Explorer les Livres électroniques
Catégories
Explorer les Livres audio
Catégories
Explorer les Magazines
Catégories
Explorer les Documents
Catégories
Robert Boyer 2
Résumé
Le retour du capitalisme : Causes et conséquences pour les sciences sociales
Pourquoi le terme de capitalisme a été de plus en plus utilisé au cours de la dernière
décennie ? Comment les recherches en socio-économie pourraient-elles contribuer à
la compréhension des diverses variantes du capitalisme ? En réponse à ces deux
questions, l’article s’attache à montrer que le concept de capitalisme n’est pas
équivalent à celui d’économie de marché car il invite à étudier les relations sociales et
le changement qui sont constitutifs de ce régime économique. Les années 90
marquent un changement majeur dans l’analyse des sociétés contemporaines car la
capacité du capitalisme à innover, à bouleverser les formes d’organisation et les
institutions et à déborder les frontières nationales constitue autant de traits distinctifs
qui sont au cœur des travaux fondateurs de l’économie politique. Compte tenu de la
multiplicité des composantes et des facettes du capitalisme, la plupart des sciences
sociales peuvent utilement éclairer ce régime complexe et évolutif, qu’il s’agisse du
droit, de l’histoire économique, de la science politique, de la sociologie, de la théorie
économique ou des analyses du changement technique. L’essentiel de l’article est
alors consacré à une brève revue de la littérature sur les mérites et limites comparés
de trois programmes de recherche : la sociologie économique, la nouvelle économie
politique et la théorie de la régulation. Il en ressort que ces trois approches peuvent
être rendues complémentaires. Ce pronostic pourrait favoriser une nouvelle
génération de travaux régulationnistes.
Mots clés
économie de marché, capitalisme, sociologie économique, nouvelle économie
politique, théorie de la Régulation, économie institutionnelle
1 This article develops a presentation prepared for the conference “Economic Sociology and Political
Economy”. First Max Planck Summer Conference on Economy and Society, Villa Vigoni, Italy, July 15-18th,
2006. The author thanks the participants of the conference and two referees for their useful comments. Version
5 after referees, editorial committee requirements, English editing and final proposal by the author
2 PSE - PARIS-JOURDAN SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES Joint Research Unit CNRS-EHESS-
ENPC-ENS) 48, Boulevard Jourdan 75014 PARIS, France Phone: (33-1) 43 13 62 56 — Fax: (33-1)
43 13 62 59 e-mail: robert.boyer@ens.fr web site: http://www.jourdan.ens.fr/~boyer
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
Abstract
This article addresses a twofold issue: why the word capitalism has become more and
more frequently used during the last decade? How could socio-economic researches
contribute to understanding of the contemporary transformations of the various
brands of capitalism? First, it is argued that the concept of capitalism is not
equivalent to the concept of market economy since it also refers to the study of
social relations and dynamic patterns of evolution. Second, the 90s were probably a
turning point in the analysis of contemporary societies since the built-in propensity
of capitalism to innovate and ability to propel structural change and promote
globalization, are easy to recognize. Third, given the multifaceted aspects of
capitalism, all social sciences (legal studies, economic history, political sciences,
sociology, economic theory, technical change analysis…) do shed some light upon
this complex and evolving regime. The bulk of the paper then surveys both the
contribution and weaknesses of economic sociology and new political economy and
proposes a research agenda in which their respective programs provide a
complementary analysis of contemporary structural transformations of capitalism.
Regulation theory is part of such a research agenda and could itself benefit from
such a joint venture.
Key words
market economy, capitalism, economic sociology, new political economy, Régulation
theory,institutional economics
J.E.L. Classification : B25 - B41 - B52 – K00 – N00 – O11 – P10 – P17 – Z1
2
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
Robert Boyer
Introduction
It is not an easy task to speak about capitalism, neither as a concept of social science,
nor as a really existing economic regime. Didn’t Marx build an entire theory of
capitalism that concluded to the irreversible deepening of contradictions, structural
crises and conflicts of the economic system built upon the domination of capital
accumulation? Now economists, even sympathetic with the Marxist approach,
recognize that the demonstration exhibited a lot of flaws and economic history
research has shown the noticeable resilience of market economies even to major
financial crises. At the other extreme of the methodological spectrum, neoclassical
economists never used, and still most of them do not use, the notion of capitalism,
since for them it is basically an ideological term that brings a critical assessment and a
political flavor to the cold and rigorous analysis of market economies that should be
the unique preoccupation of economic theories.
Back in the 1960s, the term capitalism was rarely used. It is no longer the case in the
2000s. A brief test of the number of occurrences of the term “Capitalism” in the
content of Google Scholar shows an impressive explosion after 1989, usually
perceived as the epochal transformation where the adoption of capitalism and
democracy has become the only available horizon for contemporary societies (Table
1).
Table 1 – The number of annual references to capitalism in Google Scholar
1940-49 1950-59 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-03
71 114 102 189 331 1125 3248
Note: Since the number of Reviews covered increases with time, the series should not be over
interpreted.
This article proposes to investigate various facets of this explosion of references. (1)
First it is important to contrast a market economy approach with an analysis of
capitalism. (2) Second, the origins and the reasons for this renewed interest in this
quite complex concept are to be investigated. (3) The central message of this paper is
that understanding and explaining capitalism cannot be limited to a single discipline
since the very resilience of this economic regime derives from its embeddedness in
society and polity. (4) The rest of the paper is devoted to a comparative analysis of
three research programs. What does economic sociology capture as the core of
capitalism? (5) How to explain that State and more generally polity are so present in
modern capitalism at the very epoch of liberalization and globalization? (6) To what
extent is the “regulation theory” at the crossroads of the institutions and dynamics of
capitalism ? (7) A brief conclusion proposes some common research themes.
3
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
4
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
• The Great Transformation of the Soviet regime has challenged conventional thinking
that postulated that as soon as central planning vanished and political pluralism was
implemented, the Russian economy would rapidly converge towards a typical
advanced market economy, with a similar standard of living for all citizens (Aslund,
1992). This reduction of capitalism to self-instituting and self-equilibrating markets
has proved to be quite false. If the State’s authority is totally destroyed, it is impossible
to implement and legitimize the basic institutions of capitalism: the rule of law, the
credibility of national currency, the preservation of property, the enforcement of
competition and the security of citizens. International organizations such as the World
Bank (World Bank, 2002) have had to recognize that the State can be the key actor in
3 In reference to the famous book by Milton Friedman Capitalism and Freedom, University of Chicago Press, Chicago,
1962.
5
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
the institution of a market economy. Nowadays, much active research in economics
deals with the interaction between institutions and markets. The hypothesis of a pure
economy is to be discarded and has to be replaced by a more eclectic analysis of the
complementarities of State, market, norms, values, and even constitutional order
(North, 1990; 2005).
• All governments have fallen in love with markets that they promoted as an alternative
to difficult and complex public interventions. Ironically, politicians have invoked the
creative character of the market, whereas they actually relied on its destructive role on
the institutional architecture inherited from the Golden Age (Hollingsworth, Boyer,
1997). The contradictions generated by the liberalization process have constrained to a
significant aggiornamiento of governments, whatever their political and ideological
preferences. The Chilean trajectory is quite illuminating indeed: one of the earliest and
most dramatic examples of the adoption of a free market strategy generated such
macroeconomic disequilibria that the conservative governments brought the State
back by nationalizing copper mines, instituting reserves in order to curb down short
run financial capital movements and even nationalizing banks temporarily after a
major crisis. More generally, comparative analyses of Latin-American countries show
that success has been attained after a significant re-regulation in order to correct the
imbalances created by drastic moves towards free markets. To some extent, the same
correction took place after the Thatcher years and the succession of Blair’s
government in the UK.
• The so-called Washington consensus (liberalization, international opening,
privatization and reduction of the role of the State) has not produced the expected
results, a strong and stable recovery and steady growth, at all. It is especially true in
Latin America, where many governments applied quite drastic liberalization programs.
The collapse of Argentina should have completely destroyed the naive pro-market
consensus of international organizations (Boyer, Neffa, 2004). Actually, this financial,
social and political crisis contributed to a bifurcation among mainstream economists.
The majority of them blamed governments for not being bold enough to continue full
liberalization or being insufficiently patient in the difficult learning process of living
within a globalized world. Others, including some well known economists, changed
their mind and recognized that liberalization policies did not find relevant
justifications in modern economic theories: the very imperfection of market relations
call for significant but relevant public interventions (Stiglitz, 2003).
• More fundamentally, the conventional and now obsolete theory has been unable to
explain why a series of partial measures in the “right direction” have not been
sufficient to promote the emergence of a viable institutional configuration. The very idea
that contemporary economies are only composed of markets as the unique
coordinating mechanism does not help at all in understanding how institutional
configurations, mixing public and private actors, formal and informal rules,
institutions and organizations, coalesce into viable economic regimes. By contrast,
most of the authors who adopt the concept of capitalism are concerned by more
structural analyses about the compatibility of a series of initially disconnected
institutional reforms.
• The collapse of the Berlin Wall was supposed to promote the unification of the entire
world under the hegemony of markets in the economic sphere and democracy in the
political domain. In retrospect, it is quite ironical to read the literature about the end
of history (Fukuyama, 1992). The rhetoric of the symbiosis of market with democracy
seems to have won throughout the world even though comparative research
recurrently concludes that national trajectories differ drastically across the triad (North
America, Asia and Europe) and even between the closely interdependent members of
the European Union, NAFTA or MERCOSUR (Albert, 1991; Withley, 1999; 2002;
Hall, Soskice, 2001; Streeck, Yamamura, 2001; Coates 2002; Amable, 2003; Boyer,
2004; Hopner, 2006). For mainstream analysts (Aslund, 1992; Shleifer, Vishny, 1998),
this is only transitory institutional inertia and consequently a form of benchmarking
should favor institutional convergence towards a typical market economy. The
diagnosis is quite different if one adopts an analysis in terms of capitalism: the variety
of its configurations is the logical outcome of contrasted institutional compromises
(Hibbs, 1987), the impact of increasing returns on path dependency (Arthur, 1994) or
of the fact that there exist many methods in order to correct the so-called market
imperfections (Akerlof, 1984). These include State interventions, collective actions at
the relevant level, networks, codes of conduct, social values, informal norms and
6
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
conventions. Within the same economic system, broadly defined as capitalism, various
configurations can coexist (Berger, Dore, 1996). Furthermore, they generate specific
specializations that are frequently more complementary that substitutive (Hancké,
1999; Amable, 2003).
8
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
relation and the submission to the authority of the entrepreneur, and therefore a
matter of power and conflict. For social scientists, this definition highlights first, the
centrality of work in contemporary society and second, the conflicting nature of the
wage labor nexus. For example, this definition helps to understand why strategies for
rendering the labor market flexible have been so difficult to implement and have
generated so many conflicts in spite of the erosion of worker’s and their union’s
bargaining power .
11
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
Table 5 – Neoclassical theory and economic sociology: Two visions of capitalism
A second difference is still more important. Economists only study already existing
markets and very rarely investigate the theoretical conditions of their emergence. By
contrast, economic sociologists explore specific episodes of the creation or collapse
of a given market. Consequently, what is interpreted as an imperfection by
microeconomic theory is actually the logical consequences of the constitution and
institutionalization of a specific market. In a sense, economists and sociologists seem
to explore complementary aspects of capitalist economies: the first studies the
welfare property markets and is the defender of pure competition; the second
analyzes the complex interactions that take place in a precise market, in a given time
and space.
A third difference relates to the extension and generality of markets in capitalism.
Again, by training and tradition, economists consider that their mechanisms have a
very large scope, not only in the economic sphere but also in society and the political
arena. For example, the Chicago school speaks of the marriage market, the religion
market, the market of political ideas… Within the economic sphere, the market is
supposed to be the simplest method of coordination among actors. Any market
should be self-equilibrating and its mechanisms are so natural that markets emerge
spontaneously as the logical response to coordination and allocation problems. The
sociologist prefers a more positive approach: some markets function and are
successful whereas others collapse or are impossible to implement. It is interesting to
12
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
note for example that the sociologist Harrison White (1981, 1988), developed a
totally different interpretation of the canonical model of industrial economics
elaborated by Joseph Stiglitz: he insists upon the fact that markets are impossible to
open for some specific mix of scale economies and product differentiation by
quality! Usually the economist does not insist upon this structural failure of market
mechanisms. In summary, the economist is more of a market evangelist, presenting the
market as a model of efficiency, whereas the sociologist displays a more positive
approach, by analyzing the market, he assesses both its achievements and failures.
4. 2. Achievements and challenges
It is no surprise if economic sociology adopts different methods and gets different
results by comparison with economists. This is both an asset and a liability (Table 6).
Network analysis is a frequently used tool and in a sense, markets may derive from
the consolidation and institutionalization of networking activity (White, 2001). For
the time being, the major result is that social networks are not stochastic. This is
reassuring but not surprising. Similarly, some markets can be created by direct public
interventions, the subsequent networking of agents being the consequence and not
the cause of the creation of the market. Imagine for instance the market for treasury
bonds, for the care of elderly people or even the creation of the individual housing
market in France (Bourdieu, 2000).
The use of case studies gives a very rich and detailed account of the everyday
functioning of specific markets: the social, ethical, political and economic factors that
are singled out by each specific sub-discipline of social sciences, then come together
and define a complex web of causalities. This exercise is at the other extreme of the
methodological spectrum with respect to the formal modeling that is typical of the
economic profession. Hence a dilemma for future research: how to generalize
findings from case studies? Is it possible to derive alternative hypotheses to oppose
to mainstream economists? A second limit relates to the fact that capitalism is more
than the conjunction of a series of markets, and economic sociology by
methodological choice rarely addresses this issue.
Are markets basically idiosyncratic? Economic sociologists are tempted to respond
positively, whereas the economist searches for a general theory or at least a complete
taxonomy of different forms of market. The issue of generalization is a difficult
challenge for economic sociology. Therefore, in economic and political debates, the
economist plays the role of the generalist, with clear cut ideas and proposals and the
sociologist stresses the complexity of factors involved in the issue under
review…and generally looses the debate! Today, politicians prefer simple ideas even
if they are hardly relevant to complex and accurate analyses of systemic causality.
Can a market function in total isolation from the rest of the society? The economist
usually answers that it should but unfortunately a lot of exogenous factors, either
political or social, mitigate the efficiency of market allocations. Like Karl Polanyi, a
large fraction of economic sociologists state on the contrary that some non-
economic conditions have to be fulfilled in order to warrant soft functioning of
markets. Consequently, a pure capitalist economy cannot prosper or even function if
labor, money and nature become typical commodities (Polanyi, 1948). Recent
research on monetary regimes and the credibility of economic policy show that they
may rely on extra economic beliefs. For instance, the very foundation of the
credibility of money might be in quite archaic representations and not the expression
of the interests of the traders neither the outcome of rational individual strategies
(Aglietta, Orlean, 1998). A second example concerns financial markets: whereas they
are often supposed to be the typical expression of rationality, they actually combine
13
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
various logics linked to social networks (Abolafia, 1996) and/or the political process
of law making (Zorn & al., 2007).
Table 6 – Economic sociology as analysis of capitalism
This last remark introduces quite a challenging issue for economic sociology. Many
historical and empirical studies have convincingly shown that trust is a requisite for
the viability of markets. Economic sociology defines trust as the consequence of a
14
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
set of personal interactions that can be translated from one actor to another one.
Some economic historians have analyzed the emergence and the functioning of
markets in the Middle Ages, the organization of the Chinese business international
commodities market or the diamond market (Greif, 2006). Nonetheless, one may
consider with Karl Polanyi that the market tends to be extended to fictitious
commodities that also warrant the possibility of exchanges for typical commodities.
It is thus necessary to adopt a very long-term view in order to assess the actual role
of trust in the functioning of capitalist markets (Braudel, 1979; Wallerstein, 1999).
Here is a second objection: the network analysis of the building of trust does not
necessarily apply at the macroeconomic level, since confidence in a government, the
reliability of the euro or trust in the competence and the honesty of politicians, all
seem to derive from totally different mechanisms. Seemingly, there is no solution of
continuity between interpersonal and systemic trust (Aglietta, Orlean, 2002).
Actually, various mechanisms and rules have to be defined in order to sustain trust in
the marketplace: functional efficiency, procedural legitimacy, conformity with ethics
are key ingredients in this subtle mechanism. It is precisely at this level that the issue
of trust and legitimacy play a role in the acceptability of capitalist institutions. Clearly,
one form or another of explicit, public or collective intervention is required…and
this is the special appeal of political economic approaches.
15
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
the impact of institutions is economic efficiency. Furthermore, even growth or cycle
models do not deal with the process of endogenous transformation of institutions.
On the other side, political economists, trained as political scientists or in the
heterodox tradition, are objecting to the basic assumption of a political economy
built upon rational choice theory and the market as exclusive coordinating
mechanisms (Piore, Sabel, 1984; Regini, 1995; Berger, Dore, 1996; Fligstein, 2001;
Jessop, 2002; Glyn, 2006). The most basic economic institutions are shaped by and
embedded in a web of pre-existing institutions and non economic factors, such as
political interests, ideologies, ideas, social norms…The logic of polity cannot be
reduced to the pure rational analysis of economic interests, since the two spheres,
polity and economy, have to be articulated. This delivers a general principle for
analyzing the evolution of economic institutions (Theret, 1992; Amable, Palombarini,
2005). A second distinctive feature of these political economists is their concern for
the analysis of long-run structural transformations of capitalist institutions (Streeck,
Yamamura, 2001; Thelen, 2004; Pierson, 2004).
If economic sociology gives social actors the role of architects in the construction of
capitalist organizations and institutions, political economy generally prefers to stress
the role of the State in the emergence and functioning of capitalism. Today, the
choice of monetary and exchange rate regimes, the design of competition laws and
the objectives of labor legislation involve one branch or another of the State: the
Treasury, the Central Bank, the Parliament, the Ministry of Justice, or the Ministry of
Labor. Even if the State is far from being a unified entity, it cannot be neglected in
the analysis of any modern economy (table 7).
5. 2. An implicit division of labor between two disciplines
Somehow, due to two intellectual traditions and discipline delimitations, these two
approaches adopt different but complementary visions of the genesis of capitalist
organizations and institutions.
• Economic sociology adopts a bottom up approach: the interactions among individuals
lead to the possibility of the designing rules of the game in order to facilitate everyday
behaviors and strategies. For instance, professions can organize their members, invent
and then implement a series of rules that are the equivalent of self-regulation. Some
financial markets function according this kind of informal rules, without any direct
intervention of State. But the criticism is precisely that such a configuration is not a
general rule.
Political economy develops the opposite strategy, i.e. a top-down approach of the
emergence of institutions and their influence on organizations. The nature of
property, social rights, the yardstick of fair competition, the tax code and the
principles governing industrial relations all derive from political deliberations and are
imposed by law. By the way, each major crisis of capitalism has been associated with
an impressive wave of public interventions and legislations, in order to redesign the
institutional forms that have failed to deliver an acceptable economic and social
outcome. Conversely, political economy is unable to capture some of the informal
rules that turn out to be quite crucial in the functioning of an economic regime. One
of the new institutional economics currents, inspired by Douglass North, emphasizes
the need for dealing simultaneously with formal and informal rules. This is precisely
the domain of excellence of economic sociology.
16
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
17
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
Too often, economic sociology does not mention the political resources and
constraints that shape the formation of networks. It would be interesting to explicitly
introduce these variables, thus making possible, and even necessary, a dialogue with
political scientists. Both research agendas share the same meso level but the factors
governing organization formation is quite different, but not necessary incompatible
(figure 1). In order to deal with issues that are not traditionally considered to be part
of each disciplinary research agenda, the methods of one discipline could be applied
to the domains of the other.
A second source of cooperation may emerge when both programs are facing the
same difficult issues. For instance, in both disciplines, recent research tends to give
greater importance to the creation and diffusion of ideas than to positivist analyses
of social and political processes, they used to study in the past. Macro-sociology of
capitalism stresses the role of worker empowerment and projects in new capitalism
(Boltanski, Chiapello, 1999), whereas many political economy studies grant a definite
role to the market ideology, both at the domestic and European Union levels (Jabko,
2006). Both face the same difficulty of the proof: how to be sure whether ideas are
independent variables that cause the change of policy and inspire institutional
reforms? Are they totally independent from conflicts of interest? Wouldn’t the co-
evolution of ideas, interests and institutional reforms be a more relevant hypothesis?
What tools can be used to deliver relevant discourse analyses?
18
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
What are the main findings regarding the definition, the evolution and diversity of
capitalism (Table 8) ?
• A capitalist regime is defined by the precise configuration of the basic social relations
that define five major institutional forms: the monetary regime, the forms of
competition, the wage labor nexus, the links between State and the economy and
finally the insertion of the domestic economy into international relations. This analysis
19
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
is much more precise than the traditional approach that points out the importance of
property rights, good governance and macroeconomic stability (World Bank 2002).
• These institutional forms make possible or problematic an accumulation regime in the
economic sphere, but they result from a very complex process combining social
struggles, political deliberation and law enforcement. Therefore régulation theory
crosses many disciplines of social sciences. Originating from economists, the theory
has somehow diffused in the direction of political scientists, sociologists, and
specialists of urban and regional studies.
• Consequently, various methods have to be combined before formalizing accumulation
regimes, such as long-term growth patterns– and regulation modes (i.e. how do
economic agents react to the existing institutional architecture?) A typical régulationist
investigation should ideally combine a series of steps: a historical institutional analysis,
elaboration of relevant statistical indexes, then the detection of patterns and
regularities by econometric techniques, modeling of partial régulations and finally,
macro-modeling of society wide reproduction and change. A last and more recent
research agenda, quite difficult indeed, relates to the impact of the political processes
upon the direction of reforms of institutional forms during structural crises.
• The limits of régulation theory are closely related to its merits, as are the two sides of a
coin. The researcher has to master more than one discipline in order to get relevant
and new results. This calls for longer and more painful investigations, even if the
outcome is generally and intellectually rewarding. The sense of historical time might
be interpreted as a mere return to the limits of old historicism, whereas the ambitious
objective is to elaborate embryos of theory that could explain major structural changes
and innovations. A last and long lasting criticism concerns the so-called inability of
regulationists to propose economic and social programs to politicians, by contrast
with mainstream economists eager to promote the organization of society as a mere
web of markets. This apparent shortcoming of the régulation school is the direct
consequence of a tentative to build a value free theory that abstracts from any
normative content about what should be the “good economy” and the “good society”
(Amable, Palombarini, 2005).
• This very ambitious project is quite difficult to achieve within the strict boundaries of
economic disciplines. Thus, regulationist economists follow and benefit from the
advances of fellow research fields, such as political economy, economic history and
more recently economic sociology.
• Conversely, if these research fields aim at analyzing contemporary capitalist
economies, they might benefit from a critical assessment of the achievements and
limits of this school. The régulation school provides a lot of evidence about the strong
historicity of different forms of capitalism, their persisting diversity, and screens the
basic institutions that guarantee the viability of a capitalist formation. Nonetheless, the
most important issue still needs to be addressed: what are the factors that govern the
surprising resilience of capitalisms?
20
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
•
Table 8 – Régulation theory- contributions to capitalism analysis
21
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
Bibliographie
ABOLAFIA M., Making Markets: Oppportunism and Restraint on Wall Street, Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 1996.
AGLIETTA M., Régulation and Crisis of Capitalism. New York: Monthly Review Press,
1982.
AGLIETTA M., ORLEAN A. (eds), La monnaie souveraine. Paris, Odile Jacob, 1998.
AGLIETTA M., ORLEAN A., La monnaie entre Violence et confiance. Paris, Odile Jacob,
2002.
AKERLOF G. A., Economic Theorist's Book of Tales, Cambridge MA: Cambridge
University Press, 1984.
ALBERT M., Capitalisme contre Capitalisme, Paris, Le Seuil, 1991.
AMABLE B., The Diversity of Modern Capitalisms, Oxford, Oxford University Press,
2003.
AMABLE B., PALOMBARINI S., L’économie n’est pas une science morale, Paris, Le Seuil,
2005.
ALT J., SHEPSLE A., Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, New York: Cambridge
University Press, 1990.
ARTHUR B., Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor: The
University of Michigan press, 1994.
ASPER P., « Sociology of Markets » in International Encyclopedia of economic sociology,
London: Routledge, p. 427-443, 2006.
22
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
ASLUND A., How Russia Became a Market Economy, Washington: The Brooking
Institution, 1992.
AOKI M., Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge (Ma.): The MIT
Press, 2001..
BASLE M., MAZIER J., VIDAL J.F., Quand les crises durent..., Paris: Economica,
1984. 2e edition 1993.
BERGER S., DORE R. (eds), National Diversity and Global Capitalism, Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1996.
BERLE A. A., MEANS G., The Modern Corporation and Private Property, 1932; réédition,
New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers, The State University, 1991.
BILLAUDOT B., L’ordre économique de la société moderne, Paris: L’Harmattan, 1996.
BOLTANSKI L., CHIAPELLO E., Le nouvel esprit du capitalisme, Paris, NRF,
Gallimard, 1999.
BOYER R., The Seven Paradoxes of Capitalism…Or Is a Theory of Modern
Economies Still Possible, Couverture Orange CEPREMAP, n° 9620, Octobre 1996.
BOYER R., “The Political in the Era of Globalization and Finance: Focus on Some
Régulation School Research”, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, Vol.
24, n° 2, p. 274-322, 2000.
BOYER R., Une théorie du capitalisme est-elle possible ?, Paris: Odile Jacob, 2004a.
BOYER R., The Future of Growth, Chettelham: Edward Elgar, 2004b.
BOYER R., « New Growth Regimes, But Still Institutional Diversity », Socio-
Economic Review, vol. 2, n° 1, p. 1-32, 2004c.
BOYER R., DRACHE D. (eds), States Against Markets, New York: Routledge, 1996.
BOYER R., MISTRAL J., Accumulation, Inflation, Crises, Paris, Presses Universitaires
de France, 1978, nouvelle éditions 1982.
BOYER R., NEFFA J. C. (eds), La crisis argentina (1976-2001) : una vision desde la
theorias institucionalistas y regulacionistas, Madrid, Buenos Aires: Editorial Mino y Davila,
2004.
BOYER R., SAILLARD Y. (eds), Régulation Theory: The State of The Art, London:
Routledge, 2002.
BRAUDEL F., Civilisation matérielle, économie et capitalisme XV-XVIIIe siècles, 3 Tomes,
Paris: Armand Colin, 1979.
BOURDIEU P., Les structures sociales de l’économie, Paris, Seuil
COATES D. (ed.), Models of Capitalism: Debating Strengths and Weaknesses, Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar, 3 volumes, 2002.
DOSI G., Innovation, Organization and Economic Dynamics: Selected Essays, Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 2001.
DRAZEN A., Political Economy in Macroeconomics, Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2000.
DUMÉNIL G., LÉVY D., The Economics of the Profit Rate: Competition, Crises, and
Historical Tendencies in Capitalism, Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 1993.
23
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
FLIGSTEIN N., The Architecture of Markets. An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First
Century Capitalist Societies, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001.
FUKUYAMA F., The End of History and the Last Man, New York: Avon Books, 1992.
FUKUYAMA F., Trust.,The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity, New York: Free
Press/Simon & Schuster, 1996.
GALBRAITH J. K., American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power, Reprint,
New Brunswick (N.J.): Transaction, Classsics in Economics series, 1993.
GLYN A., “Capitalism Unleashed”, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006.
GOUREVITCH P., HAWES M., « Understanding National Production Systems:
Comparative Capitalism in the Globalized Economy », L’Année de la régulation 2002,
Vol. 6, Paris: Presses de Sciences-Po, p. 241-271, 2002.
GRANOVETTER M., “Economic Institutions as Social Constructions: A
Framework of Analysis”, Acta Sociologica, 35, p. 3-12, 1992.
GREIF A., Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy. Lessons from Medieval Trade,
Cambridge: CUP, 2006.
HALL P., SOSKICE D. (eds), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of
Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001.
HANCKÉ B., « Varieties of Capitalism Revisited: Globalisation and Comparative
Institutional Advantage », La Lettre de la regulation, n° 30, septembre 1999.
HIBBS D. A. Jr., The Political Economy of Industrial Democracies. Cambridge MA and
London UK: Harvard University Press, 1987.
HOLLINGSWORTH R. J., BOYER R. (eds), Contemporary Capitalism: The
Embeddedness of Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
HÖPNER M., “Varieties of capitalism” in Jens BECKET and Milan ZAFIROVSKI
International Encyclopedia of economic sociology, London: Routledge, p. 40-44, 2006.
JABKO N., Playing the Market. A Political Strategy for Uniting Europe, 1985-2005, Ithaca
& Londres: Cornell University Press, 2006.
JESSOP B., The Future of the Capitalist State, Cambridge: Polity, 2002.
JESSOP B. (ed.), Régulation Theory and the Crisis of Capitalism, Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar, 5 volumes, 2001.
LIPIETZ A., Crise et inflation, pourquoi ?, Paris: Maspéro La Découverte, 1979.
LIPIETZ A., The Magic World from Value to Inflation, London: Verso, 1985.
LORDON F., Et la vertu sauvera le monde… Après la débâcle financière, le salut par l’«
éthique », Paris: Raisons d’Agir, 2003.
NORTH D. C., Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge
and New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
NORTH D. C., Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2005.
PIORE M., SABEL C., The Second Industrial Divide, New York: Basic Book, 1984.
PIERSON P., Politics in Time, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2004.
POLANYI K., The Great Transformation, 1946; Traduc. Franç., Paris: Gallimard, 1983.
24
Revue de la régulation, Capitalisme, Institutions, Pouvoirs, n°1, 2007
http ://regulation.revues.org
REGINI M., Uncertain Boundaries. The Social and Political Construction of European
Economies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995.
SAPIR J., Le chaos russe: Désordres économiques, conflits politiques, décomposition militaire,
Paris, La Découverte, 1996.
SAPIR J., Les trous noirs de la science économique. Essai sur l'impossibilité de penser le temps et
l'argent, Paris, Albin Michel, 2000.
SHLEIFER A., VISHNY R., The Grabbing Hand: Governments Pathologies and their Cures,
Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1998.
STIGLITZ J. E., Globalization and its Discontents, Paris: Fayard, 2003.
STREECK W. YAMAMURA K. (eds), “The Origins of Non liberal Capitalism: Germany
and Japan in Comparison”, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2001.
THELEN K., “How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain,
the United States, and Japan”, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004.
THERET B., « Régulation et topologie du social », numéro spécial Régulation et
problèmes contemporains, Cahiers de Recherche sociologique, n° 17, Montréal,
UQAM, 1991.
THERET B., Régimes économiques de l'ordre politique : esquisse d'une théorie régulationniste des
limites de l'Etat, Paris: PUF, 1992.
THERET B., « Finance, souveraineté et dette sociale. Capital symbolique,
différenciation de la société et construction européenne », in L'État, la finance et le
social : souveraineté nationale et construction européenne, sous la direction de B. THERET,
Paris : La Découverte, 1994.
WALLERSTEIN I., Le capitalisme historique, Repères no 29, Paris: La Découverte,
1999.
WILLIAMSON O., The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: Free Press,
1985.
WHITE H, “Where Do Markets Come From?”, American Journal of Sociology, 87(3):
517-547, 1981.
WHITE H., “Varieties of Markets”, in WELLMAN-BERKOWITZ Davy (eds),
Social Structures: A Network Approach, Cambridge (Ma): Cambridge University Press, p.
226-260, 1988.
WHITE H., Markets from Networks: Socioeconomic Models of Production, Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 2001.
WITHLEY R., Divergent Capitalisms. The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999.
WITHLEY R., Competing Capitalism: Institutions and Economies, Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar, 2 volumes, 2002.
WORLD BANK, The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy,
Washington DC: World Bank, 1993.
WORLD BANK, Institutions and Markets, Annual report, Washington DC: World
Bank, 2002.
YAMAMURA K., STREECK W. (eds), The End of Diversity? Prospects for German and
Japanese Capitalism, Ithaca: Cornell University Press, p. 147-182, 2003.
25