Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 20

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

Contents 1 Introduction 2 Overview 3 Introduction to equity risk premiums 4 Ex-post equity risk premiums 8 Ex-ante equity risk premiums 9 The real-time equity risk premium 13 Conclusion 14 References 16 About the authors

Introduction

The real-time equity risk premium (RTERP) model is a dened process for estimating a customized ex-ante equity risk premium (ERP) in real time or as of any user-specied historical date within the past ve years. The RTERP is an integrated, software-based model with a related database that processes certain market data from third-party data services and employs a proprietary algorithm to determine the ex-ante ERP estimate. The RTERP also provides size and industry risk premium estimates, along with descriptive statistical information such as graphs and charts.

Risk premiums change over time as 1) the risk inherent in both the overall economy and the equity market changes, and 2) investors respond to equity market conditions by requiring different rates of return in exchange for taking risks. Ex-post methods of estimating ERP generally do not consider prevailing equity market conditions at or near the valuation date. Until now, there has been no readily available source for calculating the ex-ante ERP in real time or as of a specied date. The RTERP provides this source.

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 1

Overview

The equity risk premium (ERP) represents the expected rate of return on stocks in excess of the risk-free rate. The ERP is a key component in deriving discount rates. For decades, the ERP concept has been debated by academics and practitioners because no method is universally accepted or used for deriving the ERP. The ERP is typically estimated based on the average historical return of equity securities in excess of the risk-free rate. The ERP is calculated on an annual basis over a long-term historical period. This approach is commonly known as the expost method. The ex-post method has drawn signicant criticism in nance literature as a result of several faulty assumptions explored in this paper. The most basic of these assumptions is that historical returns are equal to investors expectations regarding future returns. However, the ERP represents the returns investors expect to achieve, meaning that ex-post returns provide only a historical data point that may or may not represent investors expectations. Hence, many studies have concluded that the ex-post method does not provide a reliable indication of the ERP, as we describe in this paper. A forward-looking ERP can be determined by using observable market data to extrapolate the future returns expected by investors. This concept is known as the ex-ante method. In a 2005 article, Roger Grabowski addresses the reasoning behind using the ex-ante method:
ERP is a forward-looking concept, as it is an expectation of the valuation date for which no market quotes are observable. While you can observe premiums realized over time by referring to historical data, such calculated premiums serve only as estimates for the expected ERP. If we are to truly mimic the market, then our goal should be to estimate the true expected ERP as of the valuation date. To do that, you need to look beyond the realized premiums (Grabowski, 2005).

Ex-ante methods for estimating the ERP have been published by Brav, Chen, Damodaran, Fama, French, Ibbotson and many other economists, nance professionals and academics. Their estimates provide useful data points for demonstrating ex-ante ERPs. However, no process or system reliably calculates an ex-ante ERP as of a specic date. The timeliest source currently available is a monthly publication. As a result, practitioners generally estimate an ERP based on a qualitative assessment of dated results from ex-post and exante ERP studies. In this paper, Grant Thornton LLP (Grant Thornton) introduces the real-time equity risk premium (RTERP). The RTERP is a dened process for estimating a customized ex-ante ERP in real time or as of any user-specied historical date within the past ve years. The RTERP is an integrated, software-based model with a related database that processes certain market data from third-party data services and employs a proprietary algorithm to determine the ex-ante ERP estimate. The RTERP also provides size and industry risk premium estimates, along with descriptive statistical information such as graphs and charts. Grant Thornton has submitted an application with the U.S. Patent and Trademark Ofce for a patent on this intellectual property.

2 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

Introduction to equity risk premiums

The ERP is the expected future rate of return on equity securities in excess of the risk-free rate. The expected return has far-reaching economic and nancial implications for corporations, governments and individuals, because ERP estimates are used for allocating capital, pricing assets and determining quantities reserved for future obligations. The ERP represents a key assumption in almost every method of deriving discount rates for asset pricing, including the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), the arbitrage pricing model, the multifactor model, the build-up method and others. These discount rates have a direct and signicant effect on the value assigned to specic assets and liabilities and thus on corporate investment decisions related to projects and acquisitions. Estimates of expected returns drive investment decisions regarding how capital resources are allocated across geographies, industries, asset classes and specic investments. Such decisions are relevant to all investors: governments, private enterprises and individuals. Estimates of expected future returns also represent a critical assumption for governments, individuals and corporations when they are determining the amounts required to meet future obligations such as health care, retirement, asset decommissioning and debt payments, to name a few.

In summary, it is both fundamental and essential for professionals who measure value in our economy to estimate an accurate ERP. A signicant body of research has been developed regarding efforts to quantify the ERP. This research typically falls into one of three groups:
1. Surveys The reporting of ERP estimates based on

surveys conducted by investors, academics and nancial professionals.


2. Ex-post method The derivation of ERP estimates based

on historical returns of equity securities in excess of the risk-free rate.


3. Ex-ante method The derivation of the ERP implied by

current market prices and expected future benets (e.g., dividends, stock appreciation). Few practitioners rely on surveys for precision. While ERP surveys are useful for gauging the general range of ERPs used by various groups, they lack any direct, quantiable link to the economy or the capital markets. Many qualitative issues exist with surveys, including how questions are presented, the prole of the respondents, and the timing of the survey. As noted by Damodaran (2010), studies have provided evidence that surveys lack positive predictive power regarding future stock returns and in fact may have an inverse relationship with them. Given the limited use of surveys, this paper focuses on ex-post and ex-ante ERP estimates.

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 3

Ex-post equity risk premiums

Reliable data to estimate the historical premium of stocks over bonds were only collected in the mid-20th century, and precise econometric estimates of the equity premium only came after the development of the theory that uses it as a central input the capital asset pricing model, or CAPM (Goetzmann and Ibbotson, 2005). Since then, the most commonly cited ERP has been the ex-post premium. Until recently, the ex-post premium was considered to be the best available option because of the weaknesses of surveys and the lack of available information required to construct an ex-ante ERP. While ex-post premiums have been used in academia and practice over several decades, recent research has begun to address the problems of the ex-post premium. We summarize the primary issues with ex-post estimates in the following discussion.
Actual versus expected returns

Ex-post ERPs are based on the premise that past performance is a valid proxy for expectations regarding future results. However, several studies have noted that realized returns are a noisy proxy for expected stock returns (Black, 1986; Merton, 1980; French, Schwert and Stambaugh, 1987; Asness, 2000). Further, signicant evidence from several studies indicates that historical returns do not reect investors actual expectations and that ex-post ERP estimates are a poor predictor of future returns. In their seminal work, Mehra and Prescott (1985) observed that the high historical returns provided by equities relative to government bonds is inexplicable and implies abnormally high risk aversion in the context of standard economics models. This inexplicably high return on equities relative to government bonds became known as the equity risk premium puzzle. According to many economists, the puzzle provides evidence that historical returns have been signicantly higher than expected returns and, therefore, ex-post estimates do not reect expected returns.

Using evidence from equity fundamentals such as Sharpe ratios, book-to-market ratios, and income return on investment, Fama and French (2002) concluded that the average stock return of the last half-century is a lot higher than expected. As a result, ex-post ERP measurements overstate the premium that investors expected at that time. In a 1993 publication, Blanchard, Shiller and Siegel concluded that the ex-post ERP 8.0 percent since 1926 and 6.5 percent since 1871 appears far in excess of what is justied by standard asset-pricing models with reasonable levels of risk aversion, given the behavior of the variancecovariance matrix of historical returns on bonds, stocks and consumption (Blanchard, Shiller, Siegel, 1993). Elton outlines instances in which observed returns did not align with the given risk of the investment. The McDonalds effect is one example. Data sets within the second half of the 20th century pertaining to the fast-food chain McDonalds had abnormally large returns relative to risk. Investors were consistently surprised at the earnings reported by McDonalds, and those earnings resulted in stock price appreciation above the expected level of returns. While McDonalds was a relatively new company when the earnings surprises were occurring, there is ample evidence that mature companies can also have unusually large returns relative to risk (Elton, 1999). Similar examples involve Atlantic Richeld with North Shore Oil, Pzer with Viagra, and certain corporate restructurings. Anomalies of this kind can also be observed in index returns, such as the 20 percent run-up of annual returns in the Japanese stock market from 1980 to 1990.

4 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

In addition, Elton (1999) asserts that ex-post ERP estimates falsely assume that information surprises cancel out over the measurement period and that realized returns are therefore an unbiased estimate of expected returns. Further, Elton cites ample evidence that this belief is misplaced and outlines certain time periods within markets when both stock and bond risk and return do not follow the sensible path. Examples of these periods include: periods longer than 10 years in which realized stock market returns are on average less than the risk-free rate (1973 1984); periods longer than 50 years in which risky long-term bonds on average underperform the risk-free rate (1927 1980); and periods during which U.S. equity markets returned over 15%, while the Japanese market experienced a negative return (19901999). The preceding discussion provides evidence that actual historical returns may not provide an accurate estimate of investors expectations about future returns.

Time-period sensitivity

Ex-post ERP measurements are sensitive to the time period selected for calculation of the premium. Ex-post studies of historical returns on stocks and bonds have been performed using periods as far back as the 1870s, while other such studies look at returns beginning in 1926 or in the mid-1950s and the 1960s. Each selected time period yields signicantly different ERP estimates. Because the state-of-the-art model assumes a constant variance rate, the large differences in variance rates among the various subperiods cause the models estimates to be quite sensitive to the time period of history used (Merton, 1980). The table illustrates the signicantly different results provided by ex-post ERP calculations using different historical time periods.
Time period 192620091 196320091 199720082 180218703 187119253 ERP estimate (arithmetic average) 6.66% 4.25% -3.68% 2.20% 2.90%

Sources: Morningstar Inc. Ibbotson SBBI 2010 Valuation Yearbook, 2010.; Duff & Phelps Risk Premium Report, 2010 Source: Damodaran, Aswath, Equity Risk Premiums (ERP): Determinants, Estimation and Implications The 2010 Edition Source: Siegel, Jeremy, Stocks for the Long Run, Second Edition, McGraw-Hill, 1998

Until recently, the ex-post premium was considered to be the best available option because of the weaknesses of surveys and the lack of available information required to construct an ex-ante ERP.

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 5

There has been signicant debate regarding which time period is most relevant for estimating the current ERP. Longer time periods are advocated by many analysts because of the reduced statistical noise associated with longer-term estimates, while shorter time periods are advocated by others who argue that risk aversion has changed over time, causing recent returns to better reect current investors expectations. However, the arguments presented by both sides of this debate provide evidence that neither side may be correct. The events and issues listed below are commonly cited as problems with certain historical time periods: The concentration of railroad stocks prior to the 1860s Regulatory changes in the NYSE in the 1860s The unreliability of data prior to 1926 The bull market of the late 1920s followed by the 1929 stock market crash The postwar economic boom in the 1930s and 1940s The low interest rates from the 1930s through the 1950s Dramatically rising interest rates since the 1950s Signicant changes in investment income tax structure since the 1950s Recent decades bond market volatility relative to more stable equity markets The high standard errors indicated in 10-year and 20-year estimates It is evident that every historical time period presents its own set of problems and results in a signicantly different ex-post ERP.

Statistical reliability

As previously noted, empirical studies have concluded that historical returns are a noisy proxy for expected future returns. The statistical noise can be measured using the standard errors in ex-post estimates. The table below illustrates the standard errors in these estimates for various time periods ending in 2009 (Damodaran, 2010).

Time period 5 years 10 years 25 years 50 years 80 years

Standard error (20% n)* 8.94% 6.32% 4.00% 2.83% 2.23%

* 20% represents the standard deviation in stock prices between 1926 and 2008. Damodaran (2010) notes that the standard errors are likely understated because they assume uncorrelated annual returns, while there is empirical evidence that these returns may be correlated over time.

As shown above, shorter time periods have extremely high standard errors. However, even the longer time periods have signicant standard errors relative to the size of the ERP itself.
Survivorship bias and special events

Historical stock market returns contain an upward survivorship bias. Goetzmann and Ibbotson (2005) provide evidence that ex-post ERP estimates are affected by these survival issues. Because the returns are measured by the performance of the S&P 500, there is a focus on surviving companies, and the failure of many rms is neglected. The survivorship bias is exacerbated by the focus on domestic U.S. markets, which represent the best-performing markets over the periods typically used for ex-post ERP estimates. The survivorship bias results in ERP estimates that exceed expected returns.

6 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

Geometric versus arithmetic mean

Volatility of expected returns

There is an ongoing debate over how to average historical data in calculating an ex-post ERP. Two schools of thought center on the geometric mean and the arithmetic mean. The geometric mean represents the compound annual return over the estimation period, while the arithmetic mean measures the simple average of annual returns over that period. Many believe that the geometric mean provides a better estimate of long-term returns, while the arithmetic mean provides a better estimate of the next periods returns. Neither averaging technique has been selected as the preferred method in practice. However, the two types of averaging result in extremely different ERP estimates (see below).
Time period ERP estimate (arithmetic average) 5.56% 4.09% -3.68% ERP estimate (geometric average) 4.29% 2.74% -7.22%

There is substantial evidence that expected returns change over time. In general, expected returns are lower when economic conditions are strong and higher when conditions are weak, as determined based on a statistical analysis of default spreads and dividend yields by Fama and French (1989).
[F]rom the work of Rosenberg (1972) and Black (1976) as well as many others, the hypothesis that the variance rate on the market remains constant over any appreciable period of time can be rejected at almost any condence level (Merton, 1980). Moreover, there are two schools of thought on how to explain the variation in expected returns. Some attribute it to rational variation in response to macroeconomic factors [Fama and French (1989), Blanchard (1993) and Cochrane (1994)], while others judge that irrational swings in investor sentiment are the prime moving force [e.g., Shiller (1989)] (Fama and French, 2002).

19282008 19672008 19972008

However, regardless of the underlying reason for the variation in the ERP, the ex-post method cannot provide results reecting expected returns, which are constantly changing. Long-term averages used in the ex-post method smooth the variation in expected returns and conceal the true ERP.

Source: Damodaran, Aswath, Equity Risk Premiums (ERP): Determinants, Estimation and Implications The 2010 Edition

The averaging problem presents another unresolved dilemma with ex-post estimates, where the various options result in different ERP indications.

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 7

Ex-ante equity risk premiums

The problems with ex-post ERP estimates are welldocumented in economic and nancial literature. Ex-ante ERP estimates avoid those problems, while providing a more theoretically sound and measurable estimate of returns expected by investors at the relevant date. Some authors, including Fama and French (2002) and Claus and Thomas (2001), provide empirical evidence that ex-ante ERP estimates are more accurate than ex-post estimates based on standard errors, ratio analyses and valuation theory. However, most practitioners have been forced to use realized returns as a proxy for expected returns because of the lack of data required to determine an ex-ante ERP. Fortunately, the amount of relevant data has increased signicantly over time, and research within the past several years has yielded substantial progress in developing ex-ante ERP estimates. Ex-ante ERP estimates are derived by populating generally accepted nancial and economic models such as the CAPM, utility functions and the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) with observable market data and then solving for the ERP as the remaining unknown variable.

Economic variables such as trading prices, dividend yields, forward-looking analyst estimates, volatility and default spreads can be used to derive market evidence of investors expected returns. This is done by applying the variables to demand-side models such as the CAPM, utility functions or the APT. Most ex-ante studies have compared future economic benets expected from stocks (e.g., dividends, earnings, stock appreciation) with their observable market prices to solve for the expected percentage rate of return. The ERP is then determined by using demand-side models such as the CAPM and APT, in which all inputs are observable except the ERP itself.

8 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

The real-time equity risk premium

The RTERP is a dened process by which the ex-ante ERP may be estimated in real time or as of a historical date specied by the user. The RTERP is an integrated, software-based model with a related database that processes certain market data from third-party data services and uses that data, along with a proprietary algorithm, to determine the ex-ante ERP estimate. The RTERP output also includes size and industry risk premium estimates, along with descriptive statistical information such as graphs and charts. The integrated database stores output from the model as of the end of each trading day in order to make historical output available without rerunning the entire RTERP process. The RTERP has a graphical user interface and may be made available through the Internet, intranets, third-party database queries (e.g., an application programming interface), or a prepackaged software application.

Model overview

The RTERP model employs a bottom-up approach to calculating an ex-ante ERP, as follows:
1. Determining the long-term expected rate of return for each

constituent of a market index such as the S&P 500. This calculation is based on the internal rate of return (IRR) required to reconcile each constituents stock price with the present value of future cash ows, based on consensus analyst estimates.
2. Estimating the long-term expected rate of return on the

index by calculating a market capitalization-weighted average of the IRRs identied in step 1 above. The expected rate of return on the index represents the implied cost of equity capital for the index.
3. Applying the CAPM framework to solve for the implied

ERP. The risk-free rate is subtracted from the index-level cost of equity to estimate the ERP. The RTERP process is agnostic with regard to the sources of market data. Bloomberg, Morningstar, Thomson Financial Network, Reuters, Edgar Online, Capital IQ, Standard & Poors, and Compustat top the list of reliable data sources.

The RTERP is a dened process by which the ex-ante ERP may be estimated in real time or as of a historical date specied by the user.

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 9

IRR for index constituents

As described on the previous page, using a bottom-up ERP model involves calculating the implied cost of equity for each index constituent. That amount can be determined by solving for the discount rate (in this case, the IRR) that makes the present value of future cash ows equal to the companys stock price. The resulting discount rate represents the implied cost of equity, assuming that consensus analyst estimates represent the general expectations of the market. Cash ows From a fundamental perspective, the economic returns to equity holders can be measured by free cash ow to equity (FCFE), dened as after-tax operating cash ow less capital expenditures and debt principal payments. FCFE is available to return value to equity holders in the form of dividends, share buybacks, growth through acquisitions, and risk reduction by means of holding additional cash reserves. The RTERP uses FCFE forecasts as the primary measure of expected future returns. The data necessary to calculate FCFE forecasts are pulled from a third-party database of consensus analyst estimates (e.g., Thomson Reuters, Capital IQ). The forecasted components of FCFE are available for the majority of index constituents. For companies that do not have consensus estimates for their FCFE components, the RTERP uses earnings per share (EPS) as a proxy for cash ows. Finally, for companies that do not have FCFE or EPS consensus estimates, the RTERP uses dividends per share (DPS) estimates. FCFE, EPS and DPS are referred to collectively as cash ow measures. Utilities and nancial institutions generally do not have FCFE estimates available through the data sources mentioned above. Given that these companies typically issue dividendpaying stocks, DPS estimates are used in lieu of FCFE and EPS, because DPS estimates provide the most relevant measure of cash ows expected by investors in these companies. The cash ow measures are stated on a per-share basis for purposes of reconciling with stock prices in IRR calculations.
10 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

Stock prices The stock price of each index constituent, as of the date of the ERP estimate, is pulled from a data source. IRR calculations IRR calculations are performed in the context of a discounted future cash ow (DCF) analysis. The RTERP uses a threestage DCF model: First stage Discrete period forecasts of cash ow measures are based on consensus analyst estimates as of the date of the ERP estimate. The forecast horizon is ve years. For companies without ve years of analyst estimates available, the RTERP estimates the remaining discrete periods based on each companys growth rate in the latest forecasted period available. Blanchard (1993) suggests that a DCF is likely to be a good approximation of expected rates of return over nite but sufciently long periods say, ve years or more. Second stage For RTERP modeling purposes, the smoothing period represents the second stage, in which growth transitions in a linear manner from the discretely forecasted periods to the stable growth rate used in the terminal period. The model assumes a two-year smoothing period. The rather smooth transition toward the long-run growth rate is probably a more realistic assumption than the sudden change in the twostage model (Schrder 2007). An H-model is used to implement the smoothing period during the sixth and seventh years. Third stage This stage represents the terminal value (i.e., the present value of cash ows from the eighth year into perpetuity). Cash ows are capitalized using a Gordon growth model with a terminal growth rate equal to the risk-free rate, as measured by the yield on 20-year U.S. government bonds as of the date of the risk premium estimate.

The three-stage DCF model for calculating the IRR is as follows:


S= CF1 CF2 CF3 CF4 CF5 1 CF5 H (gS - gL) CF5 (1+gL) + + + + + + (1+k) (1+k)2 (1+k)3 (1+k)4 (1+k)5 (1+k)5 (k - gL) (k - gL)

Market capitalization and the weighted average

S = Stock price at the date of the risk premium estimate CFt = Forecasted cash ow measure for year t gS = Short-term growth rate during the smoothing period of the H-model: gS = CF5 1 CF4

After the implied cost of equity is calculated for all market index constituents, the index-level cost of equity is calculated based on the market capitalization-weighted average cost of equity. Each index constituents market capitalization is pulled from a data source and used to weight the respective costs of equity in calculating the weighted average. That weighted average represents the implied expected return on the index.
ERP estimates and the CAPM framework

gL = Long-term projected growth rate into perpetuity H = Half-life of the smoothing period stated in years (i.e., for a two-year smoothing period, H = 1) k = IRR, also the cost-of-equity component

The observed market inputs are applied in an IRR calculation using the above framework to solve for k, which represents the implied cost of equity for the subject stock. This calculation is performed for each constituent of the market index.

The CAPM framework provides an analytical basis for determining the ERP from the index-level rate of return implied by observable market data. The indexs IRR is then applied to the CAPM in the following manner:
ki = Rf + *(ERP)
ki = Cost of equity capital (i.e., the index-level expected rate of return) Rf = The risk-free rate, assumed to equal the yield on 20-year U.S. government bonds as of the date of the risk premium estimate. = Market beta dened as 1 because the index is considered to be the market ERP = Equity risk premium

Given that beta is equal to 1 for the index, the CAPM formula is simplied to the following:
ki = Rf + ERP

The RTERP model solves for the ex-ante ERP by deducting the risk-free rate from ki:
ERP = ki - Rf

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 11

Size premium estimates

Industry risk premium estimates

Practitioners frequently use data sources that provide size premiums based on the excess historical returns of small stocks relative to the returns calculated using the CAPM. These historical measures have most of the same weaknesses as ex-post ERP estimates described earlier in this paper. An ex-ante size premium estimate can be calculated in much the same way as an ex-ante ERP estimate. The following steps are used by the RTERP to calculate ex-ante size premiums:
1. Computing the long-term expected rate of return for the

Currently, practitioners use data sources that provide industry risk premiums based on historical returns. Again, however, these measures have most of the weaknesses of ex-post ERP estimates. An ex-ante industry risk premium estimate can be calculated in much the same way as an ex-ante size premium estimate. The following steps are used by the RTERP to calculate ex-ante industry risk premiums:
1. Computing the long-term expected rate of return for the

market index based on the market capitalization-weighted average IRR for index constituents (see the calculation referred to above).
2. Determining the long-term expected rate of return for a

market index based on the market capitalization-weighted average IRR for the index constituents (see the calculation referred to above).
2. Determining the long-term expected rate of return for an

small company group by using the IRR calculation and weighted average referred to above. The constituents of the small company group are not required to be constituents of the index. Size can be measured by several characteristics: market capitalization, enterprise value, total assets, book value, revenue, various earnings measures and nancial ratios, and other indicators.
3. Calculating the implied size premium as the excess of the

industry group by using the IRR calculation and weighted average referred to above. The constituents of the industry group are not required to be constituents of the index.
3. Calculating the implied industry premium as the excess of

the expected return for the industry group relative to the index.

expected return for the small company group relative to the index.

12 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

Conclusion

It is vital to estimate expected equity returns properly, because these estimates have far-reaching economic and nancial implications for corporations, governments and individuals across all sectors of the global economy. Expected returns affect critical decisions such as allocating capital resources, pricing assets, and determining quantities reserved for future obligations. The RTERP is an innovative process that uses software and database programming, combined with economic and nancial modeling, to provide estimates of the ex-ante ERP and size and industry risk premiums, along with relevant graphs and statistics. The RTERP represents the only available source for ex-ante risk premiums in real time or as of a historical date specied by the user. The RTERP has a graphical user interface and may be made available through the Internet, intranets, third-party database queries (via an application programming interface), or prepackaged software applications. In summary, the RTERP provides more accurate ERP estimates than were previously available. As a result, investors, academics, practitioners and governments may be able to improve their ability to estimate key inputs affecting important decisions.

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 13

References

Asness, Clifford, Stocks Versus Bonds: Explaining the Equity Risk Premium, Financial Analysts Journal 96, 56-2, March-April 2000. Black, Fischer, Noise, Journal of Finance, pp. 529543, 41-3, 1986. Blanchard, Olivier J.; Shiller, Robert; and Siegel, Jeremy J., Movements in the Equity Premium, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, pp. 75138, 1993. Booth, Laurence, The Capital Asset Pricing Model + Equity Risk Premiums and the Privately Held Business, CICBV/ASA Joint Business Valuation Conference paper, p. 23, September 1998. Brav, Alon; Lehavy, Reuven; and Michaely, Roni, Expected Return and Asset Pricing, Duke University, University of Michigan and Cornell University, 2002. Campbell, John Y., and Shiller, Robert J., The Dividend-Price Ratio and Expectations of Future Dividends and Discount Factors, Review of Financial Studies 1, pp. 195228, 1989. Claus, James, and Thomas, Jacob, The Equity Risk Premium Is Much Lower Than You Think It Is: Empirical Estimates From a New Approach, Columbia Business School, 1999. Claus, James, and Thomas, Jacob, Equity Premia as Low as Three Percent? Evidence From Analysts Earnings Forecasts for Domestic and International Stock Markets. The Journal of Finance, pp. 16291666, Vol. 56, No. 5, October 2001. Cochrane, John H., Permanent and Transitory Components of GNP and Stock Prices, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, pp. 241265, 1994.

Damodaran, Aswath, Equity Risk Premiums (ERP): Determinants, Estimation and Implications The 2010 Edition, Stern School of Business, February 2010. Dimson, Elroy; Marsh, Paul; and Staunton, Mike, Global Evidence on the Equity Premium, The Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15-4, Summer 2003. Duff & Phelps Risk Premium Report, 2008. Duff & Phelps Risk Premium Report, 2010. Elton, Edwin J., Expected Return, Realized Return, and Asset Pricing Tests, Journal of Finance, pp. 11991220, 54-4, 1999. Fama, Eugene, and French, Kenneth, The Equity Premium, Journal of Finance 637, 75-2, April 2002. Fama, Eugene, and French, Kenneth, The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Finance, pp. 427465, 47-2, 1992. Fama, Eugene F., and French, Kenneth R., Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Financial Economics, pp. 326, Vol. 22, No. 1, October 1988. Fama, Eugene F., and French, Kenneth R., Business Conditions and Expected Returns on Stocks and Bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 25, pp. 2349, 1989. Freeman, Mark, Explaining the Declining Ex-Ante Equity Risk Premium, School of Business and Economics at the University of Exeter, 2004. French, Kenneth R.; Schwert, G. William; and Stambaugh, Robert F., Expected Stock Returns and Volatility, Journal of Financial Economics, pp. 329, Vol. 19, No. 1, January 1987.

14 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

Goetzmann, William N., and Ibbotson, Roger G., History and the Equity Risk Premium, p. 8, Yale ICF Working Paper No. 05-04, April 2005. Grabowski, Roger, Equity Risk Premium: What Is the Current Evidence? Business Valuation Update, Vol. 11, No. 11, (November 2005. Graham, John, and Harvey, Campbell, Expectations of Equity Risk Premia, Volatility and Asymmetry From a Corporate Finance Perspective, National Bureau of Economic Research working paper, December 2001. Updated quarterly by Duke/ CFO Magazine Global Business Outlook Survey (www.cfosurvey.org). Graham, John, and Harvey, Campbell, The Theory and Practice of Corporate Finance: Evidence From the Field, Journal of Financial Economics 60, pp. 187243, 2001. Ibbotson, Roger G., and Chen, Peng, Long-Run Stock Returns: Participating in the Real Economy, Financial Analysts Journal 88, pp. 9096, Vol. 59, No. 1, January/February 2003. Updated in Stocks, Bonds, Bills and Ination, Valuation Edition, 2005 Yearbook (Ibbotson Associates, 2005). Lui, Kevin, and Subramanian, Savita, Quantitative Proles, Merrill Lynch Quantitative Strategy Report, Jan. 10, 2007. Mehra, Rajnish, The Equity Premium: Why Is It a Puzzle? Financial Analysts Journal 59, pp. 5469, January/February 2003. Mehra, Rajnish, and Prescott, E.C., The Equity Premium: A Puzzle, Journal of Monetary Economics 15, pp. 145161, 1985. Merton, Robert C., On Estimating the Expected Return on the Market, Journal of Financial Economics, pp. 323361, Vol. 8, No. 4, June 1980.

Morningstar Inc. Ibbotson Risk Premia Over Time Report, 2008. Morningstar Inc. Ibbotson SBBI 2010 Valuation Yearbook, 2010. Michaely, Roni, and Womack, Kent L., Conict of Interest and the Credibility of Underwriter Analyst Recommendations, Review of Financial Studies, pp. 653686, 12-4, 1999. Miller, Merton, and Modigliani, Franco, Dividends Policy, Growth and the Valuation of Shares, Journal of Business, pp. 411433, Vol. 34, No. 4, October 1961. Schrder, David, The Implied Equity Risk Premiums: An Evaluation of Empirical Methods, Bonn Graduate School of Economics, 2007. Shiller, Robert, Market Volatility (MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.), 1989. Subramanian, Savita, Quantitative Strategy Update, Merrill Lynch Quantitative Strategy Report, Aug. 1, 2007. Wadhwani, Sushil, The Stock Market, Capacity Uncertainties and the Outlook for UK Ination, Edinburgh University Economics Society, Nov. 21, 2001. Welch, Ivo, The Equity Premium Consensus Forecast Revisited, Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1325, September 2001. Womack, Kent L., Do Brokerage Analysts Recommendations Have Investment Value? Journal of Finance, pp. 137167, 51-1, March 1996.

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 15

About the authors

Bryan Benoit Partner, Valuation Services and Central Region Leader T 832.476.3620 E Bryan.Benoit@gt.com Bryan Benoit is a Valuation Services partner in Grant Thorntons Advisory Services practice in Houston. He has more than 20 years of experience and specializes in the valuation of complex businesses and assets. A specialist in corporate nance and accounting, Benoit is familiar with business and asset valuations related to transactions, estate and gift tax, family limited partnerships, corporate tax, transfer pricing, international tax, litigation support, and nancial reporting. Prior to joining Grant Thornton as a partner, Benoit was the managing director in charge of the Houston ofce of Standard & Poors and Duff & Phelps. Benoit has provided consulting services to clients in numerous industries, including energy, consumer and industrial products, computer software and hardware, integrated health care, life sciences, telecommunications, and nancial services. Benoit is the author of a number of published works and seminars and has been quoted in The Wall Street Journal, Bloomberg and Harvard Business School case studies.

Taylor West Senior Manager, Valuation Services T 832.476.3722 E Taylor.West@gt.com Taylor West is a Valuation Services senior manager in Grant Thorntons Advisory Services practice in Houston. West has 10 years of corporate advisory experience focused on the valuation of corporate securities, partnership interests, and intangible assets of privately held and publicly traded businesses. His valuation projects relate to M&A, nancial and tax reporting, litigation, and general corporate planning. West also manages projects involving forensic accounting, litigation consulting and intellectual asset management.

16 The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction

The real-time equity risk premium: An introduction 17

Valuation practice leaders


National Partner-in-Charge Neil Beaton 206.398.2487 Atlanta Steven Krug 404.475.0041 Boston James Dondero 617.848.4890 Cincinnati Chuck Williams 513.345.4542 Charlotte Mark Edwards 704.632.6926 Chicago Massimo Messina 312.602.8247 Dallas Todd Patrick 214.283.8195 Detroit Phil Gaglio 248.213.4219 Houston Bryan Benoit 832.476.3620 Los Angeles Edward Karstetter 213.596.6762 McLean Venkat Komarlingam 703.847.7656 Milwaukee Dean Polenz 414.277.1512 Minneapolis Mark Gehrig 612.677.5139 New York John Ferro 212.542.9574 Philadelphia Rich Hause 215.814.4024 San Jose Jim Walling 408.216.8520 San Francisco Andrew Ross 415.365.5405 Seattle Robert Duffy 206.398.2479

Content in this publication is not intended to answer specic questions or suggest suitability of action in a particular case. For additional information on the issues discussed, consult a Grant Thornton client service partner.

Grant Thornton LLP All rights reserved U.S. member rm of Grant Thornton International Ltd

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi