Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 25

PART

The Core of Macroeconomic Theory


PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory
2012 Pearson Education

1 of 29

The level of GDP, the overall price level, and the level of employmentthree chief concerns of macroeconomistsare influenced by events in three broadly defined markets: Goods-and-services market
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Financial (money) market Labor market

2012 Pearson Education

2 of 29

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

FIGURE V.1 The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

We build up the macroeconomy slowly. In Chapters 23 and 24, we examine the market for goods and services. In Chapters 25 and 26, we examine the money market. Then in Chapter 27, we bring the two markets together, in so doing explaining the links between aggregate output (Y) and the interest rate (r), and derive the aggregate demand curve. In Chapter 28, we introduce the aggregate supply curve and determine the price level (P). We then explain in Chapter 29 how the labor market fits into the macroeconomic picture.
3 of 29

2012 Pearson Education

Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output

23
CHAPTER OUTLINE The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
Other Determinants of Consumption

Planned Investment (I) The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)


The Saving/Investment Approach to Equilibrium Adjustment to Equilibrium
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

The Multiplier
The Multiplier Equation The Size of the Multiplier in the Real World

Looking Ahead Appendix: Deriving the Multiplier Algebraically

2012 Pearson Education

4 of 29

aggregate output The total quantity of goods and services produced (or supplied) in an economy in a given period.

aggregate income The total income received by all factors of production in a given period.

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

In any given period, there is an exact equality between aggregate output (production) and aggregate income. You should be reminded of this fact whenever you encounter the combined term aggregate output (income) (Y).

aggregate output (income) (Y) A combined term used to remind you of the exact equality between aggregate output and aggregate income.

2012 Pearson Education

5 of 29

The Keynesian Theory of Consumption


consumption function The relationship between consumption and income.

FIGURE 23.1 A Consumption Function for a Household

A consumption function for an individual household shows the level of consumption at each level of household income.

2012 Pearson Education

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

6 of 29

The Keynesian Theory of Consumption


With a straight line consumption curve, we can use the following equation to describe the curve: C = a + bY

FIGURE 23.2 An Aggregate Consumption Function

2012 Pearson Education

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

The aggregate consumption function shows the level of aggregate consumption at each level of aggregate income. The upward slope indicates that higher levels of income lead to higher levels of consumption spending.

7 of 29

The Keynesian Theory of Consumption

marginal propensity to consume (MPC) That fraction of a change in income that is consumed, or spent.

marginal propensity to consume slope of consumption function

C Y

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

aggregate saving (S) The part of aggregate income that is not consumed. SYC

2012 Pearson Education

8 of 29

The Keynesian Theory of Consumption


identity Something that is always true. marginal propensity to save (MPS) That fraction of a change in income that is saved. MPC + MPS 1 Because the MPC and the MPS are important concepts, it may help to review their definitions.
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is the fraction of an increase in income that is consumed (or the fraction of a decrease in income that comes out of consumption). The marginal propensity to save (MPS) is the fraction of an increase in income that is saved (or the fraction of a decrease in income that comes out of saving).

2012 Pearson Education

9 of 29

The Keynesian Theory of Consumption


FIGURE 23.3 The Aggregate Consumption Function Derived from the Equation C = 100 + .75Y

In this simple consumption function, consumption is 100 at an income of zero. As income rises, so does consumption. For every 100 increase in income, consumption rises by 75. The slope of the line is .75.
Aggregate Income, Y
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Aggregate Consumption, C 100 160 175 250 400 550 700 850

0 80 100 200 400 600 800 1,000

2012 Pearson Education

10 of 29

The Keynesian Theory of Consumption


FIGURE 23.4 Deriving the Saving Function from the Consumption Function in Figure 23.3

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Because S Y C, it is easy to derive the saving function from the consumption function. A 45 line drawn from the origin can be used as a convenient tool to compare consumption and income graphically. At Y = 200, consumption is 250. The 45 line shows us that consumption is larger than income by 50. Thus, S Y C = 50. At Y = 800, consumption is less than income by 100. Thus, S = 100 when Y = 800.
Y C = S AGGREGATE AGGREGATE AGGREGATE INCOME CONSUMPTION SAVING 0 100 -100

80
100 200 400 600 800 1,000

160
175 250 400 550 700 850

-80
-75 -50 0 50 100 150 11 of 29

2012 Pearson Education

The Keynesian Theory of Consumption


Other Determinants of Consumption The assumption that consumption depends only on income is obviously a simplification. In practice, the decisions of households on how much to consume in a given period are also affected by their wealth, by the interest rate, and by their expectations of the future. Households with higher wealth are likely to spend more, other things being equal, than households with less wealth.

2012 Pearson Education

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

12 of 29

Planned Investment (I)


planned investment (I) Those additions to capital stock and inventory that are planned by firms. actual investment The actual amount of investment that takes place; it includes items such as unplanned changes in inventories.
FIGURE 23.5 The Planned Investment Function

2012 Pearson Education

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

For the time being, we will assume that planned investment is fixed. It does not change when income changes, so its graph is a horizontal line.

13 of 29

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)


equilibrium Occurs when there is no tendency for change. In the macroeconomic goods market, equilibrium occurs when planned aggregate expenditure is equal to aggregate output. planned aggregate expenditure (AE) The total amount the economy plans to spend in a given period. Equal to consumption plus planned investment: AE C + I.

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Y>C+I aggregate output > planned aggregate expenditure C+I>Y planned aggregate expenditure > aggregate output

2012 Pearson Education

14 of 29

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)

TABLE 23.1 Deriving the Planned Aggregate Expenditure Schedule and Finding Equilibrium. The Figures in Column 2 Are Based on the Equation C = 100 + .75Y. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Planned Unplanned Aggregate Aggregate Inventory Output Aggregate Planned Expenditure (AE) Change Equilibrium? (Income) (Y) Consumption (C) Investment (I) C+I (Y = AE?) Y (C + I) 100
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

175 250 400 475 550 700 850

25 25 25 25 25 25 25

200 275 425 500 575 725 875

100 75 25 0 + 25 + 75 + 125

No No No Yes No No No

200 400 500 600 800 1,000

2012 Pearson Education

15 of 29

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)

FIGURE 23.6 Equilibrium Aggregate Output

Equilibrium occurs when planned aggregate expenditure and aggregate output are equal. Planned aggregate expenditure is the sum of consumption spending and planned investment spending.

2012 Pearson Education

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

16 of 29

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)


The Saving/Investment Approach to Equilibrium Because aggregate income must be saved or spent, by definition, Y C + S, which is an identity. The equilibrium condition is Y = C + I, but this is not an identity because it does not hold when we are out of equilibrium. By substituting C + S for Y in the equilibrium condition, we can write:

C+S=C+I
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Because we can subtract C from both sides of this equation, we are left with: S=I

Thus, only when planned investment equals saving will there be equilibrium.
17 of 29

2012 Pearson Education

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)


The Saving/Investment Approach to Equilibrium

FIGURE 23.7 The S = I Approach to Equilibrium

Aggregate output is equal to planned aggregate expenditure only when saving equals planned investment (S = I). Saving and planned investment are equal at Y = 500.
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory
2012 Pearson Education

18 of 29

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)


Adjustment to Equilibrium The adjustment process will continue as long as output (income) is below planned aggregate expenditure. If firms react to unplanned inventory reductions by increasing output, an economy with planned spending greater than output will adjust to equilibrium, with Y higher than before.
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

If planned spending is less than output, there will be unplanned increases in inventories. In this case, firms will respond by reducing output. As output falls, income falls, consumption falls, and so on, until equilibrium is restored, with Y lower than before.

2012 Pearson Education

19 of 29

The Multiplier

multiplier The ratio of the change in the equilibrium level of output to a change in some exogenous variable.

exogenous variable A variable that is assumed not to depend on the state of the economythat is, it does not change when the economy changes.

2012 Pearson Education

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

20 of 29

The Multiplier
FIGURE 23.8 The Multiplier as Seen in the Planned Aggregate Expenditure Diagram

2012 Pearson Education

PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

At point A, the economy is in equilibrium at Y = 500. When I increases by 25, planned aggregate expenditure is initially greater than aggregate output. As output rises in response, additional consumption is generated, pushing equilibrium output up by a multiple of the initial increase in I. The new equilibrium is found at point B, where Y = 600. Equilibrium output has increased by 100 (600 - 500), or four times the amount of the increase in planned investment.

21 of 29

The Multiplier
The Multiplier Equation Recall that the marginal propensity to save (MPS) is the fraction of a change in income that is saved. It is defined as the change in S (S) over the change in income (Y):

S MPS Y
Because S must be equal to I for equilibrium to be restored, we can substitute I for S and solve:
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

1 I Therefore, Y I MPS MPS Y


It follows that

1 multiplier , MPS

or

1 multiplier 1 MPC
22 of 29

2012 Pearson Education

The Multiplier
The Size of the Multiplier in the Real World In considering the size of the multiplier, it is important to realize that the multiplier we derived in this chapter is based on a very simplified picture of the economy. In reality, the size of the multiplier is about 2. That is, a sustained increase in exogenous spending of $10 billion into the U.S. economy can be expected to raise real GDP over time by about $20 billion.
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory
2012 Pearson Education

23 of 29

Looking Ahead

In this chapter, we took the first step toward understanding how the economy works. We assumed that consumption depends on income, that planned investment is fixed, and that there is equilibrium. We discussed how the economy might adjust back to equilibrium when it is out of equilibrium.
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

We also discussed the effects on equilibrium output from a change in planned investment and derived the multiplier. In the next chapter, we retain these assumptions and add the government to the economy.

2012 Pearson Education

24 of 29

REVIEW TERMS AND CONCEPTS

actual investment aggregate income aggregate output aggregate output (income) (Y)

multiplier

planned aggregate expenditure (AE)


planned investment (I) 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. SYC
MPC slope of consumption function C Y

aggregate saving (S)


consumption function equilibrium
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

exogenous variable

identity
marginal propensity to consume (MPC) marginal propensity to save (MPS)

MPC + MPS 1 AE C + I Equilibrium condition: Y = AE or Y=C+I 6. Saving/investment approach to equilibrium: S = I 7. Multiplier


1 1 MPS 1 - MPC

2012 Pearson Education

25 of 29

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi