also with varied magnitudes, namely, the presence of causality, effect of net convenience yield (i.e., convenience yield minus cost of carry) under two market situations, contango and backwardation, modelling of volatility spillover in both futures and spot markets, determination of optimal hedge-ratio, etc. It is evident from a relevant literature base in the same domain that futures and spot prices of commodities co-move with a profound lead-lag relationship. They go or move in tandem and their relationships over a particular point of time seem to establish a long-run equilibrium through short-range dynamics. Hence, order of integration between futures and spot series can be achieved, which is subject to the differenced stationary processes. However, futures-and spotreturn series do not usually stick to or follow the independent and identical distribution (IID) pattern. BDS (Broch et al., 1996) test can be employed to check this hypothesis as a dependence test of nonlinearity under some distributional assumption, which may be parametric or semi

Page 14 of 28

parametric in nature. This implies that non-linearity and non-normality are inherent in both futures-and spot-series. It is a typical characteristic of any time-series data whatever the case may be, either for financial asset or for a commodity. Incorporation of suitable or right methodology and some prudent tools and techniques can ensure the pattern and magnitude of price transmission and thus, would help anticipate the future expectations of agents about spot prices of commodities at different time interval or at different lag length. Futures also serves as a barometer or a price messenger in a manner that to what extent futures and spot markets are (co)integrated, which is often referred to as co-integration under a suitable econometric framework. Volatility measures also reinstates that how agents can derive benefits from the price volatility of two markets and eventually, risk-return optimisation through price instability (Waugh, 1944). Labys (1980) put a counter argument that consumers or producers gain or loss depends upon: the source of the price instability, say, transition in supply as compared demand; the additive or multiplicative nature of random disturbances which are functional in nature and their autoregressive properties; the nature of producer response including the formation of expectations and risk etc. Granularity or concavity effect due to the presence of non-linearity structure brings about a varied degree of outcomes with the value of position (buy or sell) on asset for agents, which could be effected through a nave strategy-buy low and sell high considering an appropriate reference frame or time horizon of trading or through exercising on the respective positions. Research through secondary sources of data definitely provides some roadmap for strategy formulation at the grass root level, which is nothing but a top-down approach. Crop selection, staggered planting, cropping intensity, inputs, and credit requirement-all these decisions are being influenced by the direction or dimension of causality between futures and spot prices. Apparently, futures prices provide the forward looking arrangement for agents or market participants and adjustment of disturbances or shocks in both price-series largely depend on different forms of market efficiency. Phenomena including contango or forwardation and backwardation are reflections of price discovery mechanism and prevailing form of market efficiency in commodity markets. Thus, appropriate and timely inputs from research-desk undoubtedly promotes the speed of price dissemination and would meet out the expectations of

Page 15 of 28

11th Five Year Plan (2007-12)-at the behest of the FMC under the aegis of the Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food, and Public Distribution. Adequate research and peer-reviewed journals in Indian commodity markets have been limited to few although there is huge scope and untapped potential for unveiling the uncovered issues. Researchers opined at several occasions that Indian futures markets are ill-developed as the major stumbling block for the development is due to the fragmented and unorganised underlying physical or spot markets (Nair, 2004). Merely, seven years data of futures-spot prices series are not effective enough to provide a signpost on futuristic trend. As commodity is distinctively different from a financial asset, primary level research should be conducted at the producers level. Theory of storage, convenience yield, and risk premium or liquidity preference theory succinctly warrant some action-research being conducted at participatory level in this market. It is important to leave a scope for discussions, which may evolve around the debate on farmers participation in commodity futures markets. Indian farmers are mostly indebted to middlemen and tiny land holdings make them handicapped from realising marketable surplus. Farmers usually grow or take one to two crop(s) in a year as mono-cropping or rice-wheat cycle has been in vogue in India. An alternative may be aggregation of produce on lot basis in order to fulfill the criteria of contract specifications directed by the exchanges as self-regulatory organisations (SROs). Aggregator model should be implemented in a manner that some subject matter specialists can intervene in the network of aggregator and exchange. This will help to achieve backward and forward integration and thereby, economies of integration. Cooperatives or NGOs who have been engaging for the last couple of years in the present structure of the model, awareness and some hands-on-exposure should be rendered at their disposal by those national level commodity exchanges. Contract specifications like lot size, margining system, and delivery process should be understood by the aggregator properly. The role of middlemen should be recognized as they know the trade better. Quality of the produce at e-auction or on futuresplatform should be examined with right deployment of entities, say of middlemen or/and exchanges employed product managers. The following avenues can be evaluated based on their merits for implementation. Few are in offing at the behest of the Government of India and others

Page 16 of 28

can be explored which will seek to achieve concordance among policymakers and industry professionals. However, support at the policy level cannot be avoided or wished away. The following avenues can be explored to encourage farmers participation in this market: 4.1. Aggregators can adopt short selling strategy. In that case, margin money and payoff should be calculated meticulously. Stop loss strategy can also be adopted by the agents in absence of arbitraging mechanism followed by a reverse cash and carry model (for more details, see, Bailey, 2005). 4.2. Hedging is not as effective as theoretically illustrated in the first section of this article. Basis risk is the most important risk element inter alia, which warrants a vigil on day-to-day price movements at both futures and its underlying markets. It is always better to have tailed hedging than untailed hedging from economic perspective as in tailed hedging the difference between the time future gains or losses and the time the gains or losses from spot markets position realized are considered. Thus, it well considers the cost of financing or returns due to variation in margin settlement. In this case, every day the hedge ration is multiplied by the daily spot to futures price ratio. If options could be introduced, then there could be some possibilities for adopting delta hedging strategy under risk-neutral environment. Aggregators could go with a positive theta (time variable), a positive gamma (first order derivative of delta or second order derivative of option premium with respect to underlying) by neutralising delta in order to optimise returns or minimise losses in either of two options, say, call or put. 4.3. Collateral Management Agencies (CMAs) should be cautious and industrious enough to protect both the exchanges and aggregators by mitigating physical, operational, and market risks with differential impacts of their respective risks elements. CMAs should test, validate, and certify the stocks kept in the bonded or accredited warehouses with the help of quality control department (which may be in-house or outsourced). First, CMA can keep the produce of aggregators into accredited warehouses and mark a lien on warehouse receipt (WR) which can be produced before a banker to raise the credit. In addition to, CMAs can take a call to dispose of the produce either at spot or futures platform based on prevailing market prices and other conditions on behalf of aggregators (as per bye-laws, which should be prescribed under the

Page 17 of 28

WDRA, 2007 to act accordingly). Hence, CMAs roles are very crucial in making the whole value chain effective and efficient. CMAs can look at seasonal calendar and historical prices of traded commodities so that they can deliver end-to-end solutions to aggregators, in turn, the latter can pass on the information to producers. This will help immensely to end users of futures or spot exchanges for choosing or selecting the crop-portfolio and modes of marketing the produces. 4.4. Government agencies including the Food Corporation of India (FCI), Food and Civil Supplies Departments, State Agricultural Marketing Boards (SAMBs) can directly procure from the farmers or traders, or/and aggregators at current market prices (besides entering into Price Support Scheme, i.e., Minimum Support Price (MSP) in collaboration with spot exchanges promoted by commodity exchanges in the year 2006. FCI, State and Central Warehousing Corporations (SWCs, CWCs) can store the procured produces after issuing warehouse receipt (WR)-a negotiable instrument as per directives prescribed by the Warehouse Development (Regulation) Act, 2007 (for more details, see, Avanthakrishnan, 2011: p. 135-139). Two kind of strategy can be formulated. If aggregators want to store the harvested produces at exchanges notified warehouses at respective locations, then WR can act as a shield by arranging the credit from financial institutions at cheap or at moderate interest rates (differential rate of interest-DRI can also be provisioned). In alternative manner, FCI, SWCs, CWCs can issue commodity bonds (like potato) which can provide an assured stream of returns (as same as coupon or coupon striping) in a stipulated time period to avoid the distress sales or crop failure. What exchanges can do that they can open alternative delivery centers in nearby FCI or SWCs/CWCs depots to expedite delivery processes during the post-settlement period. In that case, brokerage fee can be fixed upto a certain limit so that aggregators can earn reasonably a fair amount of commission based on the value of trade executed. Apart from these, RBI (2005) advocated that banks can offer non-standard contracts to the farmers and cover them in the commodity futures trade as for farmers it is difficult to take positions directly in futures markets. In view of this, RBI decided that banks can offer tailor made products to the farmers like Non-Transferable Specific Delivery (NTSD) and Transferable Specific Delivery (TSD) which are only allowed under FCRA Act, 1952. Although there are significant development happened in commodity futures markets so far, still more changes need to be required at different levels. Recently, price dissemination of both spot and futures prices of agricultural commodities has been identified as

Page 18 of 28

one of important activities by Planning Commission in its XIth Five Year Plan. The initiative had undertaken by the FMC in collaboration with Ministry Agriculture, five national level exchanges (NMCE, NCDEX, MCX, India Commodity Exchange (ICEX) and Ace Derivatives and Commodity Exchange (ACDE)) and 18 regional exchanges where futures and spot prices of commodities of national exchanges and spot prices of Agricultural Marketing board (AGMARKNET) would be operated and shown on the ticker board installed in APMCs networks under the aegis of AGMARKNET and the National Informatics Centre (NIC). By disseminating a spectrum of instantly observable prices these exchanges transferred the pricing power to the farming community and enhanced institutional development like grading, warehouse receipt etc., supply chain integration and farm credit facilitation (FAO, 2007). 4.5. FMC can promote options for certain commodities, which have users-specific demands and have relatively high asset-specificity in the industry, namely, rubber, black pepper, crude palm oil, cotton, guar seed, etc. These commodities have their regional importance as productions are being limited to few states, but consumptions are being observed profoundly round the year. Aggregators can enter into an option contract with exchanges by buying a put option (long put) whereas the FCI and other private agencies, viz., ITC, Ruchi, Reliance, Glencore, Australian Wheat Board, Louis Dreyfus, and Cargill etc. can exercise the option by selling a put (short put). Aggregators would pay the premium and can delimit the potential losses in a way that option holders can hold the produce until the maturity or till the contract expiration (Fernandes and Mor, 2009). European option would be better in order to avoid the temporal risk or liquidity risk between the time value of option price/ premium and intrinsic or theoretical value of the option. Thus, arbitrage opportunity, if any, exists during the time period of option contract until the maturity can be avoided to some extent. Hence, call-put parity will hold. In that case, exchanges should devise some indices for agricultural commodities which can minimise excessive spikes or volatilities for both the spot-futures prices of the notified commodities (like MCX-AGRI, NCDEX FUTEX) and indices should incorporate the changes in prices being reflected on tick-by-tick basis by improvising some robust mechanisms with international exchanges indices, say, Goldman Sachs Commodity Index (GSCI). In alternate of MSP, option can be introduced as several merits of this have been discussed by Fernandes and Mor (2009).

Page 19 of 28

SECTION-III 4. CONNECTION AND CONCLUSION


It is well known fact that agriculture has been a mainstay of the Indian economy. This is also evident as major portion of the economy has been harping on agriculture since the first Five Year Plan (1950-51-1955-56) with respect to procurement of raw materials, processing, and finished products. Several risks are also associated with this activity, namely, physical, credit, operational, and market risks. Risk quantification is a daunting task because of complex methodological issues. Covariancevariance matrix is a simpler one to understand risk metrices. Correlation comes to play here. It implies strength of the linear relationship among variables. But it cannot capture nonlinearity, if any, exists in the variables. Statistically, it is a ratio of covariance to the product of standard deviations of atleast two random variables; one may be dependent and other being independent. Correlation, intuitively, tells about the movement of atleast two variables either in a positive or a negative direction. A recent estimate by Sabnavis (2011) shows that correlation coefficient between domestic and international prices of commodities are quite high, for instance, correlation of sugar prices projects 0.92, followed by soybean, 0.80, then cotton, 0.71, soy oil, 0.68, and lastly, wheat, 0.64. Authors estimation considers International Monetary Fund (IMF) data for international prices and Wholesale Price Index (WPI) for domestic prices. What does this reflect? How does it help to increase producers share in consumers rupee? Is it only an indication of openness to trade (differential of export and import relative to the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of the country during a particular point of time) and smoothening of trade? One needs to be careful while interpreting these numbers. The estimation could be erroneous, if not, competitive advantage with respect to few coefficients, nominal protection coefficient (NPC), effective protection coefficient (EPC), and effective subsidy coefficient (ESC) could have been taken into consideration for exploring the status of Indian agriculture in international

Page 20 of 28

markets (for more details, see Gulati, 2002). Since these estimates have several implications at macro as well as at micro level, price discovery and market efficiency in agricultural commodity markets have become a debatable issue (Ghosh, 2009). Linking to this, integration of Indian agriculture into world markets has thrown some signposts for future research, namely, volatility of commodity prices, export-import parity in agriculture, role of tariffs on agriculture trade liberalization, etc. Moreover, India has been found losing out its comparative advantage in export of some of the agricultural commodities, tea, coffee, spices, and marine products to other Asian countries during 1991-2004 after economic reforms (Shinoj and Mathur, 2008). Arguably, simple correlation coefficient estimates hardly reflects any true picture of Indian agriculture trade in general and price realisation by farmers in particular. At this juncture, we may consider that technological mediations resulting in improvising markets could be a reason for the structural changes, which have been taken place in Indian commodity markets, especially in derivative markets, in the post 2002-03. Contrary to this, Bhalla and Singh (2009) counter that the post-reform period; 1990-93 to 2003-06 has been characterised by decreasing trend in the growth rate of crop yields and total agricultural outputs in most states of India. Commodity futures exchanges, e-auction centers or e-mandis, terminal markets, spot exchanges are few examples of technological innovations, which have been percolated at three layers-products, processes, and business models being adopted by exchanges and other agents. The fundamental focus of this article was to present the existing debate on farmers participation in commodity markets, as also to present a tentative framework on how the mechanism of participation can be drawn with some proposed avenues. While we have illustrated few concepts, this does not mean that the debate should end here. For application of such concepts, one needs to take into consideration knowledge of the physical and derivative markets, as the methodology should ideally be commodity-specific. Every commodity has its own market characteristic, and hence, the propositions narrated here should not be adopted blindly. A primary survey is most important in this regard. It is only by understanding the commodity and its associated market that the right framework or model can be adopted.

Page 21 of 28

No doubt, however, price formation and its transmission are some of the most discussed matter nowadays. While, commodity futures markets are expected to play the two important roles of risk management and price discovery, their utilities in provisioning of these two services have come under criticism from various corners. It is further argued that availability and effective dissemination of information from the futures market helps to stabilise and decrease spot price volatility (Dey and Maitra, 2011). However, all these present testable hypotheses. While ambivalence on the utility of the futures markets still exists at the policy levels, probably the endeavour will help in expanding the literature base by furthering the debate on farmers ground. Nonetheless, stated alternatives presented in the above are a few avenues which can accommodate farmers to some extent in the present structure of commodity futures markets. If option would be allowed, then possibility might lie in and around to validate the propositions empirically. Policy should weave its strength with industrys inputs to make the implementation more effective and efficient. Thereby, this article would hold its position as a precursor for the reality check in ground.
Note ___________________________________ [a] Moral hazard and adverse selection: Moral hazard refers to risk or hazard that arises when a party enters into a transaction without good faith and has given false information about his assets, liabilities etc. because of incentives attached in doing so. It sometimes leads to take unusual risk by one party to earn more profit before agreement expires. Adverse selection is wrong selection of a product. It refers to the market process which gives rise to bad results because of information asymmetry present at both sides i.e. sellers and buyers [b] Market microstructure: Exchange structure studies would stimulate some thoughts for conducting research on market microstructure level. It will further help to understand and provide explanation for price discovery, market efficiency, adequate methods to stimulate new futures contracts have been most effective (Rutten, 2009). Market microstructure may be defined broadly as the process by which investors desires and preferences are translated into financial market transactions (Madhavan, 2000; Harris, 2002; Brooks, 2008). The dynamic nature of market microstructure has been put in place because the movement of the stock/commodity prices largely depends on time-varying variances, past news, market information and macroeconomic variables (Pradhan, 2009). This actually asserts that the efficiency level of the market seems to have an impact for determining the actual return (rather than expected) to the assets being invested by the investors (Black, 1971; French, 1980; Rogalski, 1984; Roll, 1984; Kyle, 1985; French and Roll, 1986; Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993). [c] Co-integration and Causality: Stationarity condition of time-series is, indeed, helpful to satisfy the prerequisite for modelling. Considering Xt and Yt are two non-stationary series, we would expect that a combination of Xt and Yt is also non-stationary. However, a particular combination may be stationary (Gujarati, 2006). If such a combination exists, we say that Xt and Yt are cointegrated. Two cointegrated series will thus drift or float far apart overtime, say, future and spot price-series. Johansen and Juselius (1990) test is mostly employed for testing the cointegration. Engle-Granger causality, and paired Granger causality tests to confirm the short run causality dynamics in order to achieve long-run equilibrium

Page 22 of 28

relationship among bivariate or multivariate time-series (Engle and Granger, 1987; Hamilton, 1994; Enders, 1995). [d] Independently and Identically distributed variable underlying Random Walk (RW) hypothesis and dependence test for nonlinear time-series: Random walk is the simplest version of independently and identically distributed increments case in which asset price is influenced by previous close price and the disturbance form or error component follows an IID path which means mean 0 and variance 2. Sometimes, it is assumed that if error component follows IID pattern, then it is referred to as arithmetic Brownian motion. BDS test is used to find out the presence of non-linearity in the in the time series provided linear dependency has been removed from the data. [e] Hedging through options and option Greeks, delta, gamma and theta: Option pricing, especially implied option pricing works well employing Black, Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973b) model, which makes the following assumptions: There are no market imperfections, say, taxes, short sales constraint, transaction costs, excessive bid-ask spread gap, and trading is synchronous, continuous, and frictionless. There is unlimited riskless borrowing and lending at the continuously intermittent compounded interest rate (r). Option is sensitive to few variables, namely, asset price, strike price, time to maturity, interest rate, dividend or convenience yield (for commodities), and volatility. Delta, gamma, and theta are option Greeks or coefficients which give sensitivities to option pricing. Delta is defined as the change in option price at time t relative to change in underlying asset price, this implies that number of assets one needs to purchase to offset any risk arising out of a number of options (call or put) being sold. If this condition holds, then a portfolio is referred to as perfectly hedged portfolio under risk-neutral or arbitrage-free environment (Campbell, Lo and MacKinlay, 2007). Gamma is the firstorder derivative of delta and theta is defined as the change in option price relative to the change in time to maturity of the option contract. Hence, effective realisation on assets or portfolio can be ascertained given a continuously compounded interest rate, r.

References Avanthakrishnan, P. V. (2011): Warehouse Receipt Financing: Need and Prospects in Kaul (ed.) India Commodity Year Book 2011, (Mumbai: National Collateral Management Services Limited) 132-148. Bailey, R.E. (2005): The Economics of Financial Markets, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press) 13-15. Berg, Ann. E. (2007): The HAFED Experience: Wheat Hedging on the NCDEX, Viewed on 12 November, 2010 (http://www.fmi-inc.net/news/pdfs/HAFEDExperience.pdf ). Bhalla, G.S. and G. Singh (2009): Economic Liberalization and Indian Agriculture: A Statewise Analysis, Economic and Political Weekly, 44(52): 34-44. Bhattacharjee, H. (2007): Commodity Derivatives Market in India, Economic and Political Weekly, 42(13):1151-1162. Black, F. (1971): Towards a Fully Automated Exchange, Part I, Financial Analysts Journal, 27:29-34.

Page 23 of 28

Black, F., and M. Scholes (1973): The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81(3): 637-654. Brock, W.A., W.D. Dechert, J.A. Scheinkman, B. LeBaron (1996): A Test for Independence based on the Correlation Dimension. Econometric Reviews, 15:197-235. Brooks, C. (2008): Introductory Econometrics for Finance. (New York: Cambridge University Press). Campbell, John Y., and Andrew W. Lo, A Craig MacKinlay (2007): The Econometrics of Financial Markets, (New Delhi: New Age International). Cole, Shawn (2009): Futures Price Information for Farmers. Paper presented at the conference on Risk Mitigation in Agriculture, Organised by IFMR, Chennai, SEWA Bank, Gujarat, August, 2009. Dey, Kushankur and D. Maitra (2011): Price Discovery and Market Efficiency Revisited: Anecdotes from the Indian Commodity Futures Markets, Commodity Vision, 4(4): 22-34. Economic Survey of India (2009-10): Agriculture and Food Management, Union Budget and Economic Survey, Ministry of Finance, Govt. of India, Viewed on 3 March 2011 (http://indiabudget.nic.in/es2009-10/esmain.htm on 03.03..2011) Enders, W. (1995): Applied Econometric Time Series (New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.). Engle, R F and C .W. J. Granger (1987): Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing, Econometrica, 55 (2): 251-276. Fernandes, K. and N. Mor (2009): Risk Management for the Small Farmer in Kaul (ed.) India Commodity Year Book 2009, (Mumbai: National Collateral Management Services Limited) 6873. Financial Technology Group Knowledge Management Company (2011): History of Commodity Futures in India retrieved on 5 May 2011 (www.ftkmc.com/.../2008//.../History_of_Commodity_Futures_in_India.ppt) Forward Markets Commission (FMC, (2002): Market Review, 44(1). French, K. R. (1980): Stock Returns and the Weekend Effect, Journal of Financial Economics, 8:55-69. French, R., and R. Roll (1986): Stock Return Variances: The Arrival of Information and the Reaction of Traders, Journal of Financial Economics, 17:5-26.

Page 24 of 28

Ghosh, N. (2009): Issues and Concerns of Commodity Derivative Markets in India: An Agenda for Research. Commodity Vision, 3(4): 8-19. Ghosh, N. (2009): Market Microstructure in the Indian Context, Commodity Vision, 2(4):10-17 Gujarati, D. N. (2006): Basic Econometrics (New Delhi: Tata McGraw-Hill Inc.) Gulati, A. (2002): Indian Agriculture in a Globalizing World. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 84(3): 754-761. Gupta, K and B. Singh (2009): Estimating the Optimal Hedge Ratio in the Indian Equity Futures Market, IUP Journal of Financial Risk Management, 6(3&4):38-98 Hamilton, J. (1994): Time Series Analysis (Princeton: Princeton University Press.) Harris, L. (2002): Trading and Exchanges: Market Microstructure for Practitioners (New York: Oxford University Press.) Hull, J. C. (2007): Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives (New Delhi: Prentice Hall India) Jegadeesh, N. and S. Titman (1993): Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance, 48:65-91. Johansen, S and K. Juselius (1990): Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration with Applications to the Demand for Money, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52 (2): 169-210. Kalavathi L. and L. Shanker (1991). Margin Requirements and the Demand for Futures Contracts, Journal of Futures Market, 11(2):213-237. Kaul, S. (2007): Commodity Futures Trading in India: Myths and Misconceptions, Working Paper, NCDEX Institute of Commodity Markets and Research (NICR), Viewed on 29 October 2009 (http://www.nicrindia.com/wfrmRPAReport.aspx?id=72&type=Articles). Kolamkar, S.D. (2003): Regulation and Policy Issues of Commodity Derivatives in India, Viewed on 11 May 2011(http://www.igidr.ac.in/~susant/DERBOOK/PAPERS/dsk_draft1.pdf ) Kyle, A.S. (1985): Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading, Econometrica, 53:1315-1336. Kumar, B. and A. Pandey (2009): Role of Indian Commodity Derivatives Market in Hedging Price Risk: Estimation of Constant and Dynamic Hedge Ratio and Hedging Effectiveness, Viewed on 20 January 2011 ( http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1452881) Labys, W.C. (1980): Commodity Price Stabilization Models: A Review and Appraisal. Journal of Policy Modeling, 2(1): 121-136.

Page 25 of 28

Madhavan, A. (2000): Market Microstructure: A Survey, Journal of Financial Markets, 3:205258.

Multi Commodity Exchange (2008): Enabling Farmers to Leverage Commodity Exchanges, Viewed on 1 March 2011 (http://www.mcxindia.com/knowledgehub/casestudy/PDF/FarmersParticipationMCXReport12A ug08.pdf) Merton, R.C. (1973b): Theory of Rational Option Pricing, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 4(1):141-183. Naik, Gopal and S.K. Jain (2002), Indian Agricultural Commodity Futures Market, Economic and Political Weekly, 37 (30): 3161-3173. Nair, C. K. G. (2004): Commodity Futures Markets in India: Ready for Take-Off?, Viewed on 21 February, 2011 (http://www.nseindia.com/content/press/jul2004a.pdf) Newbery, M.G.N. and J. Stiglitz (1981): The Theory of Commodity Price Stabilization (Oxford University Press: Oxford) 1-55. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (2000): Income Risk Management in Agriculture (Publication Division: Paris), 43. Pavaskar, M. (2008): Ring System Required for Farm Futures, Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63(1). Pavaskar, M. 2(4):18-20. Pradhan, R. P. (2009): Stock Price and Macroeconomic Indicators in India: Evidence from Causality and Co-integration Analysis, Advanced Data Analysis, Business Analytics and Intelligence Workshop, Indian Institute of Management-Ahmedabad, Viewed on 20 May 2010 (www.iimahd.ernet.in/icadabai2009/DVDBrochure.pdf). Raipuria, K. (2002): Report of the Group on Forward and Futures Markets (Chairman, Kalyan Raipuria), Government of India. Raju, T. and K. Karande (2003): Price Discovery and Volatility on NSE Futures Market, SEBI-Working Paper Series, 7:1-16. (2009): Market Microstructure: Another Perspective, Commodity Vision,

Page 26 of 28

Ramaswami, B. and J. B. Singh (2007): "Hedging and the Emergence of Commodity Futures: The Soya Oil Exchange in India, Review of Futures Markets, 16 (1):33-54. Rogalski, R. (1984): New Findings Regarding Day-of-the-Week Returns Over Trading and Non-trading Periods: A Note, Journal of Finance, 35:1603-1614. Roll, R. (1984): A Simple Implicit Measure of the Effects of Bid-Ask Spread in an Efficient Market, Journal of Finance, 23:1127-1139. Roy, A. (2008): Dynamics of Spot and Future Markets in Indian Wheat Market: Issues and Implications, Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad, Viewed on 12 March 2011 (http://ssrn.com/abstract==1178762). Rutten, L. (2009): Researching Commodity Futures Markets in Pavaskar et al. (ed.) Effects of Futures Markets on Agricultural Commodities (Mumbai: Takshashila Academia of Economic Research) 41-51. Sabnavis, M. (2011): Commodity Inflation Dynamics in the Indian Economy in Kaul (ed.) India Commodity Year Book 2011 (Mumbai: National Collateral Management Services Limited) 101-117. Sen et al., (2008): Expert Committee to Study the Impact of Futures Trading on Agricultural Commodity Prices, The Expert Committee Report, Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food & Public Distribution, New Delhi, Viewed on 4 September 2009 ( http://www.fmc.gov.in/htmldocs/Abhijit %20Sen%20Report.pdf) Shinoj, P. and V.C. Mathur (2008): Comparative Advantage of India in Agricultural Exports vis--vis Asia: A Post-reforms Analysis, Agricultural Economics Research Review, 21:60-66. Telser L.G. (1981): Margins and Futures Contract, Journal of Futures Market, 1(3):225-253. Thomas, S. (2003), Agricultural Commodity Markets in India: Policy Issues for Growth, accessed on 21.01.2011 2011(http://www.igidr.ac.in/~susant/PDFDOCS/Thomas2003_commoditiesmkts_wb.pdf) United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) (1996): Collateralized Commodity Financing with Special Reference to the Use of Warehouse Receipts, GE.9651241/COM/84. Waugh, F.V. (1944): Does the Consumer Benefit from Price Instability? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58:602-614.

Page 27 of 28

World Bank (1999): Commodity Risk Management in Developing Countries: A Proposed Market-Based Approach and its Relevance for Small States Viewed on 20 December 2010 (http://siteresources.worldbank.org/PROJECTS/Resources/commoditypriceriskmanagement.pdf) .

Page 28 of 28

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi