Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 23

4.

ECONOMIC THEORY AND HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT: A


RICARDO’S UNEXPECTED GENERAL ASSERTION

Édith Klimovsky

Hermann | « Cahiers d'économie politique »

2020/1 n° 77 | pages 73 à 94
ISSN 0154-8344
ISBN 9791037003027
DOI 10.3917/cep1.077.0073
Article disponible en ligne à l'adresse :
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
https://www.cairn.info/revue-cahiers-d-economie-politique-2020-1-page-73.htm
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
Distribution électronique Cairn.info pour Hermann.
© Hermann. Tous droits réservés pour tous pays.

La reproduction ou représentation de cet article, notamment par photocopie, n'est autorisée que dans les
limites des conditions générales d'utilisation du site ou, le cas échéant, des conditions générales de la
licence souscrite par votre établissement. Toute autre reproduction ou représentation, en tout ou partie,
sous quelque forme et de quelque manière que ce soit, est interdite sauf accord préalable et écrit de
l'éditeur, en dehors des cas prévus par la législation en vigueur en France. Il est précisé que son stockage
dans une base de données est également interdit.

Powered by TCPDF (www.tcpdf.org)


4. Economic theory and history
of economic thought: a Ricardo’s unexpected
general assertion

Edith Klimovsky 1

Abstract
The aim of this article is to justify the relevance of economic theory for
achieving an accurate interpretation of past authors’ statements. In the light
of the contemporary classical theory, we analyze the Ricardian relationship
between the rate of profit and surplus labour in the Principles. In contrast
to what is usually assumed, we argue that such relationship is verified inde-
pendently of the labour theory of value. Ricardo discovers the limits of this
theory and never points out that labour values are necessary for relating the
rate of profit to surplus labour.
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
Théorie économique et histoire de la pensée :
une proposition ricardienne générale et inattendue
Cet article vise à justifier l’importance de la théorie économique pour parvenir
à une interprétation appropriée de propositions d’auteurs anciens. À la lumière
de la théorie classique contemporaine, nous analysons la relation ricardienne
dans les Principes entre le taux de profit et l’excédent de travail. En opposition
avec ce qui est généralement admis, nous montrons que cette relation se
vérifie indépendamment de la théorie de la valeur travail. Ricardo découvre
les limites de cette théorie et ne signale jamais que les valeurs travail sont
nécessaires pour rapporter le taux de profit à l’excédent de travail.

Keywords
Rate of profit, surplus labour, Ricardo, Sraffa.

Mots-clés
Taux de profit, excédent de travail, Ricardo, Sraffa.

JEL Classification: B12, B24, B51, D30.

1. Universidad Autónoma Metropolitana-Azcapotzalco (Mexico City); <ekb@azc.


uam.mx>.
I am very grateful to Carlo Benetti, Christian Bidard, David Gelbwaser, Alicia Rubín
and Natalie Vaisman for their valuable suggestions while writing this article. I also thank
the referees for their stimulating remarks and their careful reading.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 73 14/05/2020 17:30


74 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

Introduction

In this article we show the importance of the contemporary


economic theory for the history of economic thought. To illustrate
our point of view we consider the Ricardian assertion that “profits
depend on the quantity of labour requisite to provide necessaries for
the labourers” [Ricardo, 1821, p. 126].
Traditionally, this idea has been left aside because it is usually
associated to the labour theory of value, which only holds if the compo-
sition of capital is uniform. This is probably a consequence of Sraffa’s
interpretation according to which it is a “new”, “general” and “full
theory of value” adopted in the Principles [Sraffa, 1951, p. xxx, xxxii
and xxxiii-xxxiv] that enables Ricardo to determine the rate of profit
as a ratio of quantities of labour. If the Ricardian assertion depended
on the labour theory of value, its scope would be even more limited
since not all techniques are compatible with the labour theory of value
(see footnote 6). Another factor explaining why the Ricardian idea
disappeared from the contemporary classical theory of prices may be
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
Sraffa’s choice of the rate of profit, instead of the wage, as the exoge-
nous distribution variable.
The first part of this article establishes that Ricardo’s assertion on
the relationship between the rate of profit and surplus labour is veri-
fied in a contemporary general model, that is, independently of the
labour theory of value. The second part examines Ricardo’s arguments
in the light of the contemporary classical theory. Our reading of the
Principles confirms the outcome of the first part: it cannot be argued
that the Ricardian relationship implies the labour values.

1. Surplus labour and rate of profit


in the contemporary classical theory

We examine first two preliminary conditions for relating the rate


of profit and surplus labour. We then deal with the three classical
notions of surplus and show that surplus labour is the only surplus
univocally related to the rate of profit independently of the labour
theory of value. Finally, the third section analyses the consequences
of the determination of the rate of profit in physical terms.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 74 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 75

1.1. Two preliminary questions

The technique being given, in order to define the quantity of labour


required to produce the necessaries for workers, we have to add the
quantities of different types of labour employed in the production of
commodities and to know the physical composition of wages. The
first question is related to the classical method of homogenizing labour
(§ 1.1.1) while the second raises the issue of choosing the exogenous
distribution variable of the classical price system (§ 1.1.2).

1.1.1. The classical method of homogenizing labour


The different types of labour employed in production are as
heterogeneous as the commodities they produce. Therefore, their sum
implies their previous homogenization. In the classical tradition, they
are homogenized by means of wages, the structure of which is assumed
to be known. There are two variants of this principle, depending on
the standard in terms of which wages are expressed.
Let us consider an economy that produces n commodities and
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
employs k different qualities of labour. The quantities of them are a
technical datum, represented by a non-negative matrix, N ≥ 0, of order
n × k. If wages are expressed in terms of the wage of a particular
type of labour ‒for example, wa‒ the different qualities of labour are
reduced to quantities of this type of labour and the homogeneous
labour vector l (a) is:
l (a) = (1)

where ω is the vector of wages and the vector of the structure


of wages. Let L(a) denote the amount of labour of type a that repre-
sents the whole labour employed in the economy, which results from
adding the elements of vector l (a), that is L(a) = u´l (a), where u’ is the
(row) unit vector.
Wages can also be expressed in terms of the wage bill of the
economy W. The homogeneous labour vector l is:

(2)

In this second variant, adopted by Sraffa [1960, § 10], the quantity


of labour employed in each sector is defined as a fraction of the total
labour of society, u´l = 1.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 75 14/05/2020 17:30


76 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

Note that, unlike matrix N, neither vector l (a) nor vector l are
purely technical data since both depend on the structure of wages.
Consequently, the classical homogeneous labour quite differs from
Marx’s abstract labour, which is not a technical datum either but is
defined independently of wage relationship.

1.1.2. The exogenous distribution variable of the classical price


system
The classical price system represents capitalists’ decisions of produc-
tion and productive expenditure. In this framework, labour differs from
commodities because its reproduction does not depend on capitalist
rules. Unlike commodities, it has no price equation and the wage is not
a price but a distribution variable. Once labour has been homogenized
and the standard chosen, the price system has one degree of freedom
and a distribution variable must be fixed exogenously.
When, according to the classical tradition, wage is advanced from
capital, 2 the price system is written:
(1+r)(Ap+wl )= p(3)
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
where A ≥ 0 is a matrix of technical coefficients per unit of product,
verifying the Hawkins and Simon conditions. Matrix A presupposes
constant returns to scale and only represents the technique, being inde-
pendent of the proportions between sectors. Vector l can be obtained
as indicated either in (1) or in (2), and in both cases it represents
quantities of homogeneous labour per unit of product. An important
characteristic of system (3) is that its equations are not modified by
changes in the proportions between sectors.
In the classical tradition, the wage is conceived as the value of the
basket of goods necessary for the subsistence of the workers. This
basket is determined by historical and social factors and it represents
the exogenous distribution variable. As a result, the following equation
is added to system (3):
w = b´p(4)

2. Sraffa abandons the classical tradition and assumes that the wage “is paid post
factum as a share of the annual product” [Sraffa, 1960, § 9]. Then the price system is
written (1+ r)Ap + wl = p.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 76 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 77

where b´≥ 0 is the vector of goods consumed by workers. 3 In


this case, in order to homogenize the different types of labour before
determining prices, we must assume that all workers consume the
same goods in the same proportions, whatever the labour they perform
and the level of their wages [Klimovsky, 1998, p. 114 and 116-117].
In his outstanding mathematical analysis of Ricardo’s theory,
Dmitriev (1898) shows that this interpretation of wages results in a
loss of identity of labour, since workers may be assimilated to animals
or machines. The same idea is found in Sraffa: the goods consumed
by workers enter “the system on the same footing as the fuel for the
engines or the feed for the cattle” [Sraffa, 1960, § 8]. Furthermore,
this interpretation in terms of workers’ necessaries does not take into
account that wages “may include a share of the surplus product”
(ibid.). After some hesitation, Sraffa dissociates wages from workers’
consumption and follows “the usual practice of treating the whole
of the wage as variable” (ibid.). In his theory, the wage is conceived
as a purchasing power on the standard of prices. 4 As such, the wage
“does not acquire a definite meaning until the prices of commodities
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
are determined”, whatever the standard and not only “a more or
less abstract standard” [1960, § 44]. This difficulty explains Sraffa’s
choice of the rate of profit as the exogenous distribution variable. But
this contradicts the classical conception of income distribution as an
outcome of the power relation between capitalists and workers.
In our opinion, the wage may be still chosen as exogenous if the
wage-goods included in vector b´ satisfy two conditions. First, following
Sraffa, they are dissociated from workers’ consumption. Second, they
are conceived as a basket, agreed by workers and capitalists, in terms of
which wages are expressed in the wage bargaining process [Klimovsky,
1998, p. 118-122]. Thus, the exogenous wage is the expression of a
social agreement on both the level of the wage and the composition
of the basket in terms of which the wage is expressed. Summing up,
vector b´ in equality (4) represents the workers’ purchasing power
that results from the negotiation between classes. Then the wage

3. Vector b’ depends on the standard in terms of which wages are expressed in order
to homogenize the different types of labour.
4. As a consequence of Sraffa’s choice of the national income as the standard, the
wage becomes a purchasing power equal to a given share of wages in the national income.
Hence, the structure of vector b’ is the same as that of the net product.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 77 14/05/2020 17:30


78 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

expresses a social relation, as for the classical economists, and has a


precise meaning before the determination of prices, even though it is
dissociated from workers’ consumption.

1.2. Surplus and rate of profit

Three different notions of surplus are distinguished in the classical


theory: surplus product, surplus product available for profit, which
from now on we call net surplus product, and surplus labour. After
defining these three notions (§ 1.2.1), we examine the relation of the
last two with the rate of profit (§ 1.2.2).

1.2.1. The three notions of surplus


By definition, the surplus product is a vector obtained as a dif­ference
between the gross production and the total quantity of each commodity
used as a means of production in all sectors. Given the (row) vector
y´of production levels, we have:
y´(I – A)(5)
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
To define the net surplus product, we must take into account the
goods that compose the wage bill of the economy. In order to simplify
the formalization, we will adopt Sraffa’s variant of the homogeniza-
tion of labour which expresses wages in terms of the wage bill of the
economy. 5 By subtracting the (row) vector b´ of the total wage-goods,
we obtain the following vector of net surplus product:
y´(I – A) – b´(6)
The net surplus product is not a purely technical datum as the
surplus product because it also depends on the physical composition of
the total wage bill. Both surpluses depend on the proportions between
sectors because any change in the relative levels of gross production
modifies the structure of vector y’. Besides, in general, such vectors
cannot be compared regardless of prices.
Let us consider now surplus labour, which is the least common
but the most closely related to Ricardo. It is defined as the difference
between the total annual labour of society and the total direct and
indirect labour employed in the production of the wage-goods. Unlike

5. If wages are expressed in terms of the wage of a particular type of labour -for example,
wa, to define net surplus product and surplus labour replace b´ by La ba ´, 1 by La, and l
by l (a) in equation (6) and in all formulas in the rest of the text.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 78 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 79

surplus product and net surplus product, which are vectors, surplus
labour is a scalar representing a fraction of the total annual labour of
the society equal to:
1 – b´(I – A)-1l(7)
where vector (I – A)-1l represents the amount of direct and indirect
labour employed in production per unit of product, as a fraction of
the total annual labour of society.
Notice that, being based on the classical notion of homogenous
labour, this ‘classical surplus labour’ must not be confused with Marxian
notions of surplus labour and surplus value.
Surplus labour depends on the technique, defined by matrices A
and N, on the structure of wages, on the total annual labour of society
and on the physical composition of the total wage bill. An important
feature of surplus labour is that its size is determined without any
reference to prices and is not modified by changes in the proportions
between sectors if the total annual labour of society is unchanged.
This is so because, given the technique and the structure of wages,
the direct and indirect labour required to produce one unit of each
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
commodity does not change when the proportions are modified. This
property distinguishes surplus labour from both surplus product and
net surplus product.
Net surplus product and surplus labour are mutually implied.
Indeed, if wages absorb the total surplus, we have y´ (I – A)=b´, and
net surplus product is nil. And since y´l=1, we have: b´ [I – A]-1l=
y´ [I – A] [I – A]-1l=1, which means that there is no surplus labour either.
On the other hand, if there is no surplus labour, we have y´l=b´ [I – A]-1l,
hence y´ [I – A]l=b´l, which implies that there is no net surplus product
either, i.e. y´ [I – A]=b´. Hence, both notions are logically equivalent
but, as we will see in the next section, their relationship with the rate
of profit is very dissimilar.

1.2.2. The relationship between surpluses and the rate of profit


In the classical approach, the rate of profit is the suitable notion
concerning profits and not the profits bill, as for the Neoclassicals.
In terms of Smith, “profits of stock… are regulated altogether by the
value of stock employed, and are greater or smaller in proportion to
the extent of this stock” [Smith, 1937, p. 48]. This is the reason why
profits differ from wages.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 79 14/05/2020 17:30


80 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

The net surplus product is the basis for calculating a physical ratio:
the net surplus rate of commodities. This ratio relates the quantity of
each commodity in the net surplus product and the quantity of each
of them used as a means of production in the whole system. Therefore,
such rates depend on the proportions between sectors. Besides, since
total profits are equal to the value of the net surplus product of the
economy, the rate of profit is neither higher than the highest, nor
lower than the lowest of the net surplus rates of commodities. This is
the only relationship which can be established between the net surplus
product and the rate of profit.
The classical price system (3) can be written:
p = w(1+r)[I – (1+r)A]-1l(8)
Replacing the inverse [I – (1+r)A]-1 by the sum of the series of
powers I +(1+r)A+(1+r)2 A2 +(1+r)3 A3 +…, system (8) is rewritten:
p=w[(1+r)l+(1+r)2 Al+(1+r)3 A2l+(1+r)4 A3l+…] (9)
where vectors Al,A2l,A3l,… represent the quantities of labour corre­
sponding to the successive stages of the productive process. It follows
from (9) that, whatever the standard, the wage and the rate of profit
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
are inversely related. On the other hand, the relative prices of commod­
ities depend both on the direct and indirect labour quantities and on
the rate of profit. The labour theory of value only holds if vectors l,
Al,A2l,A3l,… are proportional. 6 That is, changes in the rate of profit
do not affect the relative prices, which are then proportional to the
quantities of labour employed directly and indirectly in the processes
of production, only if the value composition of capital is identical for
all commodities.
Introducing (8) into (4), we obtain the following fundamental
equation in which the rate of profit is the only unknown:
1=(1+r)b´[I – (1+r)A]-1l(10)
Equation (10) determines the rate of profit, which depends both
on the physical composition of vector b´ and on the quantity of direct

6. Mathematically, the proportionality of vectors l, Al, A2l, A3l,… implies that vector
l is the eigenvector associated with the maximum eigenvalue of matrix A. Thus, not all
techniques, defined by matrices A and N, are compatible with the labour theory of value
because there may be no positive wage structure which, given matrix N, allows to obtain
the vector l associated with the maximum eigenvalue of matrix A [Klimovsky, 1998, p. 31].

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 80 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 81

and indirect labour required to produce the goods that compose such
vector. 7 It also follows from (10) that r > 0 only if:
1 > b´ [I – A]-1l(11)
Thus, a positive surplus labour is the condition for a positive rate
of profit. This does not imply any hypothesis on the composition of
capital.
In conclusion, given the technique and the wage, the rate of profit is,
like prices and surplus labour, independent of the proportions between
sectors. Conversely, both profits and surplus product depend on
proportions. It follows that two economies having the same methods of
production, the same wage, the same structure of wages, and employing
the same quantity of labour, but differing in the proportions between
sectors, have the same rate of profit, the same prices, the same surplus
labour, but different net surplus products and therefore different
amounts of profits. The same rate of profit is associated to the same
surplus labour but to different net surplus products. Therefore, contrary
to net surplus product, surplus labour is univocally related to the level
of the rate of profit and thus is the suitable notion of surplus.
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
Equation (10) shows that the rate of profit depends on surplus
labour. Nevertheless, by definition, the rate of profit is a ratio between
net surplus product and total capital, both being expressed in terms of
prices. Therefore, it is necessary to go deeper into the analysis of the
relation between the rate of profit and the evaluation of net surplus
product and total capital in terms of quantities of labour.

1.3. Surplus labour and the determination of the rate


of profit in physical terms

It is usually claimed that, if the value composition of capital is


not uniform, the rate of profit cannot be defined as a ratio between
quantities of labour. In this section we examine how the contemporary
classical theory provides a clear-cut answer to the issue of whether the
uniform value composition of capital is necessary for the evaluation
of net surplus product and capital in terms of quantities of labour.
The theoretical tool is Sraffa’s notion of homothetic system related

7. The origin of this idea is found in Dmitriev [1898, p. 46-50], the Russian mathe-
matician who proposed the first mathematical formalization of the Ricardian theory of
the rate of profit in the Principles.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 81 14/05/2020 17:30


82 LA THÉORIE ÉCONOMIQUE EST-ELLE UTILE ?

to the actual system. In the first one, the rate of profit is physically
determined and thus independent of the evaluation of the net surplus
product and capital. We also show that homothetic and actual systems
have not only the same rate of profit but the same surplus labour as
well, if they employ the same quantity of total labour.
A system of production is homothetic when the structure of its total
product is the same as the structure of its total means of production,
and therefore also the same as the structure of its net surplus product.
In such systems, the net surplus rates of commodities are uniform:
siH = sH, ∀i. Hence, the rate of profit is determined in physical terms,
being equal to the uniform net surplus rate of commodities: rH = sH. In
Sraffa’s words: “the rate of profits… appears as a ratio between quan-
tities of commodities irrespective of their prices” [Sraffa, 1960, § 29].
As shown in § 1.2, the solution of the classical price system (3)
is independent of the proportions between sectors. Since the actual
system of production and the homothetic system related to it only
differ in their proportions, both have the same solution: the same
rate of profit r ‒determined in physical terms in the homothetic
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
system, r = rH‒ and the same prices. Thus, an essential feature of the
homothetic system, 8 which Sraffa mentions without highlighting it,
is that it allows us to determine the rate of profit of the actual system
independently of prices.
The homothetic system is built by applying Sraffa’s procedure for
obtaining the standard system: the proportions of the actual system
are modified in order to get a uniform rate of net surplus for all
commodities. Incorporating equation (4) into system (3), we have:
(1+r)(A+lb´)p=p (12)
which is a homogeneous linear system, just like its dual:
(1
(1+r)q’ (A+lb´)=q’ (13)
is the maximum eigenvalue of matrix (A+lb´). Vector q’ is defined
up to a scalar and, whatever its scale, it represents the homothetic
proportions. The net surplus rate of commodities is uniform and
equal to the rate of profit in
^
the homothetic system, which is written:
(1+r) [Q(A + lb´)]p = Qp (14)

8. This is a good example of Sraffa’s famous sentence: “Particular proportions… may


give transparency to a system and render visible what was hidden, but they cannot alter
its mathematical properties” [Sraffa, 1960, § 31].

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 82 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 83

^
where Q is the diagonal matrix of the homothetic proportions, defined
by vector q’. Systems (12) and (14) only differ in proportions and both
have the same rate of profit. Such a rate is determined irrespective of
prices in the homothetic system as a ratio between quantities of the
composite homothetic commodity which makes up the net surplus
product and the capital. 9 On the other hand, from (14) it follows that
the maximum eigenvalue of matrix (A+lb´) represents the technical
and social difficulty of producing the composite homothetic commo-
dity. 10 We have:

(15)

where is the inverse of the factor of net surplus of commodities.


The rate of profit is physically determined in the homothetic system
derived from the actual economy, then prices are defined so that
this rate of profit is the same in all sectors. In other words, the tech-
nical and social difficulty of production of the composite homothetic
commodity is generalized to all commodities of the actual system. Let
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
us notice the similarity with Sraffa’s interpretation of Ricardo’s Essay
on Profits [1815], in which the rate of profit is physically determined
in the agricultural sector because, according to Sraffa, corn “forms
both the capital… and the product” [Sraffa, 1951, p. xxxi]. Prices
are then determined so as to get a uniform rate of profit. Hence, the
corn difficulty of production is generalized to all other commodities.
As a matter of fact, the determination of the rate of profit irrespe-
ctive of prices leads to question Sraffa’s statement according to which
the rate of profit “must be determined through the same mechanism
and at the same time as are the prices of commodities” [see Sraffa,
1960, § 4]. Surprisingly enough, Sraffa does not revise his idea of a
simultaneous determination of prices and the rate of profit once he
has constructed the composite homothetic commodity.

9. The origin of this idea is found in Cartelier [1976, Chapter VI, § 91].
10. To extend the previous demonstration to Sraffa’s system, where the wage is paid
post factum, it is enough to replace the sum of matrices A+lb’ by the product of matrices
(I – lb’ )-1A, whose maximum eigenvalue represents the technical difficulty of production
per unit of product minus the wage bill of the economy:
[see Klimovsky 2006, p. 47-48].

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 83 14/05/2020 17:30


84 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

In the homothetic system, the rate of profit is independent of the


values used to evaluate both net surplus product and capital: prices,
quantities of labour, or any other values. It follows that the expression
of the rate of profit in terms of quantities of labour does not imply
at all the validity of the labour theory of value, which presupposes a
uniform composition of capital.
The physical rate of profit is not only independent of the compo-
sition of capital but of the scale of the homothetic system as well.
At this point an essential question is raised about the normalization
of vector q´: does it play a role in the relation between the rate of
profit and surplus labour? The answer is given by supposing that the
homothetic system employs “the whole annual labour of the actual
system” [Sraffa, 1960, § 26]. Sraffa’s hypothesis implies adding to
(13) the following equation:
q´l =1(16)
Sraffa introduces that assumption without giving any explanation,
while it plays a central role in our analysis. In this case, the homothetic
and the actual systems only differ by their proportions and, if both
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
systems employ the same quantity of labour, they have the same rate
of profit, the same prices and the same surplus labour, but different
net surplus products. Hence, the rate of profit is univocally related to
surplus labour in both the actual and the homothetic systems. This
is a general relation insofar as it does not depend on the technical
or value composition of capital. It is verified independently of the
labour theory of value. Summing up, the contemporary classical
theory shows that Ricardo is right when he asserts that the rate of
profit depends on the quantity of labour required to produce the
necessaries for workers.
In his “Introduction”, Sraffa argues that Ricardo’s theory of profit,
in the Principles, is related to a general theory of value:

“In the Principles, however, with the adoption of a general theory of value, it
became possible for Ricardo to demonstrate the determination of the rate of
profit in society as a whole instead of through the microcosm of one special
branch of production. At the same time he was enabled to abandon the
simplification that wages consist only of corn,… It was now labour, instead
of corn, that appeared on both sides of the account–in modern terms, both
as input and output: as a result, the rate of profits was no longer determined
by the ratio of the corn produced to the corn used up in production, but,

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 84 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 85

instead, by the ratio of the total labour of the country to the labour required
to produce the necessaries for that labour” [Sraffa, 1951, p. xxxii].

But he does not clarify what is the general theory of value which
authorizes the determination of the rate of profit as a ratio of quantities
of labour. Moreover, according to Sraffa, the “necessary” starting point
of a study of the chapter “On Value” in the successive editions of the
Principles is “a survey of the formation of the new theory of value out
of fragmentary elements of such theory which are to be found in the
Essay…” [Sraffa, 1951, p. xxx]. These fragments are the labour values
mentioned in the Essay: “Elsewhere in the Essay,…, there are passages
which foreshadow his full theory of value and already link it with the
theory of profits” [ibid., p. xxxiii]. And he quotes Ricardo immediately
after [Sraffa, 1951, p. xxxiii-xxxiii-xxxiv]:

“The exchangeable value of all commodities rises as the difficulties of their


production increase. If then new difficulties occur in the production of
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
corn, from more labour being necessary, whilst no more labour is required
to produce gold, silver, cloth, linen, &c. the exchangeable value of corn will
necessarily rise, as compared with those things” [see Ricardo, 1815, p. 19].

Our interpretation of Ricardo’s ideas about the rate of profit in


the light of the contemporary classical theory leads to a different
conclusion. We have shown that, in the classical price system, if the
homothetic corn assumption is ruled out, it is not labour but the
composite homothetic commodity that replaces corn. The rate of profit
is determined as the ratio of the net surplus product to the capital in
the homothetic system, irrespective of the evaluation of commodities.
We have also shown that the rate of profit depends on surplus labour
quite independently of the labour theory of value. By contrast, Sraffas’
assertions suggest the labour theory of value. Accordingly, the question
we have to ask ourselves is to what extent Ricardo’s theory of the rate
of profit in the Principles depends on the labour theory of value. This
theory only holds if the value composition of capital is uniform. The
notion of value composition of capital is an essential contribution of
Ricardo in his critique of Smith’s adding up theory of value. For these
reasons, it seems to us of great interest to analyze Ricardo’s arguments
in the light of contemporary classical theory.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 85 14/05/2020 17:30


86 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

2. Ricardo on the rate of profit in the Principles

Ricardo’s assertion relating the rate of profit to the quantity of


labour required to produce the necessaries for workers appears twice in
the Principles. First in the chapter “On Value”, where Ricardo explains
the effects of an increase in wages on relative prices and profits. And
second in the chapter “On Profits”, where Ricardo analyses the cause
of the permanent changes in the rate of profit. In both cases, Ricardo
does not make any explicit reference to surplus labour, which is only
implicit insofar as it is the difference between two magnitudes exten-
sively used by Ricardo: the total annual labour and the quantity of
labour directly and indirectly employed to produce the wage-goods. The
analysis of Ricardo’s writings in § 2.1 shows that the two prerequisites
for the definition of surplus labour are fulfilled: the homogenization
of different types of labour by means of their wages and the exogenous
wage of the homogenous labour. In § 2.2 we point out how Ricardo
conceives an increase in wages, how this increase modifies the rate of
profit, and what is the role of the value composition of capital in the
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
analysis of the effect of a variation of wages on relative prices. Finally,
in § 2.3, we examine the two hypotheses allowing Ricardo to simplify
his analysis of the cause of the permanent variations of the rate of profit.

2.1. Homogenization of labour and exogenous wage


in Ricardo’s Principles

Following Smith, Ricardo homogenizes the different types of labour


by using their wages, the structure of which is supposed to be constant.
He writes at the beginning of Section II of Chapter I:

“I must not be supposed to be inattentive to the different qualities of labour,


and the difficulty of comparing an hour’s or a day’s labour, in one employ-
ment, with the same duration of labour in another. The estimation in which
different qualities of labour are held, comes soon to be adjusted in the market
with sufficient precision for all practical purposes, and depends much on the
comparative skill of the labourer, and intensity of the labour performed. The
scale, when once formed, is liable to little variation” [Ricardo, 1821, p. 20].

In the title of Section III of Chapter I, Ricardo clarifies that


he takes into account “not only the labour applied immediately to

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 86 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 87

commod­ities…, but the labour also which is bestowed on the imple-


ments, tools, and buildings, with which such labour is assisted” [ibid.,
p. 22]. In modern terms, it amounts to using vector (I – A)-1l.
Regarding the exogenous distribution variable, there is no doubt that
Ricardo chooses the wage. In the chapter “On Wages”, he conceives
the wage as the price of a basket of goods [see, for example, 1821,
p. 95], that “varies at different times in the same country, and very
materially differs in different countries. It essentially depends on the
habits and customs of the people” [ibid., p. 96-97]. This implies
adding equation (4) to the price system (3), so that the rate of profit
is endogenously determined. We also find the wage as the exogenous
variable throughout Chapter I, where Ricardo studies the effect of a
change in wages on profits, and in the chapter “On Profits”.
Ricardo’s idea about the exogenous wage is opposed to Sraffa’s
well-known choice of the rate of profit as the exogenous variable
“susceptible of being determined from outside the system of produc-
tion, in particular by the level of the money rates of interest” [Sraffa,
1960, § 44].
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
2.2. Effect of a change in wages
on the rate of profit and relative prices

The central theme of the chapter “On Value” is to discuss Smith’s


adding up theory of value, according to which, if the wage raises all
prices increase and the rate of profit is not modified. Ricardo shows that
an increase in wages entails a reduction in the rate of profit, the effect
on prices depending on the relation between the capital composition
of each commodity and that of the standard.
According to Ricardo, an increase in wages results from “the
circumstance of the labourer being more liberally rewarded”, or of “a
difficulty of procuring the necessaries on which wages are expended”
[ibid., p. 48]. In modern terms, it is a matter of an increase in the
components of vectors b´ or [I – A]-1l  11. In both cases, surplus labour
and net surplus product decrease (see (6) and (7)). Therefore, equa-
tion (10) is implicit in Ricardo’s analysis. This equation clearly shows
that the rate of profit will fall. Ricardo’s conclusion is quite exact:

11. See Ricardo [1821, p. 143].

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 87 14/05/2020 17:30


88 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

the reduction in the rate of profit is explained by the increase in the


quantity of labour required to produce wage-goods or, in other words,
by the decrease in surplus labour.
Let us now examine the effect of a variation in wages on relative
prices. The main analytical tool is the composition of capital which,
in Ricardo’s terminology, depends on the ratio between the capital
that supports labour and the capital invested in tools, machinery and
buildings, and also on the ratio between circulating and fixed capital,
on the durability of the latter, and on the time required for the different
goods to reach the market. In modern terms, the capital composition
can be represented by the distribution of dated quantities of labour
over time (see equation (9)).
The titles of Sections IV and V illustrate Ricardo’s discovery of
the limits of the labour theory of value. Nevertheless, in Section IV,
Ricardo puts forward that a fall in the rate of profit caused by an
increase in wages has relatively slight effects:
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
“The greatest effects which could be produced on the relative prices of these
goods from a rise of wages, could not exceed 6 or 7 per cent.; for profits
could not, probably, under any circumstances, admit of a greater general and
permanent depression than to that amount” [ibid., p. 36].

Note that this famous statement, worthy of modern econometrics,


contradicts the title of Section IV itself and also Ricardo’s assertion in
the first edition of the Principles:

“… the accumulation of capital, by occasioning different proportions of


fixed and circulating capital to be employed in different trades… introduces
a considerable modification to the rule, which is of universal application in
the early states of society” [ibid., p. 66].

These contradictions clearly illustrate Ricardo’s trouble. A further


illustration is found immediately after:

“In estimating, then, the causes of the variations in the value of commodities,
although it would be wrong wholly to omit the consideration of the effect
produced by a rise or fall of labour, it would be equally incorrect to attach
much importance to it” [ibid., p. 36].

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 88 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 89

Ricardo concludes:

“and consequently, in the subsequent part of this work, though I shall occa-
sionally refer to this cause of variation, I shall consider all the great variations
which take place in the relative value of commodities to be produced by the
greater or less quantity of labour which may be required from time to time
to produce them” [ibid., p. 36-37].

Despite this assertion, in Section VI “On an invariable measure of


value”, Ricardo resumes the idea of the influence of the rate of profit
on the prices of goods produced with a proportion of fixed capital
different from that of the standard. He states:

“… as we have shown, every alteration in the permanent rate of profits would


have some effect on the relative value of all these goods, independently of any
alteration in the quantity of labour employed on their production” [ibid., p. 45].

The very search for an invariable measure of value does not make
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
sense if prices are not affected by changes in the income distribution.
But, a few lines below, once more Ricardo minimizes the effects of
such changes by saying: “but I have already remarked, that the effect
on the relative prices of things, from a variation in profits, is comparat­
ively slight” [ibid. p. 45]. However, almost at the end of Section VI,
Ricardo comes back to the central theme of the chapter “On Value”,
‒the critique of Smith’s adding up theory of value‒ and highlights
the effects of differences in the composition of capital for the analysis
of the influence of a change in income distribution on relative prices
[see ibid., p. 46].
The relationship between the rate of profit and surplus labour is
found at the end of the chapter “On Value”, in Section VII, where
Ricardo writes:

“A rise in wages, from an alteration in the value of money, produces a general


effect on price, and for that reason it produces no real effect whatever on
profits. On the contrary, a rise of wages, from the circumstance of the
labourer being more liberally rewarded, or from a difficulty of procuring the
necessaries on which wages are expended, does not, except in some instances,
produce the effect of raising price, but has a great effect in lowering profits.
In the one case, no greater proportion of the annual labour of the country is

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 89 14/05/2020 17:30


90 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

devoted to the support of the labourers; in the other case, a larger portion is
so devoted” (ibid., p. 48-49).

Ricardo never explicitly points out that the labour theory of value
is necessary to relate the rate of profit to surplus labour. Besides, the
foregoing examination of the first chapter in the Principles, does not
enable us to conclude that this relation presupposes the labour theory
of value, which implies the identical value composition of capital in
all sectors. As we have seen, in his search for an invariable measure of
value and in his critique of Smith’s adding up theory of value, Ricardo
considers that prices change when wages increase. On the other hand,
as we showed in section 1.2, the relation between the rate of profit and
surplus labour is fully explained by equation (10), which is entirely
independent of the composition of capital.

2.3. The simplified determination of the rate


of profit in the Principles
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
The object of Chapter VI is “to consider what is the cause of the
permanent variations in the rate of profit, and the consequent perma-
nent alterations in the rate of interest” [ibid., p. 110].
In line with Section IV of Chapter I [see ibid., p. 36-37], Ricardo
addresses the issue in the framework of the labour theory of value,
stating that the price of agricultural products “is regulated by the
quantity of labour necessary to produce it, with that portion of capital
which pays no rent” [ibid., p. 110]. And, to further simplify his calcu-
lations as we will see below, he assumes that the value of commodities
“is divided into two portions only: one constitutes the profits of stock,
the other the wages of labour” [ibid., p. 110]. This hypothesis implies
that prices only depend on the quantities of direct labour. Since labour
is the only input used in the production of all goods, we have A = 0.
System (8) and equation (10) are respectively written:
(1 + r)wl = p(17)
1=(1 + r)b´l(18)
System (17) shows that vectors p and l are proportional and there-
fore the labour theory of value holds. Equation (18) means that the
rate of profit depends on the quantity of labour required to produce
wage-goods or, in other words, on surplus labour:

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 90 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 91

(19)
Referring to the numerical examples he has provided to illustrate
the determination of the rate of profit, Ricardo clearly explains the
reason for assuming the labour values in his numerical illustrations: “In
all these calculations I have been desirous only to elucidate the prin-
ciple… My object has been to simplify the subject” [ibid., p. 121-122]
by assuming that the value is divided into wages and profits. A few
lines further, he admits the use of raw materials in the production of
goods [ibid., p. 122]. In this case, it follows from (19) that, due to
an increased capital, the rate of profit must be lower. This is precisely
what Ricardo says:

“I must again observe, that the rate of profits would fall much more rapidly
than I have estimated in my calculation: for the value of the produce being
what I have stated it under the circumstances supposed, the value of the
farmer’s stock would be greatly increased from its necessarily consisting of
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
many of the commodities which had risen in value” [ibid., p. 122].

Ricardo starts the last and long paragraph of the chapter “On
Profits” by summing up what he already asserted in the chapter “On
Value”: “Thus we again arrive at the same conclusion which we have
before attempted to establish: —that in all countries, and all times,
profits depend on the quantity of labour requisite to provide neces-
saries for the labourers” [ibid., p. 126], with the only difference that
now he specifies: “on that land or with that capital which yields no
rent” [ibid., p. 126]. This last paragraph of Chapter VI is ended with
the leitmotiv of Chapter I, focused on the critique of Smith’s adding
up theory of value:

“Thus then I have endeavoured to shew, first, that a rise of wages would
not raise the price of commodities, but would invariably lower profits; and
secondly, that if the prices of all commodities could be raised, still the effect
on profits would be the same; and that in fact the value of the medium only
in which prices and profits are estimated would be lowered” [ibid., p. 127].

Ricardo does not assert that prices are not affected by changes in
income distribution, as stated by the labour theory of value. Once
again, he concludes that an increase in wages certainly causes a lower

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 91 14/05/2020 17:30


92 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

rate of profit, the effect on prices depending on the standard: all prices
can increase when they are expressed in terms of the commodity whose
price falls more than any other.

Conclusion

On several occasions Ricardo points out the limits of the labour


theory of value and explicitly states that he uses a simplified model
which implies that theory. We have taken these warnings seriously
and have considered them as an invitation to reexamine Ricardo’s
main theoretical propositions on the rate of profit in the light of the
contemporary classical price theory, of which Ricardo is the father.
The notion of surplus labour can be used to explain the rate of
profit only if the wage is exogenously given. For this purpose, we have
defined the wage as a purchasing power on a basket of commodities
resulting from the negotiation between classes. This interpretation
contrasts with Sraffa’s argument for assuming the exogenous rate of
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
profit.
Above all, we have shown that, as asserted in the Principles, the
endogenous rate of profit is determined by the physical composition
of wages and the quantities of direct and indirect labour employed
in the production of wage-goods. This result is independent of the
labour theory of value and means that the rate of profit depends on
surplus labour.
In the contemporary classical theory, the rate of profit is determined
in physical terms as a ratio of the net surplus product to the capital
in the homothetic system built on the basis of the actual system.
By definition, the net surplus product depends on the proportions
between sectors. We have shown that, as the rate of profit and prices,
surplus labour is independent of such proportions. Moreover, surplus
labour is the same in the actual system and in the homothetic system
associated to it if both systems employ the same quantity of labour.
Thus, the rate of profit is univocally related to the same surplus labour
of both the homothetic and the actual systems. Such a relation cannot
be established between the rate of profit and the net surplus product.
Besides, being determined in physical terms, the rate of profit is
compatible with an evaluation of net surplus product and capital in
terms of quantities of labour, whatever the composition of capital is.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 92 14/05/2020 17:30


4. Economic theory and history of economic thought 93

This article has provided an example of the use of the contemporary


classical theory as an invaluable tool for understanding past classical
authors. This theory, the roots of which are found in Dmitriev’s and
Sraffa’s works, fully justifies Ricardo’s assertion on the relationship
between surplus labour and the rate of profit. The classical approach
emphasizes the determination of the rate of profit irrespective of
prices. As Sraffa points out, this idea appears in Ricardo’s corn model
of the Essay and is generalized in the Principles. However, contrary
to Sraffa, it is not labour but the composite homothetic commodity
that replaces the corn.

***

References

Cartelier Jean [1976], Surproduit et reproduction. La formation de l’économie


politique classique, Grenoble, Presses Universitaires de Grenoble-François
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)
Maspero.
Dmitriev Vladimir Karpovich [1898], “Théorie de la valeur de D. Ricardo”,
in Essais Économiques, [1904], Traduction française, Paris, CNRS, 1968.
Klimovsky Edith [1998], “Trabajo homogéneo y bienes-salario en la teoría
ricardiana”, in M. Teubal (ed.), Teoría, estructura y procesos económicos.
Ensayos en honor al Dr. Julio H.G. Olivera, Buenos Aires, Argentina,
Eudeba, 1998, p. 109-125.
– [1998], “Technique et salaires : limites de l’interprétation ‘classique’ de la
théorie de la valeur de Marx”, Cahiers d’Économie Politique, 32, p. 25-40.
– [2006], “Tasa de ganancia, acumulación y circulación: los conceptos
básicos de la teoría clásica del valor”, Cuadernos de Economía, vol. xxv,
44, p. 33-55.
Ricardo David, [1815], Essay on the Influence of a Low Price of Corn on the
Profits of Stock, in P. Sraffa (ed.), Works and Correspondence of David
Ricardo, vol. iv, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1951, p. 1-41.
– [1821], On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, in P. Sraffa
(ed.), Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, vol. i, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 1951.
Smith Adam, [1776] An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of
Nations, E. Cannan (ed.), New York, The Modern Library, 1937.

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 93 14/05/2020 17:30


94 La théorie économique est-elle utile ?

Sraffa Piero [1951], “Introduction”, in P. Sraffa (ed.), Works and Correspondence


of David Ricardo, vol. i, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1951,
p. xiii-lxii.
– [1960], Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Prelude to
a Critique of Economic Theory, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

© Hermann | Téléchargé le 13/08/2022 sur www.cairn.info via CNRST Rabat (IP: 196.200.131.104)

979-0302 7_Cahiers Economie politique 77_MEP-ok.indd 94 14/05/2020 17:30

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi