Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 24

World Development Vol. 31, No. 8, pp.

1343–1366, 2003
Ó 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/03/$ - see front matter
doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(03)00088-3

Transition in Sub-Saharan Africa:


Agriculture, Urbanization and Income Growth
MARY TIFFEN *
Drylands Research, Crewkerne, Somerset, UK
Summary. — Econometric analysis of some 40 years of data has provided mixed results, because of
the defects of the data, and because there are some relatively sudden structural economic shifts. An
important shift is when agricultural labor ceases to grow, now happening in sub-Saharan Africa
(SSA). A model of the interrelationship over time of the rural, mainly agricultural sector, and the
urban, mainly manufacturing and service sector, is proposed. Each provides a market to the other.
Growth in both requires investment, but of distinctly different types. Their interaction results in an
S-shaped curve. Many SSA countries are in the acceleration phase, and its agriculture, particularly
in semi-arid areas, is increasingly oriented to the growing home market. Case studies show farmers
have invested and adopted new technologies but the transition to an urbanized economy has been
hindered by poor policies. The current need is for appropriate investments and policies to develop
the productivity of the urban sectors, so that they can continue to stimulate agriculture, and
provide jobs for those who are leaving farming.
Ó 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — transitional economies, development theory, agriculture, industrial policy, statistics,
sub-Saharan Africa

1. TRANSITIONS AND GROWTH investment rate to over 10% of national in-


MODELS come. It was generally believed in the 1960s
that such investment must be made by gov-
Development theory has been preoccupied ernment, due to lack of private capacity. In
with providing improved living standards and consequence, high taxes on agriculture through
quality of life either to the great majority, or marketing boards and export duties had gen-
more recently, to the poorest of the poor. This eral approval. Helleiner (1966) wrote in relation
normally requires economic growth greater to Nigeria:
than population growth, both to improve
incomes directly, and to increase the taxable The disposition of Marketing Board surpluses may
capacity underpinning good government ser- not have been perfect, but the rates of return from
vices. 1 their investments in research, roads, agricultural
schemes, universities, modern manufacturing plants
It is clear that the high-income countries are and so forth are unlikely to have been any lower than
urbanized and have large industrial and service
sectors. Agriculture provides only 2% of their
GDP, compared with 10% in middle-income
and 41% in low-income countries (World Bank, * This paper owes much to the collaboration I have
2000b). Most low-income countries have a enjoyed over many years with Michael Mortimore, and
higher proportion of their labor force in agri- draws upon studies comparing four semi-arid districts in
culture than its proportion of output value. sub-Saharan Africa, which he led for Drylands Re-
Many development economists in the 1950s search. These were funded by the Department for In-
and 1960s therefore urged the need to shift ternational Development, UK, which, however, is not
labor into higher productivity sectors, by a responsible for the views expressed. My intellectual
structural transformation leading to industri- debts to others too numerous to mention will be par-
alization of their economies. Rostow (1960) tially apparent in the bibliography. They include an
propounded a rapid take-off stage, for which a anonymous reviewer who made helpful suggestions.
necessary condition was a rise in the productive Final revision accepted: 19 March 2003.
1343
1344 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

those on housing, sewing machines, land clearing, and Tomich, Kilby, and Johnston (1995) also
the other small-scale outlets for peasant funds dis- returned to a stages approach in their book,
cussed above, let alone so much lower as to offset Transforming Agrarian Economies. The model
the difference between savings rates (p. 184).
differs from them in emphasizing the change in
markets rather than in labor disposition, and
The failure of policies aimed at inducing rapid the acceleration of change. They identified
industrialization discredited belief in a take-off countries with abundant rural labor with 50%
and stages of growth. 2 The importance of the or more of the labor force in agriculture, but
agricultural sector as a supplier of raw materi- thought that
als, food and labor, and as the home market
for local industrial output, noted by Johnston . . .it will be decades before they reach the structural
and Mellor (1961), was increasingly recognized. transformation turning point, when the absolute size
The low productivity of many government of the agricultural work force begins to decline. Until
investments and the outright failure of some then, poverty can be alleviated only if productivity
became better known. Structural adjustment and employment in the rural economy are increased
implied ‘‘a shift away from inward-oriented (pp. 9–10).
import-substituting development strategies to
more outward-oriented ones’’ (Alexandratos, In fact, a number of countries even in sub-
1995), and debt-ridden countries have been Saharan Africa (SSA) are at or near this point.
urged to increase and diversify agricultural ex- Calculating from (World Bank, 2002), urban
ports. 3 population in SSA increased at an average of
If GDP rises smoothly as a result of long- 5% p.a. and rural at 2% p.a. 1968–2000, and
term effects of capital formation, labor force averaged 34% of the total in 2000. It is now
expansion and technological change, it can be heading for 50% in some (Figure 1). Rural
modeled by econometric analysis, using the 30– population growth had dropped to 0.4% p.a. or
40 years of statistical data which are now less in eight out of the 20 largest countries in
available for a large number of countries. 1998–2000 (Figure 2), and not all rural is ag-
Kenny and Williams (2001) have shown ricultural. While policy debates have focused
the limited explicatory power of econometric on the pros and cons of exports, the swiftly
models, and their often contradictory results. growing internal market has become much
They note several causes, including, impor- more important to farmers, and is a main
tantly, the assumption that the process of eco- generator of change in farming systems, par-
nomic growth is the same, not only in all ticularly, but not only, in the semi-arid areas.
countries, but in all periods of time. They The urban market is attracting not only their
suggest therefore, ‘‘that mathematical modeling products, but also their labor.
techniques have invaded territory to which they The model is delineated and explained in
are ill-suited’’ (p. 14). Section 2. Section 3 illustrates the dubiety of
This paper uses a few generally agreed much of the population and national income
principles of economic growth to construct a data relating to SSA, which lies behind allega-
nonmathematical model that reflects histori- tions of low or negative growth rates in income
cal experience. The model conforms to the per capita, and falling agricultural output per
broad thrust of available statistical data, but capita (World Bank, 2000a). Wiggins (1995,
shows that economies are fundamentally 2000) has already discussed the conflict between
different at different points in time, particu- these statistics and the evidence of change and
larly in the relationship of their agricultural growth gathered from a limited number of vil-
and nonagricultural sectors. Policies therefore lage case studies. As these can be unrepresen-
need to be varied according to the stage at tative, Section 4 illustrates the rapidity of
which the country finds itself, rather than change in four semi-arid African districts,
applied universally. The development of the 1960–2000. Some 30% of the SSA population
agricultural sector is initially extremely im- live in semi-arid areas (Jahnke, 1982), which
portant. At a later stage, however, increases provides a difficult environment for agriculture.
in the productivity of towns are required, to If there are achievements in these areas it is
improve urban incomes, to provide alterna- likely that this is also the case in the better-
tive occupations to the rural poor, and to endowed areas. Section 5 considers the policies
stimulate agricultural investment through and government services likely to be most im-
growing demand. portant in the near future.
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1345

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0
Tanzania
Ethiopia

Uganda

Madagascar

Mozambique

Niger

Angola

Zimbabwe
Nigeria

Kenya

Sudan

Senegal
Ghana

Cameroon
South Africa

Cote d'Ivoire

Mali
Malawi
Congo, Dem. Rep.

Burkina Faso
-0.2

Annual growth %, 1998-2000

Figure 1. Annual percentage growth in rural population, 1998–2000, in sub-Saharan African countries currently having
a population over 10 million, in 1968 and 1998. Source: Calculated from World Bank (2002). Countries in this and
subsequent figures are arranged in order of population size.

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
Uganda
Tanzania

Angola

Senegal
Sudan
Ethiopia

Ghana

Cameroon
Mozambique

Mali
South Africa

Kenya

Madagascar

Cote d'Ivoire

Zimbabwe
Nigeria

Malawi

Niger
Congo, Dem. Rep.

Burkina Faso

1968 1998

Figure 2. Urban population, largest SSA countries, as a percentage of total population. Source: Calculated from the
World Bank (2002).

2. THE MODEL ––The division of labor by specialization


improves productivity and leads to techno-
(a) Basis logical improvements developed out of the
skills and experience of the specialists.
The model utilizes some of the most basic Adam Smith gave his famous illustration
and durable concepts in economics: of pin manufacture. Specialization requires
1346 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

concentrations of population––in villages or through the concentrations of people typ-


and to an increasing extent as specialization ical of a market place.
proceeds, in towns and cities, to facilitate the ––Investment, while a necessary condition
exchange of services, products and informa- for improved output and incomes, is not a
tion. guarantee of either. A given amount of in-
––The division of labor is limited by the ex- vestment does not and cannot produce a
tent of the market. The extent of the market given amount of growth. Investment incurs
is determined in great part by the costs of risk, and is more likely to be successful with
transport in relation to the value of the good information about the nature of the
product, and also by the numbers and in- risks and of the market, and if the investor
comes of the potential purchasers. 4 has been able to develop his/her skills and
––Improvements in output per labor day or judgement. The more complex and larger
per hectare require the investment of either the investment, the larger is the range of spe-
or both capital and labor for a delayed re- cialisms needed to provide information, and
ward, but there are diminishing returns to the greater the need for qualitative and
additional units of the same input unless quantitative skills in managing and assessing
there is also a change in technology or in it.
the nature of the output. Hence sustained
growth depends on the combination of in- (b) Sectoral change over time
vestment with new or modified and adapted
technologies (Romer, 1989). This applies There is a symbiotic relationship between the
both in agriculture and industry (Anderson, agricultural and nonagricultural sectors of an
1990; Tiffen & Mortimore, 1994). The devel- economy, which changes over time, as illus-
opment of technology is facilitated endoge- trated in Figure 3. In phase A, almost all labor
nously by specialization, but is also helped is absorbed by producing food for its own
by the openness of society to information household, at low levels of output per labor
from external sources, whether brought in unit. In scattered communities in a period when
by the written word and other media, transport was slow, expensive and difficult,
through the mechanisms of external trade, labor has to be spread inefficiently to cope with

100
A
B
C
90

80
Slow Fast

70
% agric labour

60 Agricultural labor:
market for urban
50
Manufacture and service
goods and services
labor - urban market for ag
40
produce and ag labor

30

20

10

0
1

82
10

19

28

37

46

55

64

73

tim e

Figure 3. Agricultural, manufacture and service sector labor over time. Note: Arrows show positions of low income and
lower middle income countries in 1960 and 1980, as given in World Bank (1983).
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1347

a variety of needs. As Smith (1776, p. 338) re- that cut themselves off from the exchange of
marked: goods, ideas and capital, as did China for many
centuries, (Landes, 1998), and Albania more
Without the assistance of some artificers. . .the cultiva- recently, move more slowly down the curve.
tion of land cannot be carried on but with great in- The contact economy also provides a market
conveniency and continual interruption. Smiths, for farmers hitherto dependent on an extremely
carpenters, wheelwrights and ploughwrights, masons small nonagricultural sector. The enlarged
and bricklayers, tanners, shoemakers and tailors are market provides a ‘‘vent’’ for farmers, and
people whose service the farmer has frequent occasion stimulates efforts to provide a surplus above
for.
family needs in return for desirable consumer
goods and inputs, many of which are initially
Farmers are unable to sell any surplus they imported. In countries which initially have
produce, if all near them are similarly engaged, some underused labor and land the export crop
and they have no access to other centers of is additional to existing production (Myint,
demand. 5 Typically, occasional surpluses are 1967). Hopkins (1973) illustrated this with
spent in feasting and drinking rather than in- special reference to West Africa. In countries
vesting to produce more. With low population with large numbers of peasant farmers, their
density, extensive agriculture, using long fallows additional purchasing power stimulates the
to restore fertility, is appropriate (Boserup, consumer goods and service sectors. This effect
1965). is not so powerful in countries where a few
Moving out of this situation is slow and people control most of the land and hold down
difficult. Figure 3 shows that agricultural and agricultural wages, as in parts of Latin Amer-
nonagricultural labor form each otherÕs mar- ica, as Tomich et al. (1995) point out. Fortu-
ket. The respective size of the market, shown by nately, this does not apply in most of SSA,
the vertical columns, limits the development of where small-scale farming predominates.
the other sector. Typically the first nonagri- The external economy may also provide in-
cultural sectors to develop are those of ad- vestment capital that begins to expand the local
ministration and defense, which often cull any urban sector, with port and transport facilities,
small agricultural surplus that exists without etc. Smith thought the rapid progress toward
contributing much to the reduction of ‘‘incon- wealth of ‘‘our American colonies’’ in the 17th
veniency’’ and the interruption of agricultural and early 18th century was due to the fact that
tasks by other necessities. their citizens were able to concentrate their
The units of time in Figure 3 are not stan- scarce capital resources on the development of
dardized. Phase A typically lasted many cen- agriculture (which he saw as its most produc-
turies while the transition phase B may be tive and secure use) because British merchants
accomplished in 50–500 years. Its length, often were supplying the capital for the much more
difficult to document in the absence of histori- risky export trade––ships and even warehouses
cal data, depends in part on the technologies (Smith, 1776, p. 329). The steam ship and
available in an external contact economy railway expanded the reach of export markets
(Gerschenkron, 1962). In the early slow part of in Asia in the 19th century, but, aside from
phase B it is usually assisted by access to ex- ports, major transport and urban infrastructure
ternal capital and markets to expand the non- investments for SSA only occurred in the first
agricultural sector and transport facilities. In half of the 20th century.
Britain, generally recognized as the home of the Under the stimulus of export markets for a
industrial revolution, it began with raw wool product which many can supply, agriculture
exports to only slightly more advanced econo- begins to become more productive. Initially,
mies in Europe in the medieval period, and there is vacant land farmers can develop for
started gathering speed circa 1760–1800. Later cropping. They are helped by better implements
developing countries have generally made the usually brought in by trade––axes, metal hoes,
transition more quickly than the United King- animal-drawn ploughs, etc. These are often
dom. The most recent examples are in eastern locally manufactured once the market is es-
Asia. 6 Change accelerates as productive tech- tablished, though they will only be selectively
nologies and technologies for the exchange of adopted, according to their suitability for the
goods and information improve. Concentra- land-labor ratios and other local conditions
tions of people facilitate the exchange and de- (Pingali, Bigot, & Binswanger, 1987). 7 Farm-
velopment of ideas (Simon, 1977). Countries ing can therefore begin not only to supply food,
1348 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

but also to release labor to a growing urban farmers are forced out of farming by their in-
sector, which is beginning to produce and ability to finance new capital requirements, or
supply consumer goods, services and some of their heirs choose to sell up to transfer into
the inputs for agriculture, reducing the incon- activities perceived as more profitable. A ten-
veniency of self-manufacture, and freeing up dency toward larger, capital-intensive farms
labor for more intensive farming. The urban develops as phase C approaches. This paper is
sector can begin to grow because farmers are not examining phase C, but concentrates on
now becoming a local, effective, cash-earning phase B, as it is likely to develop in SSA.
market. The economy is embarking on phase B,
in Figure 3. (c) The importance of investment and the
In turn, a larger, more productive urban differing nature of investments required to
sector enlarges the market for farmers and improve agricultural and nonagricultural
stimulates them to invest in improvements. productivity
Without investments to improve productivity a
falling proportion in farming would be unable While in historical experience the growth of
to supply the needs of a greater proportion in the manufacturing and service sector is gener-
the nonagricultural sectors. The internal mar- ally associated with higher incomes per capita,
ket becomes very large by phase C. At this this desirable outcome has depended on effec-
stage the manufacturing and service sectors are tive investments in all sectors, and, therefore,
no longer limited to the agricultural sector for on policies that have provided incentives and
their internal market, since they are also selling security for investment in and maintenance of
to other specialists in the nonfarm sectors. The new assets, and the availability of information
size of the internal market for farm output and education to increase ability to select ef-
depends on the incomes (and therefore pro- fective investments.
ductivity) of urban people, as well as actual Characteristically, but not exclusively, raising
numbers in towns, since BennetÕs Law predicts the productivity of the small-scale farming
that as incomes rise, the share of starchy staples sector requires many repeated small private
in food declines, and diet shifts toward live- investments (developing new land, acquiring a
stock products, fruit and vegetables (Tomich new tool or other input, increasing the value of
et al., 1995, p. 163). It is also governed how- livestock held, planting and nurturing tree
ever, by the costs and speed of transport facil- seedlings, etc.). These are barely perceptive to
ities for bulky and/or perishable commodities. 8 outsiders, though they can have a significant
Rural should not be equated with agricul- impact on production (Tomich et al., 1995, p.
tural. While agricultural activities take place 21). In some cases the investment can be of
almost entirely in the rural areas, rural areas work for a delayed reward, rather than actual
will also develop services and small-scale man- cash. The cumulative size of these incremen-
ufacturing activities to meet local needs. Large- tal and intermittent investments depends on
scale manufacturing industries will be located whether there is an enabling policy environ-
in urban areas at nodal points on the transport ment, which preserves private incentives to in-
network, to facilitate distribution to a wide vest, spreads information about opportunities
market. 9 and risks, and improves access to markets. Ef-
As the manufacturing and service sector in- fective private investment in agriculture is most
creases its productivity and income, it attracts assisted by appropriate public investments
labor out of agriculture, leading to the faster outside agriculture, for example, in communi-
stages of phase B. At some point, even in cations infrastructure 11 to assist marketing
populations that are still growing, the actual and the gathering of new information. State
numbers of people performing agricultural investments in primary education can assist in
tasks begins to drop, as well as their share in the uptake and assessment of information.
the work force. There is a growing need for Although agricultural investments are typi-
additional capital to substitute for labor. As an cally small and incremental, there are excep-
example, farmers on a new irrigation scheme in tions. Government investment in large irrigation
Muda, Malaysia, found themselves obliged, facilities has been crucial in Asia, though often
during 1974–79, to begin hiring combine har- beset by difficulties in management and main-
vesters and other machinery to replace the tenance. The water resources of SSA make it
labor of sons and daughters who had moved necessarily more reliant on small-scale irrigation
into a growing industrial sector. 10 Some to which farmers can themselves contribute re-
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1349

sources and management inputs. State invest- same 20 years. They tend however, to confirm
ment in research has also been important and the thesis that urbanization and, by implica-
can speed up the development of improved crop tion, the development of the manufacturing
varieties, etc. and service sector, accelerate, giving rise to the
By contrast, large increases in the produc- S-shaped curve depicted in Figure 3. They also
tivity of the industrial and service sector depend confirm that this process is associated with in-
characteristically, but not exclusively, on large- creasing wealth per capita. The agricultural
scale, lumpy, investments in electricity, water, labor force figures are somewhat suspect, since
communications, etc., which are typically sup- they tend to be worked out as a residual after
plied by state, municipal authorities or by the known workforce in formal sectors have
shareholders in large private firms (often for- been deducted (Tomich et al., 1995). They in-
eign in the initial stages). These are being clude many in the nonformal nonagricultural
termed collective investments, in contrast to the sector. Hence, the data on urbanization provide
family-scale investments in farming. Large a better guide to the scale of change, though
collective investments, like family investments, there are problems with varying definitions of
need good information and risk assessment to urban. Figure 2 shows that since 1960 most
succeed but, as the demands are more complex, SSA countries have become over 30% urban
this requires public and private investments in and five are over 40%. This implies agricultural
higher education for management as well as in labor occupies no more than 60–70% of the
primary education for the workforce. labor force, placing them clearly in the transi-
tion phase B of Figure 3.
(d) Goodness of fit with statistical time series

It has already been said that the curve in 3. THE WEAKNESSES OF THE
Figure 3 is not based on consistent time units. STATISTICAL BASE
It is presented to illustrate a pattern, and the
steepness of the slope in phase B will vary ac- National statistical data have many weak-
cording to the circumstances and policies of nesses in SSA (and probably elsewhere).
particular countries. The point at which it levels
out will depend in part on the size and natural (a) Population and labor data
assets of different countries, and in part on their
policies. But, it will always take the form of a While the World Bank population and ur-
backward sloping S, owing to mutually rein- banization figures can be accepted as giving
forcing and accelerating impacts of one sector orders of magnitude, they are not safe as ac-
upon the other. These impacts are related to the curate inputs into mathematical comparisons
efficiency and income effect of the investments between countries. 12 Censuses have been in-
made in each sector. They will be less where the frequent in many SSA countries. The results are
major element in the service sector is an un- late in entering national and international sta-
productive civil service, or where the state has tistics. The on-going population transition in
invested in manufacturing projects that fail to some countries, and the AIDS epidemic in
give an economic return. The World Bank es- others, have probably lowered annual growth
timates that the productivity of investment in rates below estimated rates. The most glaring
SSA needs to double (World Bank, 2000a). errors are in Nigeria, where the census of 1991
Nevertheless, the model as depicted fits rea- counted 88.99 million. However, the World
sonably well with data on percentage of the Bank (2002) was still giving 98.98 million as the
labor force engaged in agriculture for 1960 and 1991 figure, and adding 2.8% annually till 1997,
1980. The change in their position is shown by reducing this by stages to 2.4% in 2000. This
the arrows on the curve. Low-income countries, produced an estimated population of 127 mil-
less than 18% urbanized in 1960, moved rela- lion in 2000, whereas a continuous growth rate
tively slowly in 20 years from 77% engaged in of 2.4% from the census figure results in 110
agriculture to 70% in 1980. Lower middle- million. 13 The discrepancy in the divisor affects
income countries, less than 38% urbanized in all Nigerian per capita data, and even affects
1960, moved more rapidly in the same 20 years group data for SSA, as Nigeria holds 20% of
from 71% in agriculture to 55%. The figures are the SSA population.
not exactly comparable, as some countries have Definitions of urban vary by country and
moved from one category to the other in the by census date. Urban in Nigeria in 1963 was
1350 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

defined as agglomerations over 5,000, and over local retailing, transport, and manufactures
20,000 in 1991. In Niger, in 1988, ‘‘urban’’ was rises when farming areas generate higher out-
places of more than 2,500 with a government put and higher incomes. In five villages in Java
office (Republic of Niger, 1992). In Senegal, visited in 1974 and revisited in 1987, it was
urban in 1988 meant having a municipal com- observed that farm incomes had improved by
mune. The second largest city, Touba, a reli- possibly 30–50% in real terms, and there was
gious rather than administrative headquarters, better clothing, wider possession of consumer
was administratively rural, though it counted goods, and better access to education and
183,000 inhabitants in 1988, (Barry, Ndiaye, transport (Prabowo & McConnell, 1993). This
Ndiaye, & Tiffen, 2000). By 1999 it was re- obviously meant more employment of rural
ported as 500,000 (Coulon, 1999)––not insig- teachers, drivers, shopkeepers, etc. and there
nificant in a country with a total population of were specialized industries in some villages. On
10,000,000. the Muda irrigation scheme in Malaysia every
Employment by sector is generally acknowl- additional $1 earned from improved rice output
edged to be the weakest part of most census generated another $0.74 of activities and earn-
data. 14 The percentage living in rural areas can ings off-scheme (Bell, Hazell, & Slade, 1982).
be taken as the upper limit for agricultural la- These intersectoral linkages are also noted in
bor, since the number of rural people whose SSA (Barrett, Reardon, & Webb, 2001) but
main activity is outside farming is almost cer- these often ‘‘informal’’ activities may not be
tainly greater than the number of urban people caught in official statistics.
whose main activity is farming. Many studies
have found considerable rural nonfarm income. (b) Agricultural output, food imports and
In a review of 25 case studies in SSA, at times contribution to the GDP
varying from 1974 to 1990–91, Reardon (1997)
found its average share of household income to Agricultural output is notoriously difficult to
be 45%. Bryceson (2002) found higher levels by estimate. The amounts consumed on farm or
the later 1990s in six SSA countries, with 60– traded domestically are likely to be underesti-
80% of income from nonagricultural sources. If mated. Figure 4 shows the value of agricultural
carried out only in the off-season these activities exports as a percentage of agricultural GDP for
are not competitive with farm labor, but some 1995. It is immediately apparent that Zimba-
household members give preference to nonfarm bwe and Malawi were not valuing their locally
labor even in the farming season. Demand for consumed crops and livestock. 15 A survey in a

100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Uganda
Tanzania

Angola

Niger
Nigeria

Ghana

Cameroon
Congo, Dem. Rep.

South Africa

Kenya

Madagascar

Cote d'Ivoire

Zimbabwe

Mali
Burkina Faso

Malawi
Mozambique

Agr. exports as % agr. GDP

Figure 4. Agricultural exports as a percentage of agricultural GDP in largest SSA countries, in 1995. Source: Con-
structed from World Bank (2000) (data not available in 2002 version).
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1351

tobacco growing area of Malawi found that If we ignore the countries with obvious errors
just over 40% of farmersÕ income came from in Figure 4, most countries are not exporting
crop sales, of which only 15% in 1990 and 9% in more than 20% of agricultural production
2000 came from the export crop, tobacco. The value, so 80% is locally consumed. Crops in-
field pea contribution was 10% in 1990 and 23% ternally consumed are now much more impor-
in 2000 but until 1998 this crop was not offi- tant than crops exported, as we should expect
cially recorded (Orr & Mwale, 2001). to happen with countries in the transition phase
Despite the growing urban population, who, B depicted in Figure 3.
being slightly better off, consume more high-
value foods and beverages than rural people,
food imports have generally remained in a 4. FARMERS’ INVESTMENTS IN
range of $3–$10 per head (Figure 4) since RESPONSES TO CHANGING MARKETS
1980. 16 Food import data in countries with IN FOUR SEMI-ARID DISTRICTS OF SSA
limited import routes are likely to be more re-
liable than food production data, but not all Given the deficiencies in national data, the
countries measure imports. Calculations from processes of change are best understood and
(World Bank, 2002) show that among the nine tested against the model in Figure 3 at a district
large countries supplying this data, in eight, level. At this level sample data from villages can
food imports per capita have been static or be related to district statistics and, therefore, to
falling since the mid 1980s, Kenya being a the national statistics built up from them. This
possible exception. In most they have remained has been done for four semi-arid areas, 1960–
below $10 per capita, in constant 1995 US$. 2000. These are Makueni District, Kenya,
Senegal, where policy favored rice imports to Diourbel Region, Senegal, Maradi Depart-
increase specialization on groundnuts, is ex- ment, Niger and the Kano hinterland, Nigeria.
ceptional with a level generally above $25 per Farmers in these areas are restricted in the
capita, though it seems to have fallen since the crops they can grow, unless they have access to
devaluation of the FCFA in 1994. Nigeria, up pockets of irrigable or water-retentive land.
at nearly $35 in 1981–82, fell back to $4–8 after The main crops are cereals and pulses, low in
successive devaluations. Some temporary rises value in relation to bulk, but capable also of
due to droughts can be seen, particularly providing fodder to livestock. In the past the
marked for Zimbabwe, 1989–91. The implica- main export crop was groundnuts, and in
tion is that in most countries, farmers have kept Makueni, cotton. Three districts have one short
up with the level of demand, and changes in its farming season lasting three to five months, but
nature, with variations in part due to policies, Makueni has two wet seasons of about three
and occasionally to drought. This is incom- months each. Rainfall is very variable from
patible with the calculated volume of food year to year, giving a risk of crop failure.
output by major crop given in Tables 8–6 Nevertheless semi-arid areas contain large
(World Bank, 2002), (which quotes FAO data). populations, with particularly high densities in
This shows annual percentage growth in almost the hinterlands of Kano in northern Nigeria
all cases of less than 1%, which is certainly less and Dakar in Senegal.
than population increase. Static per capita In terms of the model, we are particularly
production implies an annual growth in food interested to see whether there has been esca-
crops equal to population growth, unless im- lating growth in urban populations. If so, we
ports are rising. 17 need to see if farmers have been making the
Farmers might meet internal demand with- appropriate private investments to respond to a
out increasing productivity if they transfer re- growing urban market for both their products
sources from export crops to food crops. But, and their labor, or if they have been held back
volumes for three main exports, cocoa, cotton by deficiencies in policy, or in the government
and coffee, 1968–97 were maintained (World supply of some of the services identified as
Bank, 2002). Groundnut exports fell sub- particularly necessary. Changes in land markets
stantially during 1968–78, stabilized 1978–88 should also occur as land becomes more scarce,
and fell again somewhat during 1988–98. Our and in labor disposition if urban occupations
studies show more of the crop going to meet become more attractive. Second, we need to see
local demand, but falls in export prices and if the collective investments and policies re-
rosette disease in Nigeria in the 1970s are other quired to make the growing nonfarm sector
factors. more productive are in place, so that it can
1352 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

both provide jobs for people leaving the farms, more urbanized southern Nigeria (Ariyo, Voh,
and a growing market for higher value farm & Ahmed, 2001). If Nigerian farmers as a
produce such as livestock, fruit and vegetables. whole had failed to invest, food imports would
The studies were carried out by teams of have increased dramatically, but this has not
scientists from the countries concerned, profil- been the case. In the late 1960s NigeriaÕs food
ing particular aspects of change, 1960–2000, imports were $2–$3 per capita (World Bank,
using methods and data appropriate to the 2000a, 2000b, 2000c). Figure 5 has shown that
subject matter. This included literature reviews; although these billowed during the petroleum
collection, discussion and analysis of district boom and while the currency was overvalued,
data with the appropriate government office; in the 1990s they were running at only $5–$8
air photo and remote sensing interpretation; per capita (all in constant 1995$). Given that
and collective interviews and sample surveys of the import figure includes all foods and bever-
10–12 randomly selected farmers in four rep- ages, this does not suggest a large import of
resentative villages. 18 The country team lead- staple grains. The scale of the increased pro-
ers were Francis Gichuki (Kenya), Abdou Fall duction demanded from farmers is understated
and Adama Faye (Senegal) and Yamba Bou- in Table 1, as not all families living in towns of
bacar (Niger), who collaborated with Drylands less than 20,000 are primarily engaged in agri-
Research in developing from the profiles three culture. It also takes no account of industrial
national syntheses, using the findings to trace needs. Maize, sorghum and millet are impor-
and understand socioeconomic and environ- tant inputs into large commercial brewing,
mental change in its various interactions over flour milling and animal foodstuff enterprises
time. The Nigerian study was limited, for fi- (Swindell, Iliya, & Mamman, 1999).
nancial reasons, to five profiles, which included Crop production data for the Kano area was
an in-depth study of the marketing of food only available to us 1982–90 (World Bank,
crops and livestock in the Kano area and a 1995), when yields were strongly linked with
review of policy. Findings were checked by one rainfall (Tiffen & Mortimore, 2002). But, for
or more workshops in which District officials Maradi, Niger, there is a series of District fig-
and farmer representatives took part. DFID ures running from 1964 to 1998. These show
also provided funds for endorsement exercises the expected variation in production per capita
in the local constituencies in 2001–02. (taking the total population) from year to year,
under the influence of rainfall variation. They
(a) Changes in rural and urban population and in also show that, after recovery from the
urban demand droughts in the early 1970s, farmers upped their
production to average around 300 kg/capita,
Rapid growth of the local towns occurred in (Mortimore, Tiffen, Boubacar, & Nelson, 2001)
three of the four study areas, with urban pop- despite a growing rural population, and despite
ulation being now 30% or over in two cases the virtual cessation of supportive projects after
(Table 1). 1985, under structural adjustment (Hamadou,
The increase in the urban market over time is 2000a; Figures 4 and 5). This must mean that
particularly visible in northern Nigeria and they saw an incentive to increase their sales.
Senegal, but the outcome in terms of effective The net sellers of grain to the towns are not
demand for local farm produce differed. Table evenly distributed among the rural population.
1 shows the increase in local urban grain re- In a large CARE sample in Maradi in 1996 the
quirements estimated at 200 kg/head. During families defined as the most vulnerable (56%)
1952–91 the urban population of the two states produced 125 kg cereals/capita, against a
constituted from the colonial Kano Province moderately poor group (27%) who produced
increased at about 8% per year, while the rural 311 kg, and a relatively well-off group of 17%
increase was nearer 1.6%. In 1952 Kano mu- who produced 580 kg/capita (CARE Interna-
nicipality was the only town with more than tional au Niger & Universite dÕArizona, 1997).
20,000 inhabitants; by 1991 it had been joined The average was 252 kg/capita, in a somewhat
by 11 others (Tiffen, 2001). To cater solely for below average rainfall year. Food selling was
the local towns, each rural family needed to near universal but if one estimates per capita
supply 10 times as much grain to urban mar- needs at 200 kg/capita/annum, it is apparent
kets on average in 1991 compared with 1952. In that quite large numbers of rural families are
addition, they were supplying grains and pulses net buyers of cereals, and that a minority are
(especially maize and cowpeas) to the even net sellers. 19 Maradi town has grown, but
Table 1. Population and urban grain demand per rural person in four semi-arid areas
Total Urbana % Urban Urban growth p.a. Rural density Urban grain need, kg
per rural personb

TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA


Kano Province 1952 3,396,350 130,173 3.8 77 8.0
Kano and Jigawa States 1991 8,685,995 2,516,686 29.0 7.9 (Jigawa) 118 81.6
(Kano) 169
Maradi 1960 (estimate) 561,000 – – 13
1977 949,747 44,459 4.7 – 22 9.8
1988 1,389,443 110,739 8.0 8.7 33 17.3
Diourbel 1960 (estimate) 261,000 n.a. n.a. n.a.
1976 423,038 120,249 28.4 70 79.4
1988 620,197 251,799 40.6 6.9 94 136.7

Makueni (dryland only) 1962 170,717 – – – 38


1989 524,025 – – – 102
Source: Calculated from census data: summaries in Gichuki (2000a), Barry et al. (2000) and Tiffen (2001).
a
The 1991 Nigerian urban definition as settlements of over 20,000 is here applied to all data, regardless of country and time differences. Makueni has no towns of this
size.
b
Grain need assumed as 200 kg per head per year. Urban demand at this level has been divided by rural population. To get demand per rural family it is necessary to
multiply this up by family size, which varies by country.

1353
1354 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Figure 5. Structure of incomes by type of household, Diourbel, 1999–2000. Source: Faye and Fall (2000), Figure 1.
Household types as in Table 2.

important influences on farmers are the large spare parts, and high wage bills (Swindell et al.,
towns across the border in Katsina State, Ni- 1999), a trend also noted by Balcet (1997). A
geria. Grains and pulses flow in both directions, sudden burgeoning of large-scale farms was
depending on harvest conditions, prices, and also seen round Kano but they were estimated
exchange rate differences (Meagher, 1997). to account for only 5% of total agricultural
Most Maradi farmers have relatively small production. Mustapha and Meagher (2000)
farms. Cereal yields are in the order of 300–500 noted that many of these ‘‘modern’’ enterprises
kg/ha, which gives an idea of the modest foundered when state support was reduced in
cropped hectares in families producing 125–600 the aftermath of falling oil prices. A particular
kg/head. The distinguishing characteristic of feature in northern Nigeria has been the bur-
large sellers is their good management quality, geoning of fadama farming (on low-lying or
which has enabled them to accumulate re- riverine land), utilizing small pumps to raise
sources (from livestock sales, crop production groundwater, to irrigate wheat and vegetables.
or nonfarm incomes) for investment in inten- This demands large inputs into small areas
sification. Farmers of one southern Maradi (generally less than one ha) but leads to very
village said, in discussing the findings of the profitable sales to the towns (Swindell et al.,
research, that farming was only profitable for 1999; World Bank, 1995).
those who had the means to invest, and those Local urban growth was also very substantial
who could await a favorable moment for sell- in Diourbel, Senegal, due largely to the new city
ing. Commerce, crop farming and livestock of Touba as well as growth in the two of the
raising could not be disassociated (Boubacar & three older departmental towns (Barry et al.,
Ibrahim, 2002). 2000). In addition, farmers had easy access to
In northern Nigeria the most efficient farms the expanding capital, Dakar. But, there was
were found to be most numerous in high-den- almost no urban market for the grain they
sity areas with good market facilities. These could produce, millet, due to the long-estab-
had smaller than average farms with 4.4 ha as lished preference for rice. While they main-
against the average in the sample of 5.8 ha tained output of millet per agricultural worker
(Okike et al., 2001). There are larger farms in 1960–92 at around 500 kg for family use
the vicinity of some big cities, encouraged by (weather permitting), output per total popula-
the state, where entrepreneurs, variously from tion fell to around 100 kg (Faye, Fall, Morti-
trade, the old aristocracy, modern business or more, Tiffen, & Nelson, 2001, Figure 14). The
the civil service and army, bought land in the market for groundnuts as a local cooking oil
1980s and invested heavily in mechanized farms and ingredient was distorted by government
using hired labor, in response to a perceived efforts to channel all groundnuts to state oil
growing and profitable demand for millet and mills, whose high processing costs mean that
other staples. In the 1990s their average size in urban consumers preferred cheaper imported
the vicinity of Sokoto had been reduced to 20– oils (Gaye, 2000). Hence, the main local impact
50 ha because of rising costs of fuel, shortage of of urbanization was on demand for meat, par-
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1355

ticularly after the devaluation of the FCFA their insurance against crop failure (Fall, 2000).
made imported meat more expensive. From In the worst years, many were dependent on
erratic figures available from the veterinary food aid from relatives or the government.
department, small livestock increased from
100–140,000 1966–72 to 200–250,000 in the (b) Farmers as investors
1990s. (Cattle numbers were relatively static;
holdings of equines grew somewhat, Faye, Fall, As business managers, farmers have to decide
& Coulibaly, 2000). Sales were not equally how to react to changing product and factor
distributed, for it was only the farmers who had markets, and whether, and in what, to invest.
the resources to invest in livestock, concen- In northern Nigeria growing food demand
trated among those who did not usually have to has been met by complementary farm invest-
buy in grain, who were able to go in for sub- ments, despite having to cope with frequent
stantial livestock fattening (Figure 5). As in changes and reverses in government policies
Nigeria, there are some much larger, more which have affected the level and competitive-
mechanized farms, operated mainly by religious ness of food imports, the cost and availability
leaders and businessmen, whom we excluded of farm labor, the subsidization or not of fer-
from the sample. In the early 1970s these only tilizer and other inputs, etc. (Mustapha &
produced a small proportion of the groundnut Meagher, 2000). In response to the labor
crop (OÕBrien, 1975), but the current position is shortage induced by the urban-centered infra-
not known. structural petroleum boom in the 1970s, Kano
The exception to local urban growth was farmers invested to a very considerable extent
Makueni, in Kenya. This part of the former in buying or hiring ox-drawn equipment, pre-
Machakos District had experienced an influx of viously rare in the Kano-close settled zone.
rural settlers 1950–90 (Tiffen, Mortimore, & Maize, a minor crop in 1979, became a major
Gichuki, 1994). Neither Wote, which was made crop in suitable areas by 1989, as farmers
the capital of the newly formed Makueni dis- adopted a new variety (TZB) that was very
trict in 1992, nor any of the settlements along responsive to fertilizer, subsidized at the time
the Nairobi–Mombasa highway on its southern (Smith, Barau, Goldman, & Mareck, 1994).
edge, had attained a population of 20,000 by When the fertilizer price was raised, farmers
the 1989 census. It may be significant that, reduced its usage, 22 and reverted to older tech-
unlike the district towns in the other three niques of maintaining fertility, long practiced in
countries, there had been no collective urban the densely settled area around Kano (Morti-
investment to 1998 in electricity, telephones, more, 1993). They selected and crossed new and
etc., 20 so, even on the highway, enterprises old varieties of seed that best matched their
were limited to services to travelers, marketing, ecological niche and changed economic cir-
and such crafts and small industries as can cumstances (Mortimore & Adams, 1999), while
operate competitively without power. also adopting new crops such as soya beans
In Kenya as a whole, Figure 2 shows that (Balcet, 1997).
urbanization was estimated at 30% by 2000. Farmers have also responded to the growing
Makueni farmers had some access, over poor demand for meat. The most efficient farms,
roads, to Mombasa and Nairobi, for their with the highest gross revenue per ha and the
higher value crops such as fruit and vegetables highest net revenue per farm, were those pur-
but had no comparative advantage in produ- chasing in the most crop residues and other
cing maize for these towns (Gichuki, Mbogoh, inputs, to maintain more than double the av-
Tiffen, & Mortimore, 2000). Mbogoh (2000) erage number of livestock in addition to crops,
found cereal production per person since the using three times as much manure as the aver-
district was formed in 1992 varied enormously age and more days of animal traction (usually
from year to year, according to district statistics hired) (Okike et al., 2001). Areas of common
(which are no more than guestimates). 21 The grazing in the densely settled Kano and Jigawa
average grain and pulse production 1992–98 states are very limited, but 1984 data show the
just about met district needs taking all years high numbers of livestock kept on farms with
together. In some years however, farmers were some water-retentive land (20–40% of such
net buyers of cereals and beans (and forced households had cattle, and 75–90% had around
sellers of livestock) while in other years they 15 sheep and goats) (World Bank, 1995, Table
could sell grains and restock on animals. Un- 3.8). The livestock are penned to maximize
fortunately, livestock disease could wipe out manure collection and to fatten up quickly. The
1356 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

high inputs of labor this requires for feeding fattening. Schoonmaker Freudenberger and
and watering, as compared with herding Schoonmaker Freudenberger (1993) reported
(Mortimore & Adams, 1999) is only worthwhile how families in a village to the north of
if there is an active market for livestock as well Diourbel said it was better to invest in five
as cereals. There is now an active market for lambs than to seed an area with 500 kg of
crop residues, with prices higher for groundnut groundnuts. Livestock have become a major
and cowpea hay than for grain (Baba & Mag- element in farm incomes of the better off, as
aji, 1998). Farmers have recently shown interest shown in Figure 5. By 1999 much of their
in a new cowpea variety that gives more fodder, groundnut production was not sold for export,
though it requires spraying (Singh, Larbi, but consumed locally as nuts or oil, with the
Tabo, & Dixon, 2001). cake and hay providing valuable fodder sup-
Farmers in Diourbel, Senegal, also calculate porting their livestock enterprises (Faye, 2002;
the returns to different farm enterprises and Faye & Fall, 2000). Their investments have
technologies and invest accordingly. In the followed suit, as shown in Table 2. It is not
1960s through to the 1990s, Senegal farmers surprising that the poorest spend little on farm
weighed up the value of investing in fertilizer in inputs, but it is worthy of note that the in-
relation to its price and groundnut prices, and vestments of the middle and better-off segments
the merits of heavy versus light ploughs, or in get directed toward livestock rather than crop
buying a plough versus a cart for transport enterprises.
(Faye et al., 2001). In response to the growing The way farmers plan, assess, invest over
urban market for meat, and the rising price of time and juggle resources, was particularly il-
mutton, many in this so-called groundnut basin lustrated in the Makueni study. Farmers were
had by the 1990s decided to go in for animal asked to identify the three most important past

Table 2. Use of money income by 38 Diourbel farmers (1999–2000)


a
Type of household Type 1 Type 2 Type 3
Household characteristics
Percentage of sample in this type 29.4 41.2 29.4
Estimated income per head in past year (FCFA) 46,456 64,054 91,019
Months own millet and groundnuts met family needs <6 6–11 12+
Percentage of income not farm generated 68 48 18
Percentage of family workers absent in farming season 25.0 16.7 18.8

Use of money income (per cent)


Consumption
Buying millet 16.9 7.5 5.4
Buying rice 15.2 13.1 10.3
Buying other food 22.0 11.7 26.6
Clothing 14.3 19.2 9.0
Buying other products 5.6 2.7 3.2

Farm-related expenditure
Equipment 0.5 0.6 2.1
Buying animals 0.8 12.0 18.9
Buying animal food or medication 1.1 4.4 2.9
Buying crop inputs 1.9 1.9 2.4
Payment for services 1.6 1.8 2.0
Other expenditure
Health and education 3.6 4.1 2.7
Ceremonial expenses 16.6 21.0 14.5
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0
Source: Faye et al. (2001).
a
Percentage not farm-generated calculated from original data not there quoted. The sample was small, being based
on 10 randomly selected farmers in four villages but the results are all in the direction expected.
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1357

Figure 6. Expansion of cultivation in four terroirs, Maradi Department, Niger, 1957–99, in four cultivation frequency
classes (percent of area). Source: Mahamane (2001): Tables 5, 7, 9, 11. Villages arranged from south to north. No data
are available for Jiratawa in 1957.

investments contributing to their welfare. Ter- village area while available, later further north.
racing, planting trees, clearing bush, building a The process is made visible by air photograph
house, and educating children topped the and satellite data (Figure 6). In one of the four
charts (Nelson, 2000). Clearing bush and villages, Jiratawa, there was also project in-
building a house were preliminary investments. vestment in an irrigation scheme, but the others
Terraces, trees and education came in later were unassisted. Owing to the availability till
stages. On the farms in the sample, the con- recently of land that could be fallowed or
struction of terraces and drains had taken, per cleared, investment in intensification is only just
ha, 30–60 man days and Kenya shillings 5,000– beginning. Investments in equipment (Table 3)
9,000 (Gichuki, 2000b), and had been gradually have accelerated since the devaluation of the
extended to all their cropped land. All farmers FCFA, which, as in Burkina Faso (Hoffmann,
had planted fruit trees, ranging from three on 1998) and Senegal, has resulted in improved
very small farms to over 200 on some larger prices for local livestock and grains (Kherallah,
ones. This involves considerable investment in Delgado, Gabre-Madhin, Minot, & Johnson,
labor for planting pits and watering during es- 2000).
tablishment, as well as manure and seedling The volume of farm investment in the dis-
purchase. Half the sample had made invest- tricts over the 40 years could not be calculated,
ments intended to improve output even during but it was certainly substantial in Makueni,
the difficult 1990s, bunched in years giving a Maradi and the Kano area. In Makueni and
good harvest. All farmers could readily identify Maradi, credit was unimportant, and finance
the next one or two investments they wanted to came from crop and livestock sales, family
make when resources became available. These transfers, and use of nonfarm income. We have
were mainly related to equipment (67%), inputs no data on the role of credit in the Kano area,
(17%) and granaries (13%), needed to increase but some was available. Credit was part of the
their output of cereals and pulses (Mbogoh, state-imposed system in Diourbel, c1965–80,
2000). A good half of the finance for their in- when all producers had to belong to a co-
vestments came from nonfarm income (Nelson, operative, which provided inputs on credit, and
2000), which in bad years gets taken up by sold output at controlled, low, prices. In bad
consumption needs. years, farmers were obliged to default, eventu-
In Maradi, the main investment initially was ally bringing about the bankruptcy of the re-
in clearing new land for cultivation, within the sponsible state organization (which was also
1358 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 3. Years in which 40 interviewed farmers acquired new capital equipment in Maradi, Nigera
Plough oxen Ox cart Heavy plough Light plough Bicycle Motor cycle
(charrue) (houe)
To 1994 1 8 10 4 2 0
After 1994 18 9 2 34 6 4
Source: Hamadou (2000b).
a
The FCFA was devalued in January 1994, and 1994 was counted in the pre-devaluation epoch, on the supposition
that its effects on prices might not be immediate. (Shaikh & McGahuey, 1996 actually found some pretty immediate
increases in water conservation techniques for cereals in western Niger.) The heavy plough had been promoted, and
credit provided, under a project, which ceased operation in 1987.

overstaffed, inefficient and corrupt) and impel- (d) Changes in the land market and in income
ling Senegal to adopt drastic retrenchment distribution
policies (Gaye, 2000).
The important role of livestock, themselves a Land scarcity has developed everywhere, due
form of capital and an insurance substitute, but to a slow increase in rural population and im-
also demanding capital for replacement and proved market access, which has increased the
maintenance, was evident in all the districts. value of output, and encouraged farm expan-
But, in lowland Makueni, Kenya, livestock sion when land was available. As a result, land
appeared particularly vulnerable to disease, has become a marketable commodity, in all
and many farmers had experienced substantial four of the areas examined. This has been least
stock losses. Some farmers in the limited areas the case in the Diourbel Region, partly because
with suitable topography had built small dams of the 1964 Senegal statute ascribing ownership
to water crossbred cows, to take advantage of to the state and user rights to the user, but also
the recently improved milk market when the because state policies have in various ways de-
Marketing BoardÕs monopoly of urban sales creased the profitability of groundnut and
was abolished, and these also invested in millet sales, leading to substantial emigration
spraying equipment and veterinary supplies. out of farming 23 (Faye et al., 2001). There has
For most farmers, dairying was too hazardous not been the same competition to obtain land
(Fall, 2000; Mbogoh, 2000). for young families, or to retain land, as in the
other three districts.
In the other three areas the land market is
(c) Exports versus local urban markets active. Intensification increasingly needs cash to
buy labor, inputs, equipment and livestock, in
Exports overseas have become less important addition to, or in substitution for, labor for a
in the 1990s compared to 1960–70 (Maradi delayed reward. Not all farmers have been able
farmers still export, but to towns just over the to find the resources and to manage the asso-
border in Nigeria). Nigerian groundnut exports ciated risks. Even in Maradi, where intensifi-
fell drastically due to rosette disease in the early cation is at an early stage, some poor farmers
1970s. The crop is now reviving, with the aid of have had to sell fields to the more successful
new resistant varieties, there and in Maradi, but (Boubacar, 2000). In the Kano area, some
sales are oriented to the towns (Ariyo et al., farmers have been less able to cope than others
2001; Hamadou, 2000a). Even in Diourbel, with the rapid changes in matters such as fer-
Senegal, where the Government has continued tilizer prices, product prices, etc., and Meagher
to view groundnuts as an export crop, many and Mustapha (1997) noted increased income
farmers grow it, but do not sell (Faye & Fall, differentiation in one village, between 1989–90
2000), and they rank its uses as food, fodder and 1992–93, between small farmers who had
and then cash (Faye, 2002). In Makueni, cotton to buy in food at rising prices, and larger
was briefly promoted as a cash crop under an farmers, who were better able to play the
aid program 1978–87 but collapsed due to late markets. Farmers, or their heirs, who inherit
payments by the responsible parastatal (Tiffen smaller farms, if unable to find the necessary
et al., 1994). Some farmers would be glad if a capital to intensify production from a small
ginnery could be re-established locally (Gichuki land holding, are increasingly forced to look to
et al., 2000). other occupations for a living, and some prefer,
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1359

or are forced, to sell up. Near Sokoto and more et al., 2001). Studies of Fulani livestock
Gusau, in northwest Nigeria, some farms have raisers in reserves in northern Nigeria show
diminished in size to a garden plot, and the both they and the farmers outside the reserve
main income is earned by agricultural wage now combine livestock and cropping, in a va-
labor or other labor. These areas also have riety of ways (Baba & Magaji, 1998; Hassan,
many intermediate viable small farms, and Hoffmann, & Steinbach, 1998). If it is not a
some large capitalized farms. In the rapidly contradiction in terms, semi-arid farmers have
changing job and land market of Nigeria, af- become specialists in mixed farming and crop-
fected by petroleum booms and busts, inflation, livestock integration.
import bans and relaxations, voluntary buyers In semi-arid areas with variable rainfall, in-
and sellers of land may come to regret their come diversification, in the sense of combining
decisions, but the worst sufferers are often those farming and nonfarm activities within one
whose land has been forcibly taken over by the household, has advantages, particularly by
state (Iliya & Swindell, 1997), often without spreading risk. A Makueni farmer said ‘‘When
compensation, to accommodate urban expan- there is a drought, I lose as a farmer, but as a
sion. teacher, I never experience that drought. I still
get my salary and can survive better than if I
(e) The labor market, specialization and was only a farmer’’ (Nzioka, 2000, p. 12). Ellis
diversification of incomes (2000, p. 5) points out that this cuts across the
view that specialization and market exchanges
In Nigeria, census data showed average are the way to higher incomes and improved
family size of five in Jigawa, and 5.4 in Kano, welfare, and it might therefore be thought to be
with the (male) household head said to consti- in contradiction with the economic logic behind
tute 70–80% of its economically active work Figure 3. We must distinguish, however, be-
force. 24 In Makueni, the resident family was tween household and individual specialization.
5.8, including two adult workers and children In the Kenyan case quoted above, the husband
in school. These figures do not suggest an concentrated on teaching, and his wife on
abundance of labor on family farms. In all four farming, and they both benefited from sharing
countries the farm household was also finan- resources. 26 In other cases, a second activity
cially and emotionally linked to adult children may be carried out in a different season––a man
and/or spouses who worked elsewhere either as farms in the wet season, and trades in the dry,
commuters, or for part of the year, or as per- so he can give full attention to each in turn.
manent urban residents. Family labor has to be Indeed, by turning over his capital several times
carefully allocated across occupations, and de- in the dry season, he gains additional resources
cisions have to be made as to whether to utilize to buy inputs for the farming season. 27 It is
child labor, or forgo it in favor of sending necessary again to distinguish between those
children to school. who sell small amounts out of necessity, and
The model in Figure 3 was built on the those who buy in from others and trade on a
premise that specialization brings benefits. It is considerable scale. The latter are generally in
apparent that farmer households in semi-arid the upper echelons of small farmers. CARE
areas do not specialize in the sense of only International au Niger and Universite dÕAri-
growing crops or only rearing livestock, nor in zona (1997) found grain sold by even in the
the sense of relying only on farm income. The most vulnerable households (56% of their Ma-
separation of farming and herding made sense radi sample) 28 who had then to finance by
in semi-arid areas in phase A with low popu- some means or another grain purchases later. A
lation density and limited access to markets for few people in this group and the middle group
farm products, but in phase B, in semi-arid (27%) were able to buy on a larger scale, as an
areas, the integration of crops and livestock by agent of a bigger trader who advanced them
smallholders becomes advantageous to provide money. Wholesaler traders who bought and
manure and draught power, the more so as resold hundreds of sacks of grain on their own
their main crops also provide animal feed. 25 In account were almost all in the ‘‘riches paysans’’
Maradi, many settled Hausa farmers were ac- category (17%).
quiring cattle, and many Fulani herders were It has been observed that diversification does
cultivating crops around a camp that was be- not necessarily level rural incomes. There is
coming permanent (CARE International au often a U-shaped relationship in which the
Niger & Universite dÕArizona, 1997; Morti- proportion of nonfarm in total farm household
1360 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

income is high for both rich and poor, and 2000). They were well aware that their children
lower in the middle groups (Barrett, Bezuneh, would need nonfarm incomes and, despite high
Clay, & Reardon, 2000; Bryceson, 2002; Iliya & costs, sent all boys and girls to primary school,
Swindell, 1997; Reardon, Taylor, Stamoulis, most to nursery school, and 20–30% to sec-
Lanjouw, & Balisacan, 2000; Toulmin et al., ondary school (with an anxious eye on the job
2000). When diversification is driven by des- market, to see if the latter was cost-effective). 29
peration, families try to cobble together a living Education was regarded as a priority expendi-
by farming, working for others, collecting, ture; and farm investments got what was left
hawking, handicrafts etc., and each activity over (Nzioka, 2000; Gichuki et al., 2000). On
may impede good achievement in the others. average the household included two nonresi-
Ellis (2000) refers to the key difference between dents, and while 23% of these worked on family
individual diversification and low levels of skill, farms elsewhere, 30 26% were in urban em-
associated with poverty, and household diver- ployment in the private sector, and 10% in ur-
sification, in which individuals specialize, which ban-based government employment. Due to the
is associated with the better off. In Nigeria, the lack of local towns, rural businesses and gov-
most successful farmers were those who had ernment services provided comparatively few
within their household someone in well-paid or jobs (Nzioka, 2000). Educated children in jobs
middling formal sector jobs, or in trading and were expected to, and did, assist their parents
contracting, which provided a cash flow to fi- with emergency expenditures, and, importantly,
nance farm inputs. These households contained with financial resources for investments to im-
individual specialists, backed by accumulated prove the farm (Nelson, 2000; Nzioka, 2000).
capital or skills, while in poorer households This is household diversification, with individ-
people scramble for casual labor alongside their ual specialization. A similar value was placed
own farming (Iliya & Swindell, 1997). This was on education in western Kenya (Francis, 2000;
also the case in western Kenya (Hamilton, Hamilton, 2003).
2003). In C^ ote dÕIvoire a middle group of spe- In Diourbel and Maradi the nonfarm occu-
cialist farmers could also be distinguished pations open to the illiterate young were mainly
(Barrett, Bezuneh, & Aboud, 2001). unskilled labor and petty trading. Rural par-
In Senegal, Table 3 and Figure 5 show that ents did not see their children as likely to suc-
the poorer households in Group 1 scraped a ceed in academically-oriented schooling, which
living from a diversity of local occupations. The starts from day one in French. Hence, migrat-
wealthier households in Group 3, who were ing rural children can contribute less to the
investing most in livestock, tended to have most productivity of the urban work force in Senegal
of their nonfarm income in the form of remit- and Niger than in Kenya. With unskilled jobs,
tances from urban-based children. Those in their small remittances assist subsistence, not
residence concentrated on farming, but in all farm investment (David & Niang, 1995; Diarra
households, around a fifth of the family work Doka, 2001; Wilson Fall, 2000). Nigeria is an
force was absent in the farming season (Table intermediate position, with some families able
3). Farmers in Diourbel calculate the oppor- to access jobs through education, and others
tunity cost of using their sonsÕ labor on the investing in traditional clientage relationships
farm or encouraging them to migrate to urban to access less skilled work or to get into trade.
areas or, if they can manage the higher cost, In Nigeria, as in Kenya, nonfarm earnings fi-
overseas. Some of the ceremonial expenses nanced farm investments (Iliya & Swindell,
listed in Table 4 support the Mouride leader- 1997).
ship in construction and merchant enterprises The market for farm labor has also become
in Dakar, Touba and overseas, where petty important, as efficient farmers need to buy in
trading, transporting, laboring, etc. provide labor at crucial times or for special tasks. In
income to adherents despite lack of formal Makueni we found wages varied according to
qualifications (Babou, 2002; Wilson Fall, 2000). demand, level of skill and value of marginal
A remarkable difference between Kenya and output (Nelson, 2000). Similar wage variation
the two francophone countries was in invest- was noted in Nigeria, where the agricultural
ment in education. Makueni parents invested labor market centers on towns, where it is
heavily in educating all their children, boys and easiest for seekers of employment and seekers
girls, motivated in part by the hope of quali- of labor to meet. Farmers with very small farms
fying one or more to compete successfully for a could intercalate work on these with work for
skilled or professional occupation (Nzioka, others, and because of their experience, were
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1361

preferred to cheaper student labor (Swindell and resources (Drylands Research, 2001).
et al., 1999). Communications infrastructure, (roads and
telephones), primary education, law and order,
and good management of the currency are
5. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY needed by all sectors, and by farmers as well as
IMPLICATIONS industrialists. The interaction between the two
sectors depends on good communications.
We need to understand the interrelationship Roads usable by lorries remain vitally impor-
of the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors tant both to farmers (Omamo, 1998) and urban
at different points in time as population grows, consumers. Education benefits both, if its con-
and redistributes itself between urban and tent and language are appropriate. Farmers in
rural. When the current round of censuses Kenya find education, which starts in local
has been analyzed, we shall probably find more languages, worthwhile for their children, and
evidence of rapid change, and governments invest their own money in building schools and
need to be ready with appropriate policies. The paying fees (Gichuki et al., 2000; Nzioka,
growth of the local urban market in SSA has 2000). Swahili, like Hausa, gives access to
been demonstrated. Policies which increase the written information in newspapers, advertise-
purchasing power of local urban communities ments, etc. Their adult children and spouses
are becoming more relevant than export- had a great variety of occupations. Farmers in
oriented ones. The recent drops in livestock the Sahel are not convinced of the benefit of
turnover in northern Nigeria due to falling free education starting in French, but illiter-
urban incomes (Ariyo et al., 2001) affect not acy cuts them off from written information,
merely farmersÕ incomes, but also their ability (whether on a fertilizer label or in the accounts
to insure, and to maintain soil fertility. of their groupement d’inter^et economique), and
Farmers have responded to increased de- from the better-paying nonfarm jobs.
mand by a multitude of small investments While farmers can usually find family re-
linked to changes in technologies and in prod- sources for a profitable investment, some ser-
ucts, but they have been hindered by state vices and investments can better be supplied
control of markets (as in Senegal) or rapidly collectively. Examples are preventative veteri-
changing policies, exchange rates and inflation nary services, some types of water develop-
(Nigeria, and to a lesser extent, Kenya). Agri- ment, and research.
cultural output can now only be increased by Turning to nonfarm sectors, it is clear that
very efficient combinations of land, labor and rural families, and especially the poorer ones,
capital. Those farmers who cannot invest are rely in part on nonfarm income, preferably in a
increasingly being forced out of farming. Some nearby town or village, if not, in a more distant
of the children of even the prosperous farmer city. 31 Premature, state-led industrialization
will need, or be attracted to, other livelihoods. has a poor record. By 1986 most of the state-
The rural poorest need a vibrant nonfarm sec- promoted industries in Maradi town, set up in
tor. the late colonial period, or during the uranium
The appropriate areas for government and boom had closed, and most employment was in
aid-assisted investment need to be identified the informal sector (Gregoire, 1990; Tiffen,
bearing in mind both the different types of in- 2001). In Senegal, the modern industrial sector
vestment most required by farm and nonfarm was for various reasons uncompetitive, over-
sectors, and the changing urban–rural balance. regulated, and suffered from ‘‘a domestic mar-
For some countries, such as Niger, the em- ket that was highly restricted by low-incomes’’
phasis must still be the enabling environment to (Berthelemy, Seck, & Vourch, 1996, p. 100), so
allow small farmers to build up their farms, and failed to expand. Nigeria has conditions more
become buyers of urban services and manu- conducive to successful industrialization, and
factures. Other countries now need to give the modern sector expanded in Kano during
more attention to attracting collective resources the oil boom, with both state and private cap-
to develop the urban sector, while at the same ital, but import-reliant industries suffered in the
time protecting farmersÕ capacity to invest to 1980s from shortages of raw materials, lead-
meet urban demand. Priorities for constrained ing to retrenchment of workers, underutiliza-
government and aid budgets must be the ser- tion of capacity, and closures. While sectors
vices and infrastructures which enable citizens dependent on local raw materials did some-
to make full use of their own talents, ingenuity what better (Olukoshi, 1996), modern industrial
1362 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

establishments fell from 327 in 1989 to 243 by towns. Government investment in providing
1993 (Tiffen, 2001). Industry was hindered by infrastructure to more towns––electricity, piped
rent-seeking, deteriorating services, and fall- water, telecommunications, etc.––may be more
ing demand from consumers hit by inflation effective than direct state investment in manu-
(Olukoshi, 1996). Runaway inflation and over- facture.
valued exchange rates hindered good manage- Governments cannot do everything, particu-
ment. 32 In turn, the downward pressures on larly if they are to avoid taxing away private
wages reduced effective demand for the higher incentive to invest. They cannot rely on aid,
value agricultural products. because aid availability per head is going down.
Productive investment in West Africa has Hence, as urbanization proceeds, both aid
been more lacking in the industrial sector, agencies and national policy makers need to
which needs collective investment, than in the think seriously about appropriate public in-
farm sector which, has responded with family vestments for particular countries at a parti-
investments. Kenya has a relatively successful cular time, and to be conscious that times are
modern sector, but concentrated in a few changing.

NOTES

1. It could be argued that the poorest of the poor could 7. The local black-smithing industry seems to have
be helped by income redistribution without growth, but responded to growing demand for more efficient metal
this is politically a more difficult option. tools earlier in West than in East Africa. In Nigeria it is
beginning to be replaced by factory-made equipment
2. They have been more successful in Asia than and parts supplied by state organizations (Iliya &
elsewhere. Kriekhaus (2002) has argued that public Swindell, 1997).
savings by states with ‘‘high bureaucratic capacity’’
can successfully allocate resources to strategic in- 8. Transport costs consist of fixed and variable costs.
dustrial sectors. In many cases, however, the need The former are relatively small for human and even
to manipulate resources to reward political support- animal transport, but high for lorries. Studies in Malawi
ers has predominated over what capacity there and Benin found traders used logical combinations of
might be. transport, using lorries for distances over 12 and 4 km,
respectively. Motorized transport costs were $0.63 and
3. Alexandratos (1995) gives a fuller review of devel- $0.28 per ton/km compared with nonmotorized costs
opment policy in regard to agriculture than is appropri- averaging $1.20 and $1.78. Trading costs were also high
ate here. in both countries because in the absence of telephones,
traders had to travel personally to obtain information,
4. There are also higher transaction, insurance and place orders, etc. (Fafchamps & Gabre-Madhin, 2001).
information costs in scattered markets (Myint, 1985)–– High trading costs apply to what farmers need to buy as
and disruptions from war and disorder. well as what they want to sell. Omamo (1998) has shown
how walking more than 8 km to purchase maize or sell
cotton in a market has high opportunity costs, and leads
5. World Bank (2000b, p. 68) quotes a discussion
to a preference prefer to earn cash by migratory labor.
group in Guatemala: ‘‘We think the earth is generous;
Poor roads reduce farm incomes, ability to supply food
but what is the incentive to produce more than the
to the towns, and ability to buy goods and services from
family needs if there are no access roads to get produce
urban areas.
to the market?’’

9. Exceptions will be industries processing bulky or


6. Malaysia has made a rapid transition in recent
perishable raw materials that need to be located near the
decades (Gemmell, Lloyd, & Mathew, 2000). Japan
source of supply.
is a well-known example of an earlier rapid
transition. Land-locked countries tend to take
longer than the seaboard countries since initially 10. IBRD (1981) Impact evaluation of the Muda
the most efficient transport for traded goods was scheme, consulted by the author for a report to the
water-borne. then Overseas Development Administration on Improv-
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1363

ing the Socio-economic and institutional content of 21. Statistics were only available from 1992, when the
irrigation feasibility studies (Research scheme R4006, District was formed. Agricultural officers were not able
ESR. 326/307/01, June 30, 1986). to get out much to estimate production due to budgetary
constraints.
11. Roads and railways, but also telephones and post
offices. 22. Fertilizer was still available at official prices from
state organizations in the 1990s, but tended to be
12. Most francophone countries had their first circa monopolized by big farmers or those with the right
1977 and another circa 1988. Some have held or planned connections, who might then sell on at higher prices.
a third, at some point 1996–2003 (United Nations Subsidies benefited mainly the big farmers (Iliya &
Statistics Division, Population and Housing Census, Swindell, 1997; Swindell et al., 1999).
http://unstats.un.org/unsd/demographic/census/cendate,
accessed 20/09/02). 23. Our Senegalese colleagues were particularly keen to
test this finding, which had depended mainly on extra-
13. FAOSTAT gives a more likely 114 million for polation from census data, and some reports––Tiffen in
2000. The 1963 census, used as the base for the BankÕs Barry et al. (2000). Villagers confirmed it.
calculations, is widely known to have been manipulated
upward for political reasons. 24. This takes little account of the income-earning
activities of wives, but in Hausa areas these generally
14. The total agricultural labor force is often estimated prefer to pursue their own crafts rather than to work
by reference to the population in a given age range, such unpaid on the husbandÕs farm.
as 15–64, from which those known to be in occupations
in the formal sector are deducted. The Bank in its 25. As population density rises, and more pasture land
Technical Notes to employment tables noted some but is converted to crop production, farmers need manure to
not all of the difficulties in estimating unreported replace fallows, and herders find the advantage of
economic activity. It ceased to provide agricultural combining farming and herding from a settled base, a
labor statistics after 1990, but FAO continues to change analyzed by Binswanger, McIntire, and Udry
estimate them in FAOSTAT. (1989).

15. Local food production must have been substantial, 26. There are also cases in Makueni where the husband
as their food imports in the same year were only $6 and works in the farm and the wife is a nurse or teacher.
$7 per capita, respectively.
27. As reported to the author by a farmer in Gombe,
16. Import data are fairly reliable for countries with Nigeria, in the 1960s.
ports, but not all provide it.
28. CARE interviewed men and women in more than
17. There is no need to produce more food than can 400 households throughout Maradi District, in 1996.
locally needed, since crops low in value in relation to
bulk can only be exported when transport links are 29. By 1998, there were slightly more girls in sec-
highly efficient––not usually the case in Africa. ondary. Parents having difficulty with the fees might
think sons had a better chance of earning without
18. The sample surveys were not intended to collect formal qualifications (Nzioka, 2000; Gichuki et al.,
data at a level to enable significance testing, but rather to 2000).
check and update the information available from the
district and the literature. 30. Sons are often given a part of the farm to use on
their marriage (but the parent retains the title deed).
19. It is not just surplus food that is sold, as some
households sell off grain after harvest or at other times to 31. Long-distance migration seems more disruptive to
meet urgent needs, buying back, often at a disadvantage family structure, judging by Francis (2000).
price-wise, later on.
32. Olukoshi (1996) regarded the stabilization of the
20. WoteÕs improved administrative status led to a macro-policy environment as a necessary condition for
telephone service and some electricity by 2000. the reversal of de-industrialization.
1364 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

REFERENCES

Alexandratos, N. (1995). World agriculture towards Boubacar, Y., & Ibrahim, B. M. (2002) Rapport de
2010: An FAO study. Chichester: FAO and John mission de restitution des travaux de recherche dans
Wiley & Sons. les villages de Jiratawa, Magami, Sharken-Hausa et
Anderson, D. (1990). Investment and economic growth. Dan-Kullu (Departement de Maradi, Niger). Un-
World Development, 18(8), 1057–1079. published report. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Re-
Ariyo, J. A., Voh, J. P., & Ahmed, B. (2001). Long-term search.
change in food provisioning and marketing in the Bryceson, D. F. (2002). The scramble for Africa:
Kano Region. Drylands Research Working Paper reorienting livelihoods. World Development, 30(5),
34. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research. 725–739.
Baba, K. M., & Magaji, M. D. (1998). Fadama crop CARE International au Niger & Universite dÕArizona
residue production and utilisation in north-western (1997). Evaluation de la securite des conditions de vie
Nigeria. In I. Hoffmann (Ed.), Prospects of pastoral- dans le Departement de Maradi. Niamey, Niger:
ism in West Africa (pp. 247–262). Giessen, Germany: CARE-International au Niger.
Tropeninstitut. Coulon, C. (1999). The Grande Magal in Touba: a
Babou, C. A. (2002). Brotherhood solidarity, education religious festival of the Mouride Brotherhood of
and migration: The role of the Dahiras among the Senegal. African Affairs, 98(391), 195–210.
Murid muslim community of New York. African David, R., & Niang, O. M. (1995). Diourbel, Senegal. In
Affairs, 101(403), 151–170. R. David (Ed.), Changing places? Women, resource
Balcet, J.-C. (1997) Retrospective assessment of farm management and migration in the Sahel (pp. 23–53).
technology adoption in northern Nigeria (1982– London, UK: SOS Sahel.
1997): emerging lessons for technology development Diarra Doka, M. (2001). E  volutions a long terme de
and the rural development agenda. Unpublished lÕorganisation sociale et economique dans la region
report. Washington, DC: World Bank. de Maradi. Drylands Research Working Paper 26.
Barrett, C. B., Bezuneh, M., & Aboud, A. (2001). Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research.
Income diversification, poverty traps and policy Drylands Research (2001). Livelihood transformations in
shocks in C^ ote dÕIvoire and Kenya. Food Policy, semi-arid Africa 1960–2000: Proceedings of a work-
26, 367–384. shop arranged by the ODI with Drylands Research
Barrett, C. B., Bezuneh, M., Clay, D. C., & Reardon, T. and the ESRC, in the series Ôtransformations in
(2000). Effects of non-heterogeneous constraints, African agriculture.Õ Drylands Research Working
incentives and income diversification strategies in Paper 40. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research.
rural Africa. Mimeo. Department of Agricultural, Ellis, F. (2000). Rural livelihoods and diversity in devel-
Resource and Managerial Economics, Cornell Uni- oping countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
versity. Fafchamps, M., & Gabre-Madhin, E. (2001). Agricul-
Barrett, C. B., Reardon, T., & Webb, P. (2001). tural markers in Benin and Malawi: The operation
Nonfarm income diversification and household live- and performance of traders. Policy Research Work-
lihood strategies in rural Africa––concepts, dynamics ing Paper 2734. Washington, DC: World Bank
and policy implications. Food Policy, 26(4), 315–331. Development Research Group, Rural Development.
Barry, A., Ndiaye, S., Ndiaye, F., & Tiffen, M. (2000). Fall, A. (2000). Makueni District profile: livestock
Region de Diourbel: Les aspects demographiques. management, 1990–1998. Drylands Research Work-
Drylands Research Working Paper 13. Crewkerne, ing Paper 8. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research.
UK: Drylands Research. Faye, A. (2002). Comte rendu de la journee de restitu-
Bell, C., Hazell, P. B. R., & Slade, R. (1982). Project tion: Recherches sur les politiques publiques et les
evaluation in regional perspective: A study of an investissements paysans dans la Region de Diourbel;
irrigation project in NW Malaysia. Baltimore: John CNRA de Bambey, 19 fevrier 2002. Unpublished
Hopkins University. report. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research.
Berthelemy, J.-C., Seck, A., & Vourch, A. (1996). Faye, A., & Fall, A. (2000). Region de Diourbel:
Growth in Senegal: a lost opportunity? Paris: OECD. Diversification des revenus et son incidence sur
Binswanger, H., McIntire, J., & Udry, C. (1989). lÕinvestissement agricole. Drylands Research Work-
Production relations in semi-arid African agricul- ing Paper 22. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research.
ture. In P. Bardhan (Ed.), The economic theory of Faye, A., Fall, A., & Coulibaly, D. (2000). Region de
agrarian institutions (pp. 122–144). Oxford: Claren- Diourbel: evolution de la production agricole. Dry-
don Press. lands Research Working Paper 16. Crewkerne, UK:
Boserup, E. (1965). The conditions of agricultural growth: Drylands Research.
The economics of agricultural change under population Faye, A., Fall, A., Mortimore, M., Tiffen, M., & Nelson,
pressure. London: Allen and Unwin. J. (2001). Region de Diourbel: synthesis. Drylands
Boubacar, Y. (2000). E  volution des regimes de propriete Research Working Paper 23e. Crewkerne, UK:
et dÕutilisation des ressources naturelles dans la Drylands Research.
region de Maradi. Drylands Research Working Francis, E. (2000). Making a living: Changing livelihoods
Paper 29. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research. in rural Africa. London: Routledge.
TRANSITION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 1365

Gaye, M. (2000). Region de Diourbel: politiques natio- Johnston, B. F., & Mellor, J. W. (1961). The role of
nales affectant lÕinvestissement chez les petits explo- agriculture in economic development. American
itants. Drylands Research Working Paper 12. Economic Review (September), 566–593.
Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research. Kenny, C., & Williams, D. (2001). What do we know
Gemmell, N., Lloyd, T. A., & Mathew, M. (2000). about economic growth? Or, why donÕt we know
Agricultural growth and inter-sectoral linkages in a very much? World Development, 29(1), 1–22.
developing economy. Journal of Agricultural Eco- Kherallah, M., Delgado, C., Gabre-Madhin, E. Z.,
nomics, 51(3), 353–370. Minot, N., & Johnson, M. (2000). The road half
Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic backwardness in traveled: Agricultural market reform in sub-Saharan
historical perspective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Africa. Washington, DC: International Food Policy
University Press. Research Institute.
Gichuki, F. N. (2000a). Makueni District profile: Kriekhaus, J. (2002). Reconceptualizing the develop-
farm development, 1946–1999. Drylands Research mental state: Public savings and economic growth.
Working Paper 1. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands World Development, 30(10), 1697–1712.
Research. Landes, D. (1998). The wealth and poverty of nations.
Gichuki, F. N. (2000b). Makueni District profile: soil London: Little, Brown & Co.
management and conservation, 1989–1998. Drylands Mahamane, A. (2001). Usages des terres et evolutions
Research Working Paper 4. Crewkerne, UK: Dry- vegetales dans le departement de Maradi. Drylands
lands Research. Research Working Paper 27. Crewkerne, UK: Dry-
Gichuki, F. N., Mbogoh, S. G., Tiffen, M., & Morti- lands Research.
more, M. (2000). Makueni District profile: synthesis. Mbogoh, S. G. (2000). Makueni District profile: crop
Drylands Research Working Paper 11. Crewkerne, production and marketing, 1988–1999. Drylands
UK: Drylands Research. Research Working Paper 7. Crewkerne, UK: Dry-
Gregoire, E. (1990). Croissance urbaine et sante a Maradi lands Research.
(Niger). Bordeaux: Universite de Bordeaux II. Meagher, K. (1997). Current trends in cross-border
Hamadou, S. (2000a). E  volution a long terme des grain trade between Nigeria and Niger. Paris:
productions agricoles, du systeme de commercialisa- IRAM.
tion et des prix des produits dans la zone de Maradi. Meagher, K., & Mustapha, A. R. (1997). Not by
Drylands Research Working Paper 32. Crewkerne, farming alone: the role of non-farm incomes in rural
UK: Drylands Research. Hausaland. In D. Bryceson, & V. Jamal (Eds.),
Hamadou, S. (2000b). Politiques nationales et investiss- Farewell to farms: De-agrarianisation and employ-
ement dans les petites exploitations a Maradi. ment in Africa. Aldershot, UK: Avebury Ashgate
Drylands Research Working Paper 33. Crewkerne, Publishing Ltd.
UK: Drylands Research. Mortimore, M. (1993). The intensification of peri-urban
Hamilton, P. (2003). Struggling to survive poverty: A agriculture: the Kano Close-Settled Zone, 1964–86.
survey of small farmersÕ coping strategies in rural In B. L. Turner, R. W. Kates, & H. L. Hyden (Eds.),
Kenya. ENABLE: Newsletter of the Association for Population growth and agricultural change in Africa.
better land husbandry, 16(March), 3–30. Gainesville: University Press of Florida.
Hassan, W. A., Hoffmann, I., & Steinbach, J. (1998). Mortimore, M., & Adams, W. (1999). Working the
Sheep and goat keeping under arable farming in the Sahel: environment and society in northern Nigeria.
Zamfara Reserve. In I. Hoffmann (Ed.), Prospects of London: Routledge.
pastoralism in West Africa (pp. 196–210). Giessen, Mortimore, M., Tiffen, M., Boubacar, Y., & Nelson, J.
Germany: Tropeninstitut. (2001). Department of Maradi: synthesis. Drylands
Helleiner, G. K. (1966). Peasant agriculture, government, Research Working Paper 39e. Crewkerne, UK:
and economic growth in Nigeria. Homewood, IL: Drylands Research.
Irwin. Mustapha, A. R., & Meagher, K. (2000). Agrarian
Hoffmann, I. (1998). Cattle marketing in Burkina Faso production, public policy and the State in Kano
after the devaluation of the Franc CFA. In I. Region, 1900–2000. Drylands Research Working
Hoffmann (Ed.), Prospects of pastoralism in West Paper 35. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Research.
Africa (pp. 127–135). Giessen, Germany: Tropenin- Myint, H. (1967). The economics of the developing
stitut. countries. London: Hutchinson University Library.
Hopkins, A. G. (1973). An economic history of West Myint, H. (1985). Organisational dualism and economic
Africa. London: Longman. development. Asian Development Review, 3(1), 25–
Iliya, M. A., & Swindell, K. (1997). Winners and losers: 42.
household fortunes in the urban peripheries of Nelson, J. (2000). Makueni District profile: income
northern Nigeria. In D. F. Bryceson, & V. Jamal diversification and farm investment, 1989–1999.
(Eds.), Farewell to farms: De-agrarianisation and Drylands Research Working Paper 10. Crewkerne,
employment in Africa. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate. UK: Drylands Research.
Jahnke, H. E. (1982). Livestock development systems and Nzioka, C. (2000). Makueni District profile: human
livestock production in tropical Africa. Kiel: Wis- resource management, 1989–1998. Drylands Re-
senschaftsverlag Vauk. search Working Paper 9. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands
Research.
1366 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

OÕBrien, D. B. C. (1975). Saints and politicians: Essays in Smith, A. (1776). The wealth of nations. London:
the organisation of a Senegalese peasant society. EverymanÕs Library, 1991, Random House (UK)
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Ltd. (Reprinted).
Okike, I., Jabbar, M. A., Manyong, V., Smith, J. W., Smith, J., Barau, A. D., Goldman, A., & Mareck, J. H.
Alinwumi, J. A., & Ehui, S. K. (2001). Agricultural (1994). The role of technology in agricultural inten-
intensification and efficiency in the West African sification: the evolution of production systems in the
savannahs: evidence from northern Nigeria Socio. northern guinea savanna of Nigeria. Economic
Economics and Policy Research Working Paper 33. development and cultural change, 42(3), 537–554.
Nairobi, Kenya: ILRI. Swindell, K., Iliya, M. A., & Mamman, A. B. (1999).
Olukoshi, A. (1996). Economic crisis, structural adjust- Making a profit, making a living: commercial farm-
ment and the coping strategies of manufacturers in ing and urban hinterlands in north-west Nigeria.
Kano, Nigeria Discussion Paper 77. Geneva: UN- Africa, 69(3), 386–403.
RISD. Tiffen, M. (2001). Profile of demographic change in the
Omamo, W. S. (1998). Transport costs and smallholder Kano–Maradi Region, 1960–2000. Drylands Re-
cropping choices: an application to Siaya District, search Working Paper 24. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands
Kenya. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Research.
80, 116–123. Tiffen, M., & Mortimore, M. (1994). Malthus contro-
Orr, A., & Mwale, B. (2001). Adapting to adjustment: verted: the role of capital and technology in growth
smallholder livelihood strategies in southern Malawi. and environment recovery in Kenya. World Devel-
World Development, 29(8), 1325–1343. opment, 22(7), 997–1010.
Pingali, P., Bigot, Y., & Binswanger, H. (1987). Agri- Tiffen, M., & Mortimore, M. (2002). Questioning
cultural mechanization and the evolution of farming desertification in dryland sub-Saharan Africa. Nat-
systems in sub-Saharan Africa. Baltimore: Johns ural Resources Forum, 26, 218–233.
Hopkins University Press. Tiffen, M., Mortimore, M., & Gichuki, F. (1994). More
Prabowo, D., & McConnell, D. J. (1993). Changes and people less erosion: environmental recovery in Kenya.
development in Solo Valley farming systems. Indone- Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons.
sia, Rome: FAO. Tomich, T. P., Kilby, P., & Johnston, B. F. (1995).
Reardon, T. (1997). Using evidence of household income Transforming agrarian economies: Opportunities
diversification to inform study of the rural nonfarm seized, opportunities missed. Ithaca: Cornell Univer-
labor market in Africa. World Development, 25(5), sity Press.
735–747. Toulmin, C., Leonard, R., Brock, K., Coulibaly, N.,
Reardon, T., Taylor, J. E., Stamoulis, K., Lanjouw, P., Carwell, G., & Dea, D. (2000). Diversification of
& Balisacan, A. (2000). Effects of nonfarm employ- livelihoods: evidence from Ethiopia and Mali. IDS
ment on rural income inequality in developing Research Report, No. 47. Brighton, UK: Institute of
countries: an investment perspective. Journal of Development Studies.
Agricultural Economics, 51(2), 266–288. Wiggins, S. (1995). Change in African farming systems
Republic of Niger (1992). Recensement de la population between the 1970s and the 1990s. Journal of Inter-
de 1988: Analyse des donnees definitives. national Development, 7(6), 807–848.
Romer, P. M. (1989). What determines the rate of Wiggins, S. (2000). Interpretating changes from the
growth and technological change? Country Econom- 1970s to the 1990s in African agriculture through
ics Department WPS. Washington, DC: World Bank. village studies. World Development, 28(4), 631–662.
Rostow, W. W. (1960). The stages of economic growth. Wilson Fall, W. (2000). Region de Diourbel: the family,
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. local institutions and education. Drylands Research
Schoonmaker Freudenberger, M., & Schoonmaker Working Paper 20. Crewkerne, UK: Drylands Re-
Freudenberger, K. (1993). Fields, fallow and flexi- search.
bility: natural resource management in Ndam Mor World Bank (1983). World Development Report 1983.
Fademba, Senegal. Drylands Paper 5. London: Washington, DC: World Bank.
IIED. World Bank (2000a). Can Africa claim the 21st Century?
Shaikh, A., & McGahuey, M. (1996). Niger case study: Washington, DC: World Bank.
capitalizing on change. In D. C. Clay, T. Reardon, & World Bank (2000b). World Development Report 2000/
A. Shaikh (Eds.), Population, environment and devel- 2001: Attacking poverty. New York: Oxford Uni-
opment in Africa: Dynamic linkages and their impli- versity Press.
cations for future research and development World Bank (2000c). World Bank Africa Database 2000.
programming (pp. 93–118). Michigan State Univer- CD-Rom. Washington, DC: World Bank.
sity: Institute of International Agriculture. World Bank (2002). World Bank Africa Database 2002.
Simon, J. (1977). The economics of population growth. CD-Rom. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Princeton: Princeton University Press. World Bank, O.E.D (1995). Nigeria, Impact Evaluation
Singh, B. B., Larbi, A., Tabo, R., & Dixon, A. G. O. Report, Kano Agricultural Development Project,
(2001). Improvement for crop-livestock systems de- Sokoto Agricultural Development Project. No.
velopment in West Africa. ILRI-IITA, Ibadan, 14767-UNI. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Nigeria.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi