Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 28

The Journal of Israeli History Vol. 26, No. 2, September 2007, pp.

201227

Mamlakhtiyut, Capitalism and Socialism during the 1950s in Israel


Avi Bareli

The debate over mamlakhtiyut (Zionist republicanism) in the early years of the State of Israel concerned the centrality of the state in the shaping of Israeli society. This article considers whether and to what extent this debate can be seen as a struggle over the possibilities of a left-wing mamlakhtiyut, aimed at an egalitarian politics, society and economy, as opposed to a mamlakhtiyut, based on structural stratication in the distribution of real political, social and economic power. It concludes that although in the short and medium term Israeli mamlakhtiyut was egalitarian in its socioeconomic policies, its political and educational policies fostered structural inequality in Israeli society.

The process of the foundation of the Jewish democratic nation-state is a unique case in many ways, notably insofar as a social democratic party was the main political force during its decisive years. The involvement of various socialist parties in the development of democratic regimes in European nation-states cannot compare with that of MAPAI (acronym for the Workers Party of Eretz Yisrael, the main party of the Zionist Labor Movement). This applies both to Mapais formative role from 1933 to 1948 in laying the foundations for the future establishment of a democratic nationstate, as well as to its role in the construction of a democratic regime during the early years of statehood (1948 1953). In countries like France, Spain, Great Britain, Denmark, Sweden or Germany, nation-states existed before the establishment of socialist parties, which subsequently attempted to shape them in their spirit and promote economic, social and political equality among their citizens. Although certain European socialist parties may have played a role in the establishment of a democratic regime in some existing European nation-states, they were not long-term ruling parties during those crucial years.1 The uniqueness of the Israeli case, relative to other
Avi Bareli is a lecturer in the Ben-Gurion Research Institute, Ben-Gurion University of the Negev. Correspondence to: Ben-Gurion Research Institute, POB 257, Sde Boker Campus 84990, Israel. Email: abareli@bgu.ac.il
ISSN 1353-1042 (print)/ISSN 1744-0548 (online)/2007/020201-27 q 2007 Taylor & Francis DOI: 10.1080/13531040701552132

202

A. Bareli

examples of the foundation of democratic nation-states, grants particular importance to the debates over mamlakhtiyut (Zionist republicanism) in the early period of independence.2 Hence, an understanding of the Israeli case can provide important insights into the relation of socialist parties with the mechanisms of the modern state. The debate over mamlakhtiyut, the multifaceted and multivocal debate over the shaping of the state during its early years and the centrality of the state in the shaping of Israeli society, took place mainly within the Zionist Labor Movement, although right-wing parties also took part. The fundamental question is whether this debate was an ethereal utopian, semantic discussion or whether it engaged with the status of the values of the Zionist Labor Party in shaping the political institutions of the new democratic nation-state. What concerns us here is whether and to what extent we may speak of a struggle over the possibilities of a left-wing mamlakhtiyut aimed at an egalitarian politics, society and economy, as opposed to a right-wing mamlakhtiyut that advocated a procedural and perhaps liberal democracy but was based on structural stratication in the division of real political, social and economic power. This larger question may be broken down into sub-issues that will be discussed in this article: did the political parties of the Labor Movement engage in a discussion as to how and to what extent political power and inuence on the new sovereign power would be transferred to the citizens? In other words, what was the desired measure of equality in the distribution of political power? Was there, in the Israeli case, a discussion of the conditions for the existence of a left-wing mamlakhtiyut in the political realm as well, or was it restricted to questions of shaping the economy and society? And if such ideological discussion of the political structure of the new state did take place, that is, insofar as there was discussion of the political viability of left-wing mamlakhtiyut, what was its actual effect? What was the relation between it and the discussion of the socioeconomic forms of mamlakhtiyut during the founding years of the state? This discussion was of decisive import during the early years of Israel and undoubtedly inuenced the internal political and socioeconomic form of the state. Even more important, however, were the issues omitted from these discussions, which attest to the limitations of the discourse. I will argue that while the socioeconomic foundations for a left-wing government were laid in the 1950s, its political infrastructure was inadequate. The failure to address political conditions and the lack of arrangements for stimulating political co-empowerment were important factors that led to the early demise of left-wing mamlakhtiyut in Israel. Anti-mamlakhti pseudo-socialist (in fact, sectorial) rhetoric obscured and weakened the political debate in the 1950s and prevented effective discussion of the appropriate political bases for a left-wing mamlakhtiyut in Israel. The anti-mamlakhti rhetoric of the debate within the Labor Movement blurred the choice between left-wing and right-wing mamlakhtiyut in both the political and socioeconomic spheres. By diverting the discussion to the question of the centrality of the new state in the process of nationbuilding in the 1950s, i.e. mamlakhtiyut itself, the debate failed to address the various political and socioeconomic options for mamlakhtiyut.

The Journal of Israeli History

203

This focus obscured the discussion that took place within the ranks of Mapai on left-wing or right-wing alternatives to the political and socioeconomic form of mamlakhtiyuti.e. the alternatives to the structure of power sharing and the proper extent of cooperation and equality in mamlakhtiyut. The anti-mamlakhti rhetoric directed against Mapai reduced the effectiveness of the critical discussion provoked by opposition forces within Mapai over the desired extent of equality in the distribution of political power in the state, which was crucial for the establishment of a long-term left-wing mamlakhtiyut. In its broader context, the weakness of this discussion indicates the theoretical weakness of political discourse in the State of Israel and the Zionist movement preceding the establishment of the state. Despite their historical ambitions, the founders of the state and the Zionist leaders did not prepare for their decisive political actions by conducting fundamental theoretical and political discussions, as did, for example, the American founding fathers. The discussion in this article will move from the debates on the social and economic aspects of Israeli mamlakhtiyut to those concerning its political aspects, focusing on social, economic and political equality (or inequality) within Israeli mamlakhtiyut during its early years. Although the socioeconomic analysis in sections three and four will, to some extent, stray from the limits of the political analysis of the debates on mamlakhtiyut, it is essential for understanding the crucial issue of this article: how did early forms of mamlakhtiyut affect the development of equality and inequality in Israel? This discussion may shed light on what was lost with the impoverishment of the debate over the political conditions of left-wing mamlakhtiyut in the early years of the state. Mapais temporary success in limiting inequality in the early years of independence was part of an important historical opportunity missed by the Zionist Labor Movement. 1. The Three Demands of Israeli Mamlakhtiyut

Mamlakhtiyut was the conception guiding the leadership of the State of Israel in the 1950s, as it attempted to reform the distribution of resources and power between civil society and the sovereign power that rose out of what were then known as the national institutionsthe semi-autonomous Zionist center that had developed in the pre-independence years around the Jewish Agency (led by Mapai since 1933) and the Vaad ha-Leumi (National Council) (led by Mapai since 1931). Mamlakhtiyut was thus a conception related to the transition from the semi-autonomous voluntaristic politics of the pre-independence years to the politics of sovereignty.3 In the preindependence years, the national institutions worked through secondary cultural and movement-based centers. The state leadership demanded that these secondary centers give up certain aspects of their mediatory activity between the state, which now replaced the national institutions, and the members of the Yishuv (pre-state Jewish community), who now became citizens of the State of Israel. This demand comprised three aspects. The rst was the new nations claim to the ultimate loyalty of its citizenspatriotism. The second was its claim to be the center

204

A. Bareli

of decision-making in normative questions and in issues of appropriation of resources, based on a democratic process encompassing all citizens, which required that citizens obey norms, that is, the laws of democracy and the order they impose. The third was the demand that the relations between citizens and the state be direct, egalitarian and impersonal, and that basic services such as employment, housing, education and health should not be tied to sectorial afliation or made conditional upon other relationships and acquaintances in civil society.4 While this demand is always only partially implemented in any given society, in Israel it was of extreme importance.5 It lent functional meaning to the term mamlakhtiyut in the 1950s. The demand for directness, equality and impersonality was, of course, connected to the development of the social functions of the state as practiced by most socialist parties, at the expense of the organizations of civil society. These three claims, the patriotic, the normative-democratic and the functional, made up the core of the mamlakhti concept. The debate over mamlakhtiyut in the 1950s revolved around the various positions towards this republican aim at tighter sociopolitical integration. This is a democratic-national rather than merely a democratic-procedural concept, even if it does contain a procedural-legal element; the demand for ultimate loyalty is a clearly national demand, as is the demand that the state be the primary normative arbiter; the latter is, fundamentally, a demand for national unity around the sovereign center, based on democratic legitimacy. Of course, the formation of civil consciousness, like the consciousness of integrationist mamlakhtiyut, is often fraught with tension. On the one hand, the state is made manifest through its sovereign institutions and bureaucratic organizations and becomes increasingly identied with the institutions of government. On the other hand, the state is considered a common object (res publica), a center of nationalism uniting all citizens, both the supporters and the opponents of the government. The state is thus both the government and the possession of all its citizens, demanding the loyalty of all. This tension was one of the main catalysts of the debates over mamlakhtiyut. Many of its opponents saw mamlakhtiyut as an illegitimate move of Mapai domination, a partisan appropriation of the res publica to serve party interests; the newness and lack of tradition-based legitimacy of the res publica and the sovereign power made this appropriation all the more contested. This denition of mamlakhtiyut as a republican endeavor designed to achieve greater integration of social belonging through the realization of the three demands mentioned above is not the only possible one. There are other denitions, which may be suitable for other discussions and do not necessarily contradict the denition provided here.6 A broader justication for the adequacy of this denition of mamlakhtiyut would require an extended discussion, beyond the scope of this article. Here, however, the test of the concept is its suitability to explaining Mapai mamlakhtiyut in the 1950s and its social and political perspectives. Mapai mamlakhtiyut was the subject of intense political debates in the 1950s, which in general may be divided into four critiques: rst, an anti-mamlakhtiyut critique launched by the main left-wing opposition party Mapam against Mapai; second,

The Journal of Israeli History

205

the criticism within Mapai against the hierarchical political structure of mamlakhtiyut, which accepted mamlakhtiyut and left-wing democratic principles, while emphasizing political equality; third, criticism that Mapai was not mamlakhti enough in shaping Israeli politics and society; and fourth, criticism of the development of the public economic sector and the limitations placed on the private sectorthat is, that the economic and social aspects of mamlakhtiyut were too leftist. The critique that Mapai was not mamlakhti enough in its policies and the critique of the leftist nature of mamlakhtiyut came from the right, from the General Zionists and the Herut Party, the two main parties that stood to the right of Mapai on socioeconomic issues.7 For the purposes of this article we are concerned mainly with Mapams anti-mamlakhtiyut critique, which will be discussed in the next section, and with the left-wing democratic pro-mamlakhtiyut critique within Mapai, which will be discussed in sections four and ve. 2. The Equation Mamlakhtiyut 5 Capitalism

In the 1950s mamlakhtiyut became the prominent banner of David Ben-Gurion and his party, Mapai. The purpose of the State of Israel was, in Ben-Gurions view, the political self-liberation of the Jews in their sovereign state. Thus, he saw it as crucial that they work as a united front, that is, as a single collective-national body, growing out of a varied civil society, which contained many legitimate disagreements but whose identity would develop around a center of political democratic authority. This was an important aim of Ben-Gurions activities in the pre-independence period and in the rst two decades of the states existence. In the 1950s Mapai was seen as a central actor in the mamlakhti formation of the State of Israel. Only after the political conict that erupted in 1960 with relation to the succession of Ben-Gurion,8 and especially after Mapai had passed into the hands of leaders who were Ben-Gurions political opponents, did mamlakhtiyut come to be identied with a rejection of the centrality of political parties in socioeconomic arrangements, especially of the centrality of Mapai.9 In 1948, several groups within the Zionist Labor Movement established a competing force, Mapam, a Zionist party with pro-Soviet leanings. Its main components were two communal settlement groups: Ha-Kibbutz ha-Meuhad, led by Yitzhak Tabenkin, and the Ha-Kibbutz ha-Artzi movement, founded by veterans of the Ha-Shomer haTzair youth movement, led by Meir Yaari and Yaakov Hazan. Smaller urban groups joined the two movements. In the rst general elections, Mapam became the second largest party after Mapai, and was stronger than the two main right-wing parties. The two political organizations of the Zionist Labor Movement thus made up the majority at the time of the establishment of the State of Israel, and remained a major force throughout the rst decade of statehood.10 At the time, the State of Israel was a new state, birthed by a socialist movement which had an original vision of constructive socialism and great potential for mobilizing volunteers for social and national service (through pioneers, halutzim).

206

A. Bareli

Mapai and Mapam thus had the opportunity and the wherewithal to shape the politics, society and economy of the new country based on the values and interests of the Zionist Labor Movement. As we shall see, the society and economy were indeed shaped signicantly, for good or bad, by the values of the Zionist Labor Movement and the shared interests of its social and political institutions, as well as by the interests of the communal settlement movements, in which Mapam played a prominent role. But, we shall ask, was Israeli politics shaped by the values of the Labor Movement? Was the construction and delegation of political power inuenced by the movements aims of partnership and equality? The ability of Mapai and Mapam to do so was, to a great extent, undermined by the conicts between them, by Mapams attacks on mamlakhtiyut in general, by the silencing of the proposals of an opposition faction within Mapai opposed to the dominant political shaping of mamlakhtiyut, and by the hierarchical bureaucratization of the majority party of the Labor Movement. The attacks by Mapam subverted any discussion of the political nature of mamlakhtiyut, i.e. of conditions necessary to create a measure of equality in the division of political power. Mapam was pushed into (or positioned itself in) the opposition during the rst years of statehood.11 Mapai, along with smaller members of the coalition for whom the economy was not the main interest, laid down the basic principles for what we might term the statehood phase in the complex process of nation-building begun by the Zionist movement in the rst decades of the twentieth century. This political situation led Mapam to severely criticize the path taken by Mapai in shaping the new state and to adopt a harshly negative rhetoric towards mamlakhtiyut.12 Members of Mapam accused Mapai mamlakhtiyut of undermining the social achievements of the Zionist Labor Movement in the pre-state years and leading the new country to capitalist social structures. Thus the platform adopted by the second Mapam congress asserted that the social reformists [Mapai] in Zionism, in abandoning the fundamental principles of the workers movement, have undermined the independence of the working class, abandoned its positions and subverted its mission in the State of Israel and in the Zionist movement. [Mapai] has cut its links to international solidarity and violated its ties with the workers of the world. The same congress claimed that Mapai was realizing the bulk of the plan of the bourgeoisie in the internal social realm.13 Mapam members presented themselves as attempting to protect the socialist voluntarist sector, which had developed under the British Mandate in the form of the settlement movement and the Histadrut (the general workers union). The Histadrut was a central organization comprising political parties and settlement movements of the Zionist Labor Movement, as well as social, educational, cultural and urban services; professional trade unions; cooperative unions; and construction rms and industrial plants. Mapam leaders saw Ben-Gurions mamlakhtiyut as an attack on the voluntarist socioeconomic sector, especially the values of equality, communality, and halutziyut (pioneering), which were its founding principles, in the attempt to replace them by new capitalist socioeconomic forms. Their trenchant criticism,

The Journal of Israeli History

207

opposing socialist voluntarism to capitalist mamlakhtiyut, had much resonance in the Israeli political discourse of the 1950s, displacing the more substantial question as to what the proper political foundations were for socialist mamlakhtiyut, which was a focus of Mapai discussion during the early years of independence.14 Mapams arguments against mamlakhtiyut were focused apparentlyand only apparentlyon its economic and social meanings: they were directed against the concentration of socioeconomic power in the hands of the state and the transfer of functions to government bureaucracy. This criticism is somewhat puzzling: if socialists tend to foster the development of the state, to work towards socioeconomic centralization and the regulation of the economy and the society through government bureaucracy, how did the left-wing Mapam (or perhaps it was less left-wing than normally presumed?) come to attack the socioeconomic manifestations of mamlakhtiyut? I suggest that Mapams stance wavered between its socialist positions and its organizational interests. While the former led it to support the socioeconomic manifestations of mamlakhtiyut, the settlement organizations that controlled the party and were fearful of Mapai-dominated government involvement in their affairs led Mapam to object to mamlakhtiyut. By contrast, the right-wing parties, the General Zionists and Herut, supported greater involvement of the state and its centralized control for a variety of reasons, in particular because they desired to restrict the economic and social role of the Histadrut and the settlement movements within the new society.15 This, they believed, would prepare the ground for a market economy and the advancement of the economic groups that were associated with it. Thus they sought to establish a socioeconomically right-wing mamlakhtiyut, essentially different from Mapais policies.16 While Mapai and the two right-wing parties shared the goal of strengthening the state, their aims were different: Mapai used the state in order to build a broad and strong public sector (governmental and Histadrut), while providing some support for the private sector and attempting to attract private investment from abroad. The rightwing parties, however, criticized the prominent expansion of the public sector. They demanded that the state focus solely on the construction of a strong and independent private sector, free from the competition of the nancial, commercial and industrial projects of the Histadrut and free from the inuence of its trade unions, while nurturing the social strata that would further develop the private sector. The right sought the almost exclusive transfer of capital, property and government franchises into private hands. Indeed, as we shall see, Mapam accused Mapai of realizing the plan of the right-wing parties in establishing a society and an economy based solely on capitalist foundations. This accusation was at the center of Mapams public campaign against the claim of the state, led by Mapai, to be the chief normative arbiter and against the states invasion of areas of activity which, in pre-state years, had been in the hands of groups like the settlement movement, the Histadrut, political parties or other sectorial organizations. Although this campaign was merely territorial, Mapams political

208

A. Bareli

rhetoric encompassed all debates over mamlakhtiyut under the oppositional categories of socialism versus capitalism. At the time, Mapam was characterized by pro-Stalinist tendencies, yet it described the dependence on the state, political centralization and the universalization of public services as actions encouraging capitalism. Public destruction was the title bestowed by Israel Galili, one of the main leaders of Mapams Ha-Kibbutz ha-Meuhad, on the tendencies of mamlakhtiyut.17 Yaakov Hazan, Meir Yaaris comrade in the leadership of the Ha-Kibbutz ha-Artzi organization of the Ha-Shomer ha-Tzair movement, the largest of the branches of Mapam at the time, accused Mapai of abolishing the Labor Movement. From the speakers podium at Mapams second congress in 1951, he declared that the true choice is between capitulation to the priests of the golden calf in Israel or the establishment of the hegemony of the independent workers class; the true choice is between Jerusalem and Wall Street.18 Nevertheless, Mapams members were well aware that in order to establish the new society on socialist principles or, at least, to reduce the severe inequality that characterized the rst years of the State of Israel, centralized mamlakhtiyut was essential, and hence the emphasis on the governments role in planning, supervision and even entrepreneurship, as well as the tighter sociopolitical integration unmediated by secondary centers. Thus, in contradiction to its rhetoric, which depicted mamlakhtiyut as the realization of the social projects of the bourgeoisie, Mapam supported increased government planning and supervision of the economy, and even supported the establishment of a large governmental sector of industrial plants.19 This position encouraged Meir Yaari, the leader of Ha-Shomer ha-Tzair in Mapam, to expect that the state would ensure the continued transfer of Jews to Israel, which at the time was called the ingathering of exiles.20 This was a task that no voluntary civil society could perform. Mapams position wavered between socialist mamlakhtiyut and sectorial antimamlakhtiyut. Its social and national view led it to support the centralization and universalization of social services, but the structural interests it represented led it to negate that very tendency. Sectorial insularity was liable to bring about social inequality and weaken national solidarity, but at that time Mapam was outside the centers of power and was not responsible for the extent of inequality or the lack of integration between the various parts of the new society. It could thus allow itself to focus on the organizational and political interests of the political elites that had established it in 1948. These elites had sectorial interests in freedom from governmental supervision, which led Mapam to negate the mamlakhti conception of proper reciprocal relations between the state and the various institutions of the Labor Movement, especially the Histadrut and the kibbutzim. Thus, as noted, Mapams criticism of mamlakhtiyut attributed to Mapai what we have characterized here as the position of the right. According to Mapam, Mapais actual policies, like the plans of the General Zionists and Herut, only employed big government in order to found a market economy, construct a middle class and bourgeoisie and foster social inequality. This, however, was mere rhetoric designed

The Journal of Israeli History

209

to protect Mapam against government encroachment as demonstrated by even a cursory glance at Mapais main socioeconomic policies in the 1950s, which, in fact, Mapam supported, in contradiction to its own rhetoric. In the following two sections we shall examine several socioeconomic features of mamlakhtiyut in the early period of independence and show that, even if they demonstrate contradictory aims, we can hardly characterize mamlakhtiyut as the realization of a bourgeois plan, as the Mapam congress called it. This discussion will prepare the ground for a consideration of the political aspect of mamlakhtiyut and the debate surrounding it in Israels early years of independence. 3. Mapais Left-wing Mamlakhtiyut: Short and Medium Range

Any discussion of Mapais sociopolitical policies is complicated by a fundamental contradiction. Although the rst 15 years of its rule were marked by a dramatic narrowing of social gaps, as a result of the policies of the government and the Histadrut, in this same period Mapai adopted hierarchical and segregationist models in politics and education which ensured that the historical moment of restricted inequality, achieved in the second half of the 1960s, would be short-lived; ever since, the tendency has reversed, resulting in a steady widening of socioeconomic gaps. In the space of this article I can draw only a very general picture of this phenomenon. The following discussion will therefore be limited to those aspects necessary for isolating some socioeconomic conditions that were conducive to left-wing mamlakhtiyut, and for evaluating the claim that, from a socioeconomic point of view, the mamlakhtiyut of the founding years of the state actually furthered the construction of capitalism and promoted the interests of the classes that would foster it. In the rst years after independence, when the number of Jews doubled as a result of the mass immigration of 1948 1952, severe inequality arose in all areas of social life. Hundreds of thousands lived in tents and in other crowded temporary dwellings, suffered from unemployment or worked in low-paying jobs and had poor access to basic social services.21 In this period work was distributed in ways that placed the veteran Israelis at the top of the social pyramid and doomed the new immigrants to social inferiority. Jews from Muslim countries (Mizrahim), who made up half of the immigrants of those years, also suffered from a sense of foreignness with regard to the veteran Israelis, mostly of European origin, and thus encountered more social barriers. They also had relatively less education and vocational skills, larger families and more traditional social orientations.22 The hierarchical division of labor between immigrants and veterans, the proletarianization of the immigrants and the special difculties of the Mizrahi immigrants, along with the embourgeoisement and upward mobility of the Ashkenazic veterans, who had greater economic opportunities in the given circumstances, were all the inevitable result of the Israeli governments decision to accept the immigration of entire Jewish communities and masses of displaced persons over the course of only three to four years. Moreover, the Arabs who remained within

210

A. Bareli

Israel after 1949 were, for the most part, poor villagers, isolated from their national and cultural centers.23 Hence, in the early 1950s it is evident that there was rampant inequality throughout Israeli society, even if we have no recorded statistics to bear this out. The claim that any particular government policy could have prevented the classand ethnically determined division of labor that created this inequality in the 1950s seems out of touch with the social and political realities of that time.24 Only a decision to restrict the mass inux of immigrants could have nipped that initial inequality in the bud.25 The more important question was, however, what was done from this social low point on, until the mid-1960s. How did the Mapai government deal with the severe social gaps engendered in the early 1950s? Economic indicators show that it succeeded in narrowing the gaps substantially. Fanny Ginor, relying on several studies, shows that in the late 1960s Israel was one of the most egalitarian societies with regard to distribution of income. In 1968/1969, the Gini coefcient measuring inequality in income in Israel was 0.327 (0 complete equality, 1 complete inequality). According to a study carried out by the World Bank on the extent of inequality in 81 countries, Israel was ranked fth in equality, after Sweden, Taiwan, Japan and Great Britain. With regard to the lower 40 percent of the population in income, Israel ranked seventh among the 81. The status of the middle 40 percent in income was similar to that of Sweden. Among countries that underwent rapid development, Israel was more like Taiwan and Sri Lanka in its relatively high equality, as opposed to countries like Brazil, which underwent development similar to Taiwans insofar as the GNP was concerned (in both cases, it was inferior to Israels), but was typied by great inequality (0.621 Gini coefcient in 1972).26 The relatively low inequality was reached not simply through development but through a particular development policy, which was relatively egalitarian. Most important for our study is Israels sharp transition from extreme inequality which resulted from unique historical circumstancesto a far lesser degree of inequality in the mid-1960s, in comparison with both developed and developing countries. From being a society marked by extreme social gaps between residents of the transit camps and the tents, on the one hand, and veteran Israelis, on the other, by the mid-1960s Israel became one of the most egalitarian societies in the world. This development was hardly self-evident. It was the result of the Mapai governments scal policythe policies of supply, development, employment, taxation and wagesand, to a lesser extent, a result of its welfare programs.27 Through a policy of austerity and through rationing of vital commodities, the Mapai government imposed egalitarian distribution of the limited supplies by requiring the veteran population to restrict its consumption. Mapai paid a high political price for this policy. Although its success was only limited, it prevented mass hunger and limited other dire social phenomena during the rst years of immigrant absorption. Through a consistent policy of intense development and full employment (excepting short periods of unemployment), the Mapai government prevented the development of poverty among wide sectors of the population.28 This policy remained in force until the economic

The Journal of Israeli History

211

recession of 1966.29 The policy of wage protection, fostered by Mapai from its positions in the government and the Histadrut, was an essential element in the drastic reduction of inequality in income. The crux of this policy was widespread enforcement of the principle of work organized through trade unions and the prevention of wage gaps among the salaried employees of the public sector through a policy of taxation and relatively uniform salaries. Their determination to prevent the development of severe wage stratication in the public sector even led the Mapai government in 1954 1956 to a heated head-on confrontation with the academic white-collar workforce in the public sector. Their representatives demanded differential salaries in response to the erosion of their salaries respective to those of clerks and workers, as a result of the taxation policy, ination and the salary rankings implemented by the government and the Histadrut. The crisis peaked in a general strike announced by the unions of the academic white-collar workforce in the public sector in 1956, demanding greater stratication between their salary and those of other employees in the public sector. The strikers failed to achieve their aims, and Mapais salary and taxation policies were ratied. Despite this failure, the strikers and other veteran Ashkenazic Israelis did eventually take advantage of the conditions of the immigrant absorption period to improve their socioeconomic status, including their salaries. Mapais policies in those years, however, restrained them, thus limiting the inequalities caused through such exploitation.30 This important case demonstrates Mapais sociopolitical orientation in this period: relative economic equality and prevention of the development of severe social stratication. The Gini coefcient for 1968/1969 was a result of government policy for the short and medium term, and was enforced despite the opposition of elite groups which later became dominant in Israeli society. This evidence may be sufcient to disprove Mapams claim that in the early years of the state mamlakhtiyut was the realization of a bourgeois plan. There are, however, additional facts that demonstrate the extent to which this claim was mere political rhetoric, divorced from all reality. Already in the early 1950s, at a time of severe shortages, the government implemented the rst steps towards a welfare state, providing free elementary education to the entire population.31 In the government and the Histadrut, not only did Mapai not accomplish bourgeois plans, but it even opposed them directly both through its dramatic policy of social equality and by developing the large productive sectors of the government and the Histadrut.32 In this sense, it was the accusations of the General Zionists and Herut that were justied, rather than the opposing accusations of Mapam. Mapai developed not only the Histadruts economic projects but also those of the moshavim and kibbutzim, which received subsidized government credit and deeds to large tracts of government land.33 Financially, they were the favored children of the government. We may assume that it was their cooperative and communal nature that motivated Mapai to develop them, since at the time the majority of the kibbutz movement was in opposition to the government and identied with Mapam. Mapam supported all these socioeconomic aspects of Ben-Gurions mamlakhtiyut. It supported the egalitarian tendencies of the scal policy, as well as the policy

212

A. Bareli

of developing the public sector and the cooperative and communal settlements. Thus, we may regard its criticism of mamlakhtiyut, i.e. that it was an imposition of capitalism on the State of Israel, as rhetoric that camouaged its underlying purpose: to protect the political, nancial and settlement institutions of Mapam from government encroachment. Mapams anti-mamlakhti rhetoric purported to be directed towards a left-wing socioeconomic order, whereas its real purpose was to gain structural-political protection from Mapai rule, a territorial holding action against the states encroachment on the settlement movement and the Histadrut, under the unfounded rallying cry mamlakhtiyut capitalism. 4. Mapais Right-wing Mamlakhtiyut: Long-Term Effects

What was stated in the previous section in respect of the implications of the socioeconomic policies of Mapai applies to the short- and medium-range periods only. In the long range, Mapais policies in the 1950s fostered structural inequality in Israeli society. This section will analyze two of the important tendencies in this policy in the context of the debate between Mapam and Mapai and within the ranks of Mapai on the politics and economics of mamlakhtiyut. Mapais socioeconomic policy was, as noted, characterized by a fundamental contradiction between the restraints on inequality in the short and medium term and the adoption of hierarchical and segregationist molds in the political and education systems. The bureaucratic patterns of Israeli politics in those years were based upon Mapais transformation into an organization that mobilized the population to the goals of the government, explained government policy and acquired support in exchange for personal benet. The heads of Mapai, led by Ben-Gurion, decided that it would be the center of a democratic-hierarchical politicsa politics based on periodic elections, free press and major elements of formal democracy, but which excluded the popular classes, especially the masses of new immigrants, from effective political inuence. Almost the entire leadership of Mapai, headed by Ben-Gurion, adopted this mold of politics, based on Mapais political machine and the strength of its leaders. They thereby rejected calls from the rank and le to turn the party into a base for a broadly inclusive politics, a mediatory institution through which its many citizenmembers could inuence the workings of the new political society.34 The heads of Mapai assigned it the role of mobilizing civil society through frameworks of power and dissemination of information, while preventing it from working in the opposite directionas a conduit for bringing the inuences of civil society to bear on the ruling powers. Mapai was designed to be a quasi-governmental force, assisting ministers in their connections with the public, rather than an organization that supervised the government or had substantial inuence upon it. This decision was an important stage in the process of creating a democratic politics with a hierarchical or elitist structure in the State of Israel. The decision in favor of political hierarchy helps explain why relative social equality was a short-lived phenomenon. One of the long-term results of these policies was that

The Journal of Israeli History

213

the popular classes and Mizrahim, who proted from the successful implementation of Mapais egalitarian socioeconomic position until the mid-1960s, lacked the political means to protect their relatively favored position and promote their interests in the distribution of state resources. They had no means of protecting themselves from the powerful Mapai political activists and leaders, who were at the top of the political ladder, or the relatively afuent Ashkenazic classes they belonged to. In later years, the established social classes could translate their political privileges, earned under Mapai rule, into socioeconomic benets without interference. Hence, from the 1970s, we begin to see the emergence of socioeconomic inequality, based on the political inequality that characterized the political structures of the 1950s. This process of hierarchical institutionalization, with its concomitant socioeconomic ramications, met with widespread opposition from Mapai members in the early 1950s, but none of the Mapai leaders added their voices to the critique. Mapam also failed to address this issue, and its members did not join the opposition within Mapai. This is not surprising since the two branches of Mapam, Ha-Kibbutz ha-Meuhad and Ha-Kibbutz ha-Artzi, and their urban branches were also fairly hierarchical bodies, which, at the time, were preoccupied with tightening discipline within their ranks.35 The political and bureaucratic elites in Mapam were similar to those in Mapai in their view of the desirable political structure: hierarchy. Thus, not surprisingly, Mapam did not attack the hierarchical structure of mamlakhti politics or its long-term socioeconomic implications. Insofar as we can judge from its public behavior, it was indifferent towards these issues, and if we extrapolate from the interests of the Mapam elites, they apparently supported Mapais policies in practice. The hierarchical-bureaucratic institutionalization of Israeli politics was thus one of the factors that brought the term of relative economic equality in Israel to an end during the 1960s. From the 1980s on, we see a reversal of the historical tendencies of the early years and the development of what a recent parliamentary committee on inequality termed a cruel trap of permanent and widening gaps in Israeli society, which were fostered by the dominant parties in Israel from the 1980s.36 Mapais educational policy from the mid-1950s had a similar inuence. The policy of educational tracking (haslalah), implemented in secondary education by Education Minster Zalman Aranne, channeled the graduates of elementary schools into separate streams, leading either to matriculation exams or to other tracks that did not.37 This contradicted the policy of socioeconomic equality practiced by Mapai during those years. The long-term effect of this policy was that many graduates of the Israeli education system lacked the capacity to compete in the work market of the 1970s, which lent increasing importance to secondary and higher education, a tendency that only increased in the 1980s and 1990s.38 This same hierarchical tendency typied the structure of higher education in the 1950s and had a long-term effect on social stratication in Israel.39 The long-term inuence of settlement and housing policy requires further study.40 To summarize: whereas in the short and medium terms Mapai successfully limited severe inequality, at least in the socioeconomic sphere, already in the 1950s it created conditions leading to long-term structural inequality.

214

A. Bareli

The contradiction between the short- to medium-term versus long-term effects of Mapais policies merits more extensive discussion.41 Briey, this contradiction resulted from the dual nature of Mapai in the 1950s (unlike in other periods), as both a workers party and a bureaucratic structure whose members belonged to the middle classes and sought to advance their own interests, as long as they did not harm the short-term electoral interests of their party. Insofar as socioeconomic policy was concerned, Mapais political elite tried to navigate their way between the interests of the social classes it represented, on the one hand, and the middle-class interests of the party leaders and activists, on the other. This gave rise to the gap between its egalitarian short- and medium-term socioeconomic policies and its long-term policies. Political pragmatism concealed fundamental contradictions. The dual nature of Mapaias both workers party and bureaucratic elitetypied Mapam as well, thus impeding its criticism of Mapais lack of egalitarianism in the distribution of political and educational opportunities. As in Mapai, Mapams elite was also served by the policies privileging the political elites and the bureaucratic apparatus, even if they conicted with its ideological identity. In any case, there was clearly no essential disagreement between Mapai and Mapam with respect to the economic and social aspects of mamlakhtiyut. Mapam supported the restraints on inequality in the short and medium terms, without criticizing the conditions that led to future structural inequality. This supports the conclusion of the previous section that Mapams claims that mamlakhtiyut was a means for shaping the economy and the society according to a capitalist model was merely a rhetorical cover for the true aim of the critiqueto guard against the states encroachment on the social organizations represented by Mapam. An examination of all Mapais socioeconomic policies yields conicting conclusions, as Mapai of the 1950s was not a uniform political body (as we shall explore further in the next section). For the moment, however, we may condently state that its socioeconomic policy was certainly not the realization of a bourgeois plan, either in the distribution of resources or in the distribution of socioeconomic power among the various sectors. One can hardly assume that Mapam members were unaware of this. Thus, whatever the degree to which Mapais policies contributed towards the creation of long-term inequality in Israel, those policies were not the target of Mapams criticism. This complexity, which resulted from conicting directions in the policies of Mapai and from the rhetorical vacillation of Mapam, should not obscure certain basic conclusions: Mapai employed state institutions towards various and even contradictory aims with regard to social equality during its years in power. But the source of the development of inequality in the early years of the state was not the mere fact of mamlakhtiyutthe centrality of state institutions in shaping the society and economy of the statebut, rather, the conicting social interests that motivated both Mapai and Mapam. The anti-mamlakhti rhetoric of Mapam created a false picture, as if the choice were between a lost socialism of the pre-state years and so-called mamlakhti capitalism. In fact, the choice was between right-wing and left-wing mamlakhtiyut. Thus, the anti-mamlakhti sectorialism of Mapam obscured both the nature of the

The Journal of Israeli History

215

choice and the need of the entire Zionist Labor Movement to clarify the socioeconomic and political form of mamlakhtiyut. 5. Left-wing Mamlakhti Politics: The Path Not Chosen

The choice between right-wing and left-wing mamlakhtiyut had, as we have seen, a socioeconomic dimension, which oscillated between left and right, as determined by the complexities of Mapai politics. Was there also a political dimension to the choice between left-wing and right-wing mamlakhtiyut? The relation between the distribution of socioeconomic power and the distribution of political power is clear: as we have seen, the choice of a hierarchical political constellation was an important source of the development of socioeconomic inequality in the long term. But in addition to its socioeconomic consequences, the measure of political freedom, or the nature of the distribution of political power, is also an independent criterion in the evaluation of Israeli mamlakhtiyut and its possible forms, whether right or left. In the case of European socialist parties, although the institutions of the state were at the core of their efforts to limit social inequality, they failed to develop molds for limiting inequality in the distribution of political power among citizens. They administered normal representative democracies. But the Zionist Labor Movement and its parties, Mapai and Mapam, were at a historical juncture unique among socialist partiesthey were the main political power at the time of the establishment of a state. Thus, they could implement their egalitarian ideology to shape the distribution of political power in the state. Indeed, many Mapai members thought that from 1948 the shaping of democratic politics in the new state from the ground up was one of the major challenges facing their movement. The party press was replete with demands that the new Israeli democracy be more direct or broader, a democracy of a different mold than that prevalent in the Western world.42 Thus, an article that appeared as early as April 1949 noted: We have obtained power, rule and inuence, and if these are not distributed over wide areas, and are not subject to the surveillance of a wide public, they will bring forth weeds and thistles and nourish forces of destruction and corruption.43 The imposition of the new sovereign authority on the civil society that developed in the pre-state years naturally provoked opposition: Mapams criticism of mamlakhtiyut was one of its important manifestations. Most of the members of Mapai, however, were committed to the mamlakhti conception as dened at the beginning of this article. For this reason and, of course, because their party was the party in power, they supported the governments aim of imposing its control over civil society. Many of them, however, demanded that this control be subject to broad democratic surveillance, i.e. that mamlakhtiyut be left-wing not only by restraining socioeconomic inequality but also by promoting political equality and empowering the citizens. They supported their government leaders, headed by Ben-Gurion, but wanted them to be subject to greater supervision on the part of elected party institutions.

216

A. Bareli

While approving of the political dimension of mamlakhtiyut, they demanded that it be based on as equal a distribution of power as possible. A common demand among Mapai members focused on the democratization of their party in the hope that a ruling party that was democratic within itself would mold an egalitarian mamlakhti politics. This would be a party whose branches would grant inuence to the rank and le and whose institutions would be chosen in honest periodic elections and effectively supervise the leaders in government and other centers of power, as well as the party machine, which had acquired substantial power in the early years of the state. Mapai would thus become a force supervising the ruling powers in the name of civil society, rather than merely a group operating within civil society in the name of the ruling government. Since Mapai was such a dominant factor in the shaping of Israeli politics in its early stages, they hoped that by making it a conduit through which prevailing desires of the public would percolate up (that is, by turning it into a vessel of participatory democracy), they would determine the nature of Israeli politics as a whole. Many of them supported increased representation in the new democracy by calling for district-wide elections and for conducting referenda among citizens, members of the Histadrut or party members on important and appropriate issues. The Mapai leadership, led by Ben-Gurion, chose the opposite direction, that of the hierarchical institutionalization of the party and centralized democratic politics, which conicted with the tradition of egalitarian participation that Mapai had inherited from its founding elites, those of the Second and Third Aliyah (wave of Jewish immigration to Palestine), which took shape during the rst two decades of the twentieth century. But the critics of hierarchical institutionalization were not only inspired by the past, by pre-independence days; they also believed that a participatory democracy was essential for the success of the practical tasks of the timethe mass transfer of Jews to Israel (the ingathering of exiles)and for realizing the ideological hopes of left-wing Zionism through the politics of the new state. Among the many oppositional voices, there were two groups that voiced particularly trenchant criticism: the Ha-Meorer (The Awakener) circle and the Tzeirim (Young) group. The former was made up of Mapai members who arrived in Israel from the Third Aliyah on and had inuence on the professional urban intelligentsia, as well as in the Histadruts daily newspaper, Davar (the main organ of Mapai at the time), the Histadrut health system (Kupat Holim), and the Tel Aviv branch of the party. The Tzeirim faction was a group of native-born veterans of the Israeli youth movements. These and other groups criticism of the emerging hierarchical structure of the Israeli political system expressed the unrealized communalist hopes that had guided the left-wing vision of Zionism since its outset. One of the main voices of participatory mamlakhtiyut was Yehiel Halpern, the leading gure on the editorial board of Davar and in the Ha-Meorer circle. Halpern called for the institutionalization of participatory democracy in Israeli society, and for the process to commence with the reformation of Mapai in this spirit, by turning the rule of the party over to its members. He summarized this demand by means of the key

The Journal of Israeli History

217

democratic-republican concept of the ownership of the state by the public. In an article published in Davar in January 1951, Halpern claimed that the large structural economic gap that was developing between absorbers and absorbees during the great wave of immigration, combined with the lack of experience of democratic rule and institutions on the part of those leaving the exiles of Asia and Africa as well as many of the post-World War II immigrants from Europe, threatened the relation of Israeli citizens to their state. Without a sense of ownership, anchored in actual political structures, a sense of belonging was not possible. It was only in Israel that many of the immigrants rst encountered a democratic form of government, but they would be indifferent to its values if they do not see what use they can make of the democratic privileges and freedoms in alleviating their suffering and fullling their basic needs. Halpern argued that the democratic government of Israel did not empower them with partnership in actual ownership of the state and the party; it did not enable them to become masters of their destiny. Halpern also insisted that the immigrants should have possession or part-ownership, not only of the state but of the Labor Movement and its public assets as well. Halperns approach blatantly conicted with that of the veteran Ashkenazim who sought to defend themselves against the invasion of immigrants by dominating the political organizations to which they belonged and of which Mapai, of course, was one of the most important. Halpern summarized his criticism as follows:
If the social and economic inequality between the various parts of the Yishuv endures, if the inequality within the working class itself continues to grow, the risk is serious that in our country, too, a rule of despots will arise, supported by and enslaved to foreign capital. With multitudes of destitute and disenfranchised in an ofcially democratic Israel, the tendencies towards communism and fascism will inevitably ourish among them, with all of the resultant consequences for the fate of Zionism and the mission of the ingathering of the exiles.44

One of the prominent features of Halperns criticism was his insistence on the interdependence of socialism and democracy, on both a logical-conceptual and an empirical-historical level. But Halpern is unique not only because he advanced the oftrepeated claim that socialism could not exist without democratic rule in state institutions but also because he arguedat a critical juncture in the history of the statethat socialism was impossible without a radical democratic approach to the political institutionalization of civil society, including its main organizations, especially the socialist party. The argument within Mapai between hierarchical and participatory mamlakhtiyut, which took place during the rst years of the state was, to a great extent, an argument over the political dimension of left-wing mamlakhtiyut. Those who advocated participatory mamlakhtiyut demanded that their party restrain the political inequality that accompanied the increasing power of the political center and the strengthening of the government bureaucracy and Mapais political machine. Their demand was based on the assumption, later to be proven correct, that there was a close relation between political and socioeconomic inequality. They suggested limiting political inequality

218

A. Bareli

through elements of unmediated democracy, which would be integrated into the representative democratic system then developing in Israel. This was a radical left-wing version of the mamlakhti conception, rather than anti-mamlakhti anarchism. The members of Ha-Meorer and the Tzeirim shared the notion that all manifestations of governmentsovereign authority in the hands of a democratic government, state bureaucracies and party machinerieswere essential tools of movements such as Socialist Zionism that sought change. Thus for them too, compliance with government decisions was a necessary element of political frameworks. They claimed, however, that without participation in decision-making, compliance becomes mere passivity. Their conception was clearly both radically democratic and mamlakhti. Mapai did not follow this path. Although many of its members in various branches of the party demanded that it be adopted, none of the leaders supported the idea. The party press was replete with demands for radical democratization, but the two groups that attempted to formulate a political force based on such claims, Ha-Meorer and the Tzeirim, were defeated after a short struggle with the party machine operated by the leadershipthe Tzeirim prior to the 1951 elections, and the Ha-Meorer circle shortly after the elections in 1952 1953. The discussion within Mapai on the political dimension of mamlakhtiyut was short-lived and ineffective. While the proposals to form new political power relations that would accord with the aims of Socialist Zionist liberation were very popular among the Mapai rank and le during the rst years of the state, the party leadership impeded their realization. In Mapam, on the other hand, there was no echo of the debate taking place in Mapai over the political dimension of mamlakhtiyut. The heads of Mapam and its members were indifferent to the proposals raised by the Mapai opposition. Mapams attacks focused on the socioeconomic aspects of mamlakhtiyut, and, as we have seen, they were merely hollow rhetorical devices. As far as the political dimension of mamlakhtiyut was concerned, Mapam remained silent. Mapam thus missed a historical opportunity to participate in the discussion of the political dimension of left-wing mamlakhtiyut in Israel. The particular channels in which the discussion of mamlakhtiyut between right and left took place resulted in mamlakhtiyuts being perceived as an intrinsically right-wing position. Thus, the unique conditions of the developing State of Israel notwithstanding, there was no effective discussion with a practical outcome with regard to the desired political nature of left-wing mamlakhtiyut. Mapam ignored the question, and although such discussion did take place among the various factions within Mapai, it was marginal and Mapais leadership had it rapidly silenced. In the end, politics in Israel was shaped in ways fundamentally similar to those of democratic European nation-stateswith the same formal and informal patterns for the distribution of political power, the same structure of representative political institutions, and the same political culture, regardless of whether the ruling parties were socialist or non-socialist. In Israel too, the socialist government made an impact, whether for good or bad, on the patterns of distribution of social and economic power, but not political power.

The Journal of Israeli History

219

Mapams anti-mamlakhti polemic had a socialist image, but it was in fact motivated by sectorial rather than socialist aspirations; thus, to a great extent, this misleading image derailed the possibilities for the development of a meaningful political discourse that might shape a left-wing mamlakhtiyut by creating new templates for the distribution of political power. Within Mapai, there were some preliminary manifestations of such discourse, but it met with indifference on the part of the Mapam leadership. Furthermore, the development of such a discourse was impeded by Mapams success in portraying mamlakhtiyut itself as problematic. Thus, the main axis of the discussion of mamlakhtiyut in the Zionist Labor Movement was not right-wing vs. left-wing mamlakhtiyut, in the distribution of political or economic power. The question of hierarchical or participatory politics never became the main issue on the agenda. The short-lived opposition within Mapai in the early days of statehood did not succeed in persuading the Zionist Labor Movement to limit the political inequality prevalent in the early State of Israel. The long-term inuence of this failure resulted in the establishment of structural political and socioeconomic inequality in Israeli society. Summary As a result of the positions of the Mapai leadership and of the entire Mapam movement during the rst years of the state, the unique opportunity presented by the establishment of a state with dominant social democratic forces was wasted. The state that emerged was characterized instead by relatively hierarchical political systems and extremely limited public inuence on the government. This failure was shared by Mapai and Mapami.e. the entire Zionist Labor Movement. It limited the period of relative success in the reduction of socioeconomic inequality to the short and medium range. Although it created communal and egalitarian social entitiesthe kibbutz, the moshav, the urban workers economic sector and the social services operated through the Histadrutat a key historical juncture the Zionist Labor Movement wound up fashioning a politically hierarchical form of mamlakhtiyut. Consequently, the relative socioeconomic equality it fostered did not last, as the people that beneted from it lacked the political means to defend it in later years. Here we see an important source of Mapais subsequent socioeconomic turn to the right, beginning in the mid-1960s (through the policy of planned unemployment, known as ha-mitun [the recession] in 1966), and exemplied in the policies of its heir, the Israeli Labor Party, which from the mid-1980s culminated in its becoming one of the leading forces supporting privatization. The dual nature of Mapaias both workers party and a party dominated by the political-bureaucratic elite of the middle class and identied with middle-class interestswas expressed through the conict between short-term egalitarian tendencies and long-term social stratication. This conict could not continue for long. It was nally resolved when the Labor Party became the prominent representative of Israeli social elites in its socioeconomic policies as well.

220

A. Bareli

The discussion within Mapai on the political conditions for the existence of stable left-wing mamlakhtiyut remained embryonic and ineffective and died out completely within ve years after the establishment of the state. It testies as to what could have been but was nota productive discourse on the foundations of the new state. This is surprising. The Zionist Labor Movement had been marked by great originality until that point. The situation was unique and provided enormous opportunities: a socialist movement founding a state. But, nonetheless, there was no serious reexive thought on the process of state-formation. How are we to explain this weakness? Perhaps the answer can be found in what I perceive as the anti-theoretical nature of the Zionist Labor Movement. While it had many practical accomplishments, neither it nor the other streams of the Zionist movement produced preliminary theoretical discussions like those we nd, for example, in The Federalist, preceding the foundation of the United States of America. At a key historical juncture, this was a grave defect. Despite the unique circumstances of the Zionist Labor Movement, this failure illustrates the problematic relation of socialism to the institution of the state, an issue of general theoretical import. Under the rule of social democratic parties, European governments generally enlarged their state bureaucracies substantially. Thus, the socialists themselves intensied the problem of power vested in the state apparatus, the question of how the ever-growing bureaucratic state could be effectively controlled by the citizens. This question is essential to the socialist project of liberation: although the intensive use of bureaucratic mechanisms turned the state and its offshoots into major tools of the socialists and their followers, both in Europe and elsewhere, socialists have almost completely ignored this dimension. Furthermore, the historical project of socialism was designed to empower the citizens. It was this aim that led socialists to develop many of the branches of the modern state. Nevertheless, socialism has not devoted any serious discussion to the question of how to maintain real inuence of the citizens on state action. They certainly did not analyze this from the point of view of the socialist liberation project. While some attempts were made to ensure the equitable distribution of socioeconomic power, they failed to develop methods to narrow the gap in distribution of political power in the modern state. Hence, the mechanisms of government and representative politics in countries led by social democrats for extended periods of times are not substantially different from those in countries led by other democratic forces. For this reason, the history of Mapai during the early years of statehood, as a party inuenced by many streams of European socialism, is of particular interest. The attitude of socialists to the state is fundamentally ambivalent. On the one hand, they usually tend to develop the role of the state in social and economic arrangements through the welfare state, Keynesian management of the macro-economy, state and public ownership of means of production, and so forth. In other words, they tend towards big government, towards the socioeconomic and administrativebureaucratic aspect that we have identied as mamlakhtiyut in the Israeli context. On the other hand, the political tradition of European socialism grants considerable weight to the utopia of the abolition of governments, seeing government as a tool

The Journal of Israeli History

221

of oppression. This tradition commonly assumes that there is an inherent contradiction between state compulsion and social freedom, and even a democratic government is merely, in the well-known phrase of the Communist Manifesto, a committee for managing the common affairs of the whole bourgeoisie or of the dominant social forces. In fact, although the development of the state and government bureaucracy was of greater historical signicance in the functioning and policy of socialist parties, the utopian socialist ambivalence with regard to the state also played a part. This is most evident in the actions of the Zionist Labor Movement during the rst years of statehood and was also one of the causes of the lack of effective discussion of the political conditions of left-wing mamlakhtiyut. An investigation of the tension between mamlakhtiyut and anti-mamlakhtiyut in the case of the socialist founders of the State of Israel can be extremely instructive for the more general relation between socialists and the state. Although Socialist Zionism was, in many ways, a unique phenomenon, many aspects that are present (although sometimes in latent form) in other socialist movements were more openly expressed in that movement simply because it was presented with a unique opportunity to realize its plans and build a new political society from the ground up. It can therefore serve as a touchstone for the understanding of the role of the state in socialism, and its failure can shed light, among other things, on the general disregard shown by socialists for the ways in which political power is distributed in the modern state.

Notes
[1] The German Social Democratic Party, which was the governing party at the time of the establishment of the Weimar democracy in 1918, is one such case. This party, however, remained in power for a very short time and faced powerful opposition from both left and right. See Mommsen, The Rise and Fall of Weimar Democracy. The Social-Revolutionary and Menshevik parties also played a role in the establishment of the short-lived Russian democracy in 1917. See Hosking, The First Socialist Society. [2] By mamlakhtiyut and its associated adjective mamlakhti, I refer to Zionist republicanism, which aimed at tighter social and political integration. David Ben-Gurion and his political colleagues supported this aim and, to a great extent, were guided by it. I will discuss the denition of mamlakhtiyut further in the rst section of the article. I prefer the Hebrew word mamlakhtiyut to its common translation, statism, in order to distinguish it from the French term etatisme. [3] For the tendency to play down the signicance of the categorical historical transition from voluntarism to sovereignty, see Shapiro, Ha-demokratiyah be-Yisrael, 119 44. [4] This, of course, also applies to religious, gender or ethnic afliation, though these elements are beyond the scope of this discussion. To some extent, this is also the denition of mamlakhtiyut given by Horowitz and Lissak in Trouble in Utopia, chaps. 2 and 5. See also Kedar, Ben-Gurions Mamlakhtiyut; Yanai, Ha-tsah ha-mamlakhtit shel David Ben Gurion, 169 89; idem., Musag ha-ezrahut, 494 504. [5] This demand was only partially implemented in the relation of the State of Israel to its Arab citizens. See: Jamal, Al dfusey kinun ha-i-shivyon ha-leumi be-Yisrael, 145 82; Jerais, Ha-aravim be-Yisrael; Greitzer, Ben-Gurion, Mapai ve-arviyei Yisrael, 151 68.

222

A. Bareli

[6] For example, the denition of mamlakhtiyut as civil religion does not contradict the denition provided here, but places greater emphasis on the ceremonial as opposed to the functional aspect. See Liebman and Don-Yehiya, Civil Religion in Israel, chap. 4. For another denition, closer to that proposed here, see the two articles of Yanai, n. 4 above. In Zion and State, Mitchell Cohen claims that the mamlakhtiyut of Ben-Gurion was a mobilizing concept that resonated with the Bible for many of its hearers. [7] In elections to the First Knesset in 1949, Herut won 14 of the 120 seats, and the General Zionists 7. See Divrei ha-knesset (Knesset record), vol. 1 [1949], rst session, booklets 1 17, sessions 1 49, pp. 3 4. In the elections to the Second Knesset, in 1951, the General Zionists won 20 seats and Herut won 8. Divrei ha-knesset, vol, 10, rst session, booklets 1 17, sessions 1 46, pp. 3 4. [8] The conict devolved directly from the question as to whether Pinhas Lavon, in his capacity as defense minister, bore responsibility for a failed Israeli Security operation in Egypt in 1954; Lavon, a possible heir to Ben-Gurion as head of the party and the state, was forced to resign after this failure. In 1960, his demand for a reinvestigation of the responsibility for the failure set off a chain of struggles over Ben-Gurions succession between groups within Mapai, leading to Ben-Gurions expulsion from the party in 1964. Afterwards, one of the groups of disputants on this issue, including Moshe Dayan and Shimon Peres, also left Mapai and founded Ra (Israel Workers List), with Ben-Gurion as its leader. [9] In the rst phase of mamlakhtiyut, in the 1950s, Mapai was the ruling establishments main agent for recruiting administrative manpower and elites and representing interest groups in return for their support. In its later stages, beginning in the 1960s, mamlakhtiyut presented itself as (or perhaps was in fact) a position that sought an end to the party system that the Israeli government had inherited from the pre-state period. Ra, the party of Ben-Gurion after leaving Mapai, was, in the end, the political body that adopted this version of mamlakhtiyut, which developed after the succession dispute of the early 1960s. [10] Mapai had 46 seats in the rst Knesset, and Mapam had 19 (Divrei ha-knesset 1: 3 4). Throughout the rst decade, they made up, between them, approximately half of the seats in the Knesset. [11] The two factions of Mapam, which later in 1954 split into two separate parties, only joined Mapai governments during the second half of the 1950s. By then, the political foundations of mamlakhtiyut had already been established, and Mapai, as senior partner, had already been shaped into a hierarchical party, while those opposing such arrangements were effectively silenced. On the failure of coalition negotiations between Mapai and Mapam in 1949, see Tzahor, Mapai, Mapam, 378 99. [12] For an analysis of the various forms of criticism of Mapai during the early years of independence, see Shavit, Meshihiyut, utopiyah u-pesimiyut, 56 78. [13] With the adoption of a single united platform of principles guiding the organizational structure, the Mapam Congress comes to a close, Al ha-Mishmar, 4 June 1951, 1 (Hebrew). For examples of the claim that Mapai was weakening the Histadrut, see Yaakov Yasur, Moatzot yitzur meshutafot, hitnakshut ba-igud ha-miktzoi (Cooperative production councils, an attack against the trade unions), ibid., 29 January 1950, 2; Pinhas Bendori, Al mishmar atzmautah ve-khlaliyutah shel ha-histadrut (Guarding the independence and scope of the Histadrut), ibid., 8 September 1950, 2. [14] For a more detailed analysis of Mapams criticism see Bareli, Mapai, chap. 9. [15] See, for example, Yohanan Bader, Ha-emet al matzavo shel ha-mishtar ha-nokhehi (The truth about the current government), Herut, 26 July 1951; L. Berger. Ma tihiyeh ha-idiologiyah ha-kalkalit shel ha-memshalah ha-hadashah? (What will the economic ideology of the new government be?), Ha-Boker, 31 August 1951; idem., Karikaturah shel meshek leumi (A caricature of a national economy), ibid., 7 September 1951.

The Journal of Israeli History

223

[16] See Histadrut ha-tziyonim ha-klaliimmieget ha-merkaz: Ha-tokhnit shelanu, ekronot le-mishtar alternativi (The Histadrut of General Zioniststhe center party: Our program, principles for an alternative government), Ha-Boker, 27 July 1951; Tnuat ha-herut: Matza peulot la-knesset ha-shniyah le-hakamat mishtar hadash be-Yisrael (The Herut movement: The platform of actions for the second Knesset, for the establishment of a new government in Israel), 5. Mediniyut kalkalit-hevratit (Socioeconomic policy), paragraph 3, Herut, 6 July 1951. [17] We will be an active agent in the liberation of the nation, in a covenant with our brethren for world revolution: From the words of Yisrael Galili in the Second Congress of the United Workers Party (Mapam), Al ha-Mishmar, 1 June 1951, 2 (Hebrew). [18] Al ha-Mishmar, 31 May 1951, main headline, The true choice: Jerusalem or Wall Street, 1, 4. [19] Margalit summarized it as follows: The leading and dominant force was to be the governmental sector and governmental capital working through a regime of comprehensive planning . . . . Margalit, Ha-idiologiyah ha-hevratit, 215, 217. See also the contemporary publications: Yosef Shatil, Meshek Yisraellean? (Israels economywhither?), Al-haMishmar, 20 January 1950, 4; H. Nahshon, 1948 1951 ba-mediniyut ha-kalkalit she Yisrael (1948 1951 in Israels economic policy), ibid., 11 May 1951, 3. See also the special issue of Al Ha-mishmar on the economy, 10 February 1950, especially articles by Yitzhak Ronkin and Moshe Sneh, 1, 2, 16. [20] Yaari, Kibbutz galuyot, 62. [21] Ginor, Pearim hevratiim, esp. 47 48; Lissak Ha-aliyah ha-gedolah, 95 120. See also Eisenstadt, Lissak, and Nahon, eds., Edot be-Yisrael; Ofer, ed., Bein olim levatikim; Swirsky, Lo nekhshalim. [22] See Amir, Hitpathut ramat ha-haskalah; Lissak, Ha-aliyah ha-gedolah, 95 106. [23] Beumel, Mediniyut ha-aayah, 409. [24] Shlomo Swirsky has not provided convincing arguments to support his thesis that the ethnic division of labor between Jewish immigrants from Muslim countries and those from Europe was the result of government policy, rather than a necessary consequence of the circumstances. See Swirsky, Lo nekhshalim, 12 56, esp. 17 20 and 56; Swirsky and Bernstein, Mi avad be-mah, 120 47. [25] This was the demand made by many in the absorbing society at the time. See Hacohen, Mediniyut ha-aliyah ba-asor ha-rishon la-medinah: Ha-nisyonot le-hagbalat ha-aliyah ve-goralam (Immigration policy in the rst decade of statehood: The attempts to restrict immigration and their outcome), in idem, ed., Kibbutz galuyot, 285 316. Cf. idem, Ha-garin veha-reihayim, and Olim bi-searah. [26] Ginor, Pearim hevratiim, 154 57. Ginor relies, among other sources, on Jain, Size Distribution of Incomes, and Sawyer, Income Distribution. In the comparison conducted by Sawyer among the 12 members of the OECD, we nd that, according to the data of 1968/1969, Israel was in sixth place, ahead of Canada, Holland, Spain, the United States, West Germany, Italy and France, and behind Sweden, Norway, Australia, Japan and Great Britain. See also Geva and Habib, Maarekhet ha-haavarot, 272 83. [27] On state policy, see Gross, Ha-mediniyut ha-kalkalit be-Yisrael, 325 41, and Ha-mishtar ha-kalkali be-Yisrael, 342 51; Barkai, Yemei bereshit, 33 52; Halevi and Klinov-Malul, Ha-hitpathut ha-kalkalit, 4 6; Alexander, Kalkalat ha-klitah, 79 93; Plessner, The Political Economy, 77 78. [28] For various evaluations of the economic program of 1952, see Barkai, Yemei bereshit, 54 69; Alexander, Kalkalat ha-klitah, 86; Gross, Ha-mishtar ha-kalkali, 344 46; idem, Ha-mediniyut ha-kalkalit. [29] On the dramatic change in Mapai policy, beginning with the 1966 recession, see Shalev, The Political Economy.

224

A. Bareli

[30] See Bareli and Cohen, Distributive Justice; idem, Middle Class. These articles are part of broader research being conducted on the confrontation between Mapai and the white-collar workforce. On the upward socioeconomic mobility of veterans in the context of mass immigration, see also Lissak, Ha-aliyah ha-gedolah, 95 106. [31] In Mapai, there was a struggle on this issue. See Doron, Ha-maavak. Cf. idem, Maanakei ha-ziknah, 300 26. See also Kanev, Yitzhak Kanev. [32] Greenberg, Ha-kalkalah ha-marhivah, 327 64. [33] Bein, Toldot ha-hityashvut, 95 396; Tzur, Ha-kibbutz ha-meuhad, 2:332 58, 3:9 45; Gvati, 100 shnot hityashvut, vol. 2, part 3, 9 52. [34] On opposition groups within Mapai and on Mapams position on these issues, see my forthcoming book, Mapai, chaps. 3, 4, 8. The materials presented in this and the subsequent section summarize some of my conclusions in the book. [35] See Beilin, Banim be-tzel avotam, 119 77. [36] The Parliamentary Investigative Commission on the Subject of the Social Gaps in Israel, Hitpathut ha-pearim ha-hevratiim be-Yisrael be-esrim ha-shanim ha-aharonot: Taktzir (The development of social gaps in Israel over the last twenty years: A summary) (Jerusalem: Ha-Knesset, 2002). [37] Swirsky, Zraim shel i-shivyon; Yona and Saporta, Ha-hinukh ha-kdam miktzoi, 68 104; Zameret, Zalman Aranne, 295 326. [38] Shwed and Shavit, The Occupational and Economic Attainments. [39] Cohen, Ha-universitah. See also Shavit et al., Ethnic Inequality. [40] The difculty being that the alternativeconcentrations of poor neighborhoods near the large citiesalso had negative social signicance. See Picard, Rakevet mi-Kazablanka, 581 614. [41] I hope to develop this explanation in further studies. The discussion on these issues was provoked through stimulating and extremely helpful debates with Daniel Gutwein. [42] Bareli, Mapai, chap. 7. [43] Aharon Shechtman (Shamir), Tnuah u-manganon (Movement and machinery), Be-Terem, April 1949. [44] Yehiel Halpern, Mi-ketz shavua: Kibbutz galuyot ve-shivyon sotziali (From the end of a week: The ingathering of exiles and social equality), Davar, 19 January 1951.

References
Alexander, Esther. Kalkalat ha-klitah ba-asor ha-rishon li-medinat Yisrael (The absorption economy in the rst decade of the State of Israel). Iyunim Bitkumat Israel 2 (1992): 79 93. Amir, Shmuel. Hitpathut ramat ha-haskalah shel ha-yehudim ba-ukhlosiyah uve-koah ha-avodah be-Yisrael 1950 1980 (The development of the level of education of Jews in the Israeli population and in the work force, 1950 1980). Sidrat maamarim le-diyun 85.08 (A selection of articles for discussion 85.08). Jerusalem: Bank of Israel, Research Division, 1985. Bareli, Avi. Mapai be-reshit ha-atzmaut, 1948 1953 (Mapai in the early independence years, 1948 1953). Jerusalem: Yad Ben-Zvi, in press. , and Uri Cohen. Distributive Justice and an Upcoming Middle Class: Conict between MAPAI and Academic Professionals prior the 1955 General Elections in Israel. Israel Affairs, forthcoming (2008). , and Uri Cohen. The Middle Class versus the Ruling Party during the 1950s in Israel: The Engine-Coach Car Dilemma. Middle Eastern Studies, forthcoming (2008). Barkai, Haim. Yemei bereshit shel ha-meshek ha-yisraeli (The early days of the Israeli economy). Jerusalem: Mosad Bialik, 1990. Beilin, Yossi. Banim be-tzel avotam (Sons in the shadow of their fathers). Ramat-Gan: Revivim, 1984.

The Journal of Israeli History

225

Bein, Alex. Toldot ha-hityashvut ha-tziyonit mi-tkufat Herzl ad yamenu (The history of Zionist settlement from the period of Herzl until the present day). Ramat-Gan: Masada, 1976. Beumel, Yair. Mediniyut ha-aayah klapei ha-aravim be-Yisrael: 1948 1968 (The policy of discrimination towards the Arabs in Israel: 1948 1968). Iyunim Bitkumat Israel 16 (2006): 391 413. Cohen, Mitchell. Zion and State: Nation, Class and the Shaping of Modern Israel, Oxford: B. Blackwell, 1987. Cohen, Uri. Ha-universitah ha-ivrit veha-ribud ha-maamadi-adati ba-asor ha-rishon (The Hebrew University and ethno-class stratication in the rst decade). In Hevrah ve-kalkalah be-Yisrael: Mabat histori ve-akhshavi (Society and economy in Israel: A historical and current view), edited by Avi Bareli, Daniel Gutwein, and Tuvia Friling. Special issue of Iyunim Bitkumat Israel (2005): 233 62. Doron, Avraham. Ha-maavak al ha-bituah ha-leumi be-Yisrael, 1948 1953 (The struggle over national insurance in Israel, 1948 1953). Jerusalem: The Hebrew University, 1975. . Maanakei ha-ziknah bi-shnot ha-50 veha-60 (Old age pensions in the 1950s and 1960s). Iyunim Bitkumat Israel 7 (1997): 300 26. Eisenstadt, Shmuel Noah, Moshe Lissak, Yaakov Nahon, eds. Edot be-Yisrael u-mikuman ha-hevrati (Ethnic groups in Israel and their social position). Jerusalem: Jerusalem Institute for Israel Studies, 1993. Geva, Yehuda, and Jack Habib. Maarekhet ha-haavarot ve-hithalkut ha-hakhnasah (The system of transfers and the division of income). In Ha-meshek ha-yisraeli: Hevlei tzmihah (The Israeli economy: Growing pains), edited by Yoram Ben-Porat. Tel Aviv: Am Oved, 1990. Ginor, Fanny. Pearim hevratiim ve-kalkaliim be-Yisrael (Social and economic gaps in Israel). Tel Aviv: Am Oved, 1983. Greenberg, Yitzhak. Ha-kalkalah ha-marhivah shel meshek ha-ovdim, 1948 1988 (The policy of economic expansion in the Histadrut). In Hevrah ve-kalkalah be-Yisrael: Mabat histori ve-akhshavi (Society and economy in Israel: A historical and current view), edited by Avi Bareli, Daniel Gutwein, and Tuvia Friling. Special issue of Iyunim Bitkumat Israel (2005): 327 64. Greitzer, Dina. Ben-Gurion, Mapai ve-arviyei Yisrael (Ben-Gurion, Mapai and the Arabs of Israel). In Ha-asor ha-rishon: 1948 1958 (The rst decade: 1948 1958), edited by Zvi Zameret and Hanna Yablonka. Jerusalem: Yad Ben-Zvi, 1998. Gross, Nahum. Ha-mediniyut ha-kalkalit be-Yisrael, 1948 1951: Beayot ha-haarakhah ha-mehudeshet (Economic policy in Israel, 1948 1951: Problems of re-evaluation). In idem, Lo al ha-ruah levadah: Iyunim ba-historiyah ha-kalkalit shel Eretz-Yisrael ba-et ha-hadashah (Not by spirit alone: Studies in the economic history of Eretz Israel in the modern period). Jerusalem: Magnes, 1999. . Ha-mishtar ha-kalkali be-Yisrael: Ha-asor ha-rishon (The scal regime in Israel: The rst decade). In idem, Lo al ha-ruah levadah: Iyunim ba-historiyah ha-kalkalit shel Eretz-Yisrael ba-et ha-hadashah (Not by spirit alone: Studies in the economic history of Eretz Yisrael in the modern period). Jerusalem: Magnes, 1999. Gvati, Haim. 100 shnot hityshavut (A hundred years of settlement). Tel Aviv: Ha-Kibbutz Ha-Meuhad, 1981. Hacohen, Dvora. Olim bi-searah: Ha-aliyah ha-gedolah u-klitatah be-Yisrael, 1948 1953 (Immigrants in turmoil: The great wave of immigration and its absorption in Israel, 1948 1953). Jerusalem: Yad Ben-Zvi, 1994. . Ha-garin veha-reihayim: Hityashvut Ha-olim ba-negev be-asor ha-rishon la-medinah (The kernel and the millstone: The settlement of immigrants in the Negev in the rst decade of statehood). Tel Aviv: Am Oved, 1998.

226

A. Bareli

, ed. Kibbutz galuyot: Aliyah le-Eretz Yisraelmitos u-metziut (Ingathering of exiles: Immigration to Eretz Israelmyth and reality). Jerusalem: Zalman Shazar Center, 1998. Halevi, Nadav and Ruth Klinov-Malul. Ha-hitpathut ha-kalkalit shel Yisrael (The economic development of Israel). Jerusalem: Akademon, 1968. Horowitz, Dan, and Moshe Lissak. Trouble in Utopia: The Overburdened Polity of Israel. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press, 1989. Hosking, Geoffrey A. The First Socialist Society: A History of the Soviet Union from within. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1992. Jain, J. Size Distribution of Incomes. New York: World Bank, 1975. Jamal, Amal. Al dfusey kinun ha-i-shivyon ha-leumi be-Yisrael (On patterns of establishment of national inequality in Israel). In Hevrah ve-kalkalah be-Yisrael: Mabat histori ve-akhshavi (Society and economy in Israel: A historical and current view), edited by Avi Bareli, Daniel Gutwein, and Tuvia Friling. Special issue of Iyunim Bitkumat Israel (2005): 145 82. Jerais, Sabri. Ha-aravim be-Yisrael (The Arabs in Israel). Haifa: El Ittihad, 1966. Kanev, Yitzhak. Yitzhak KanevAvi ha-bituah ha-leumi: Kovetz maamarim, neumim ve-raayonot (Yitzhak KanevThe father of National Insurance: Collected articles, speeches and interviews). Tel Aviv: Mahbarot Le-Sifrut, 1998. Kedar, Nir. Ben-Gurions Mamlakhtiyut: Etymological and Theoretical Roots. Israel Studies 7, no. 3 (fall 2002): 117 33. Liebman, Charles S. and Eliezer Don-Yehiya. Civil Religion in Israel: Traditional Judaism and Political Culture in the Jewish State. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1983. Lissak, Moshe. Ha-aliyah ha-gedolah bi-shnot ha-hamishim: Kishlono shel kur ha-hitukh (The great immigration of the 1950s: The failure of the melting pot). Jerusalem: Mosad Bialik, 1999. , et al. Arbaim shanah li-shvitat ha-yamaim (The fortieth anniversary of the sailors strike). Ramat Efal: Yad Tabenkin, 1992. Margalit, Elkana. Ha-idiologiyah ha-hevratit kalkalit shel Mapam, 1948 1954 (The socioeconomic ideology of Mapam, 1948 1954). In Ha-smol ha-meuhad: Darkah ha-hevratit shel Mapam be-reshit ha-medinah, 1948 1954 (The united left: The social path of Mapam in the early state, 1948 1954), edited by Elkana Margalit. Yad Yaari: Givat Haviva, 1994. Mommsen, Hans. The Rise and Fall of Weimar Democracy. Translated by Elborg Forster and Larry Eugene Jones. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1996. Ofer, Dalia, ed. Bein olim le-vatikim: Yisrael ba-aliyah ha-gedolah, 1948 1953 (Between immigrants and veterans: Israel during the great wave of immigration, 1948 1953). Yad Ben-Zvi: Jerusalem, 1996. Picard, Avi. Rakevet mi-Kazablanka le-moshav o le-ezor pituah: Klitat ha-olim mi-tzfon- Afrikah ve-ikhlus ha-periferiyah be-Yisrael ba-shanim 1954 1956 (A train from Casablanca to the moshav or development area: The absorption of immigrants from North Africa and the populating of the periphery in Israel in 1954 1956). In Hevrah ve-kalkalah be-Yisrael: Mabat histori ve-akhshavi, (Society and economy in Israel: A historical and current view), edited by Avi Bareli, Daniel Gutwein and Tuvia Friling. Special issue of Iyunim Bitkumat Israel (2005): 581 614. Plessner, Yakir. The Political Economy of Israel: From Ideology to Stagnation. Albany, NY: State University of New York, 1994. Sawyer, M. Income Distribution in OECD Countries. OECD Economic Outlook (July 1976). Shalev, Michael. The Political Economy of Labor-Party Dominance and Decline in Israel. In Uncommon Democracies: The One-Party Dominant Regimes, edited by T. J. Pempel. Ithaca, NY and London: Cornell University Press, 1990. Shapiro, Yonathan. Ha-demokratiyah be-Yisrael (Democracy in Israel). Ramat Gan: Masada, 1977.

The Journal of Israeli History

227

Shavit, Yaakov. Meshihiyut, utopiyah u-pesimiyut bi-shnot ha-hamishim: Iyun be-vikoret al ha-medinah ha-ben-guryonit (Messianism, utopia and pessimism in the 1950s: A study of the critique of the Ben-Gurionist state). Iyunim Bitkumat Israel 2 (1992): 56 78. Shavit, Yossi. Ethnic Inequality in University Education in Israel. Jewish Journal of Sociology 41, no. 1 and 2 (1991): 5 23. Shwed, Uri, and Yossi Shavit. The Occupational and Economic Attainments of College and University Graduates in Israel. European Sociological Review 22, no. 4 (2006): 431 42. Swirsky, Shlomo. Lo nekhshalim elah menukhshalim: Mizrahim ve-ashkenazim be-Yisraelnituah sotziologi ve-sihot im peilim u-feilot (Not lagging behind, but kept behind: Mizrahim and Ashkenazim in Israela sociological analysis and conversations with activists). Haifa: Mahbarot le-Mehkar u-Vikoret, 1981. Zraim shel i-shivyon (Seeds of inequality). Tel Aviv: Breirot, 1995. , and Deborah Bernstein. Mi avad be-mah, avur mi, u-tmurat mah? Ha-pituah ha-kalkali shel Yisrael ve-hithavut halukat ha-avodah ha-adatit. (Who worked in what, for whom, and for how much? The economic development of Israel and the formation of the ethnic division of labor). In Ha-hevrah ha-yisraelit: Hebetim bikortiim (Israeli society: Critical perspectives), edited by Uri Ram. Tel Aviv: Breirot, 1993. Tzahor, Zeev. Mapai, Mapam ve-hakamat memshelet Yisrael ha-rishonah, 1949. (Mapai, Mapam and the establishment of the rst government of Israel in 1949). Iyunim Bitkumat Israel 4 (1994): 378 99. Tzur, Zeev. Ha-Kibbutz ha-Meuhad be-yishuvah shel haaretz (Ha-Kibbutz ha-Meuhad in the settlement of the Land of Israel). Vol. 2. Tel Aviv: Ha-Kibbutz ha-Meuhad, 1982; vol. 3, 1984. Yaari, Meir. Kibbutz galuyot ba-aspaklariyah shel yamenu (The ingathering of the exiles in presentday perspective). Merhavyah: Sifriyat Poalim, 1954. Yanai, Natan. Ha-tsah ha-mamlakhtit shel David Ben Gurion (The mamlakhti vision of David Ben-Gurion). Cathedra no. 45 (1987): 89 169. Musag ha-ezrahut bi-tsato shel David Ben-Gurion (The concept of citizenship in the understanding of David Ben-Gurion). Iyunim Bitkumat Israel 4 (1994): 494 504. Yona, Yossi, and Yitzhak Saporta. Ha-hinukh ha-kdam miktzoi ve-yetzirat maamad ha-poalim be-Yisrael (Pre-vocational education and the creation of a working class in Israel). In Mizrahim be-Yisrael: Iyun bikorti mehudash (Mizrahim in Israel: A new critical study), edited by Hanan Hever, Yehouda Shenhav and Pnina Motza-Haller. Jerusalem and Tel Aviv: Ha-Kibbutz ha-Meuhad and Van Leer Institute, 2002. Zameret, Zvi. Zalman Aranne veha-produktivizatziyah shel bnei edot ha-mizrah (Zalman Aranne and the productivization of the members of the Mizrahi ethnic group). In Hevrah ve-kalkalah be-Yisrael: Mabat histori ve-akhshavi (Society and economy in Israel: A historical and current view), edited by Avi Bareli, Daniel Gutwein, and Tuvia Friling. Special issue of Iyunim Bitkumat Israel (2005): 295 326.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi